ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group DOMINANCE/SUBSTANTIAL MARKET POWER ANALYSIS PURSUANT TO UNILATERAL CONDUCT LAWS. Recommended Practices



Similar documents
UNILATERAL CONDUCT WORKBOOK CHAPTER 3: ASSESSMENT OF DOMINANCE

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of XXX

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of (Text with EEA relevance)

MERGER GUIDELINES COMPETITION COMMISSION OF PAKISTAN

ENTERPRISE DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY Small- and Medium-Sized Enterprises. I. Introduction

Fair Competition Commission. THE FAIR COMPETITION COMMISSION PROCEDURE RULES, 2013 Rule 33(2) MERGER NOTIFICATION (Application for Merger Clearance)

Cable Europe answer to BEREC s questionnaire for a report on oligopoly analysis and regulation

Cases COMP/AT Google Google s revised proposed commitments BEUC response to the questionnaire

PART III: HORIZONTAL RULES. Criteria for the analysis of the compatibility of state aid for training subject to individual notification 1

Price relationship agreements in the UK and EU: a retail-mfn enforcement gap?

Defining Merger Transactions for Purposes of Merger Review

Guidelines for Merger Analysis

Market Definition and Analysis for SMP: A practical guide

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire. Refusal to Deal

ICN Merger Working Group: Analytical Framework Sub-group THE ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK FOR MERGER CONTROL

EU Competition Law. Article 101 and Article 102. January Contents

Antitrust Law & Economics: Exclusionary Behavior, Bundled Discounts, and Refusals to Deal

Position Statement on Cable Television Regulation in Maine. Submitted by New England Cable and Telecommunications Association ( NECTA ) June 2009

The minimum set of leased lines retail market

JURY INSTRUCTIONS. 2.4 Willful Maintenance of Monopoly Power

Box 1: Four party credit card schemes

Aggregation. Is bigger always better?

A Report to the Minister for Health and Children. Competition in the Irish Private Health Insurance Market Executive Summary

Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Joshua D. Wright In the Matter of Fidelity National Financial, Inc. and Lender Processing Services, Inc.

Proposed acquisition by Unum Limited of the employee benefits business of Swiss Life (UK) plc

New York Insurance Exchange. Sub-Group Recommendations. June 28, 2010 NYC, NY

Revised ERG Common Position. Appropriate remedies in the ECNS regulatory framework

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

Modernisation of Article 102 TFEU: Use of Economic Analysis for Conditional Rebates

Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation

INCENTIVES FOR MOBILE CO-LOCATION PROVISION IN NEW ZEALAND

Investing in the Infrastructure for Energy Markets

INTERNATIONAL STANDARD ON AUDITING (UK AND IRELAND) 240 THE AUDITOR S RESPONSIBILITIES RELATING TO FRAUD IN AN AUDIT OF FINANCIAL STATEMENTS

Data Communications Company (DCC) price control guidance: process and procedures

Response to Consultation and Final Document. Information Technology and Communication Authority

Auditing in Foreign Jurisdictions

Response to consultation on options for reform: a competition regime for growth

Procurement, Competition and Choice in the new healthcare landscape

October 23, Mr. Robert Goldman 5638 Springwood Ave. SE Salem, Oregon Re:

How To Compete With A Monopoly On A Job Portal

for Private Purchasers Engaged in Value Purchasing of Health Care

Competition Legislation. Competition Act Application in the Energy Sector

EU MERGER CONTROL 4 NOVEMBRE 2005 NOËLLE LENOIR PRESIDENTE DE L'INSTITUT DE L'EUROPE DAN ROSKIS

How To Write A Listing Policy For A Species At Risk Act

European Commission Consultation document on Voice over IP

Competition in EU Electricity Markets The Role of Antitrust Policy

Qihoo v. Tencent: economic analysis of the first Chinese Supreme Court decision under Anti-Monopoly Law

Response to. DG Competition Best Practices on the conduct of proceedings concerning. Articles 101 and 102 TFEU

Note No. 138 March Natural Gas Markets in the U.K.

BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 (3) of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC:

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. Electric Creditworthiness Standards ) Docket No.

Review of recent CCSA experiences in the Telecommunications Sector Kazan, Russia. Selelo Ramohlola & Tapera Muzata 31 March 3 April 2015

General remarks. Page 1 of 6

Statements of Antitrust. in Health Care

Market Review for the Postal Sector: Letter Mail Markets

SUMMARY OF CHANGES COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION RULES

Procurement guidance Prequalifying suppliers

Submission by the Commonwealth Ombudsman

ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR HORIZONTAL COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS:

Competition and Mobile Penetration in Sub-Saharan Africa

PanTerra Gold Limited Share Trading Policy

Evaluation of the 2009 interchange and credit card settlements

RESPONSE TO THE INFORMATION COMMISSIONER S OFFICE BIG DATA AND DATA PROTECTION PAPER 1. BACKGROUND

THE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES IN IRELAND

RECOMMENDATIONS ON BUSINESS PLAN PREPARATION

How To Decide If There Is A Need For Regulatory Intervention In Relation To End To End-To-End Competition In The Postal Sector

Consultation paper on telecommunications market reviews and notification of the proposed determinations

Telecommunications EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Submission to the Department of Finance on The Taxation of Corporate Groups

Designation of Universal Service Provider

Practical guide... termination of employment

Fee Waivers INTRODUCTION CONTENTS FEES: THE RATIONALE

Update on Developments in Competition Law/Policy

DECISION OF THE THIRD-PARTY DECIDER

ACCESS TO JUSTICE GROUP: RESPONSE TO SRA DISCUSSION PAPER ON REFERRAL FEE BAN

Technical Factsheet 189 Intangible Fixed Assets

1.2 This license shall be subject to the provisions herein stated, the Telecommunications Law and any regulations issued thereunder.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. Jon Leibowitz, Chairman William E. Kovacic J. Thomas Rosch Edith Ramirez Julie Brill

Sample Request For Information and Statement of Purpose 1.1

Response by NIE Energy (PPB)

Oligopoly in small economies

APPLICATION BY JERSEY POST LTD FOR WAIVER UNDER CONDITION 20.7 OF LICENCE IN RESPECT OF BULK MAIL SERVICES

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C

INTERNATIONAL STANDARD ON AUDITING (UK AND IRELAND) 240 THE AUDITOR S RESPONSIBILITY TO CONSIDER FRAUD IN AN AUDIT OF FINANCIAL STATEMENTS CONTENTS

Investigation Report to Competition Commission

Barriers to Entry. by Paolo Buccirossi * Director, Lear Laboratorio di economia, antitrust, regolamentazione; paolo.buccirossi@learlab.

KINGDOM OF SAUDI ARABIA. Capital Market Authority CREDIT RATING AGENCIES REGULATIONS

Rule change request. 18 September 2013

Response to European Commission inquiry into the European business insurance sector pursuant to Article 17 of Regulation 1/2003

Home Model Legislation Telecommunications and Information. Cable and Video Competition Act

Code of Conduct for Persons Providing Credit Rating Services

Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire Response by Tadmor & Co. (Israel)

Policy Statement. Employee privacy, data protection and human resources. Prepared by the Commission on E-Business, IT and Telecoms. I.

August A Review of the Development of Competition in the Industrial and Commercial Gas Supply Market

CONTRACT MANAGEMENT FRAMEWORK

What Is a Barrier to Entry?

Agency Effectiveness Competition Agency Practice Manual March CHAPTER 1 Strategic Planning and Prioritisation

Strategy is about organizational change.1 An action is strategic when it allows a

Transcription:

ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group DOMINANCE/SUBSTANTIAL MARKET POWER ANALYSIS PURSUANT TO UNILATERAL CONDUCT LAWS Recommended Practices The concept of dominance or substantial market power limits the scope of application of most unilateral conduct laws. Making dominance or substantial market power a prerequisite for intervention under unilateral conduct laws serves as a filter for intervention against specific anti-competitive conduct. 1 The concept of dominance pursuant to unilateral conduct laws is generally equivalent to the possession of substantial market power, and thus this document uses the terms dominance and substantial market power interchangeably. Market power is defined generally as the ability to price profitably 2 above the competitive level. Dominance/substantial market power is a high degree of market power both with respect to the level to which price can be profitably raised and to the duration that price can be maintained at such a level. The degree of market power required to constitute dominance/substantial market power and the nature and extent of the evidence required to establish dominance/substantial market power are basic and important policy choices made by legislatures, competition agencies, and courts. The work of the Unilateral Conduct Working Group in 2006-2007 highlights different policy choices as to what is required to constitute and establish dominance/substantial market power. All jurisdictions agree that unilateral conduct laws address specific conduct and its anticompetitive effects, rather than the mere possession of dominance/substantial market power or its creation through competition on the merits. All jurisdictions also agree that the goal of enforcement is to identify and act against conduct that is anticompetitive, although it can be difficult to distinguish between pro- and anticompetitive unilateral conduct. Determining whether a firm possesses dominance/substantial market power generally is the first step in the evaluation of potentially anti-competitive unilateral conduct. Laws differ in the way dominance/substantial market power is defined. Most jurisdictions find that a rigorous assessment of whether a firm possesses dominance/substantial market power, going well beyond market shares, is highly desirable. In jurisdictions with a more formalistic definition of dominance based on market shares, it is recommended that agencies be particularly rigorous in their analysis of the conduct at issue. 1 See ICN Report on the Objectives of Unilateral Conduct Laws, Assessment of Dominance/Substantial Market Power, and State-Created Monopolies. 2 The ability to raise and maintain prices is used as a shorthand for the various ways in which market power can be exercised.

2 Based on the group s work during 2006-2007, the ICN recommends the following practices for the assessment of dominance/substantial market power in the context of unilateral conduct laws: I. General Framework 1. Agencies should use a sound analytical framework firmly grounded in economic principles in determining whether dominance/substantial market power exists. Comment: Properly assessing whether a firm possesses dominance/substantial market power, is a complex and multi-faceted analysis. Although each jurisdiction has chosen its own specific wording for the legal definition of dominance/substantial market power, there is increasing convergence toward the principle that the analysis reaches well beyond market shares. The analysis of dominance/substantial market power, therefore, should be based on the assessment criteria mentioned in section II. 2. A firm should not be found to possess dominance/substantial market power without a comprehensive consideration of factors affecting competitive conditions in the market under investigation. Comment 1: Various market characteristics determine the extent to which a firm is or is not constrained by competitive pressure, in particular from actual or potential competitors. Agencies should assess dominance/substantial market power by directly investigating how the particular relevant market operates and the competitive situation in the market. Comment 2: The analysis of dominance/substantial market power includes but does not stop with the assessment of market shares. At a minimum, conditions of entry and expansion (affecting the durability of market power) should also be assessed. Agencies should, where appropriate, also take into account other criteria such as buyer power, economies of scale and scope/network effects, and access to upstream markets/vertical integration. II. Assessment Criteria

3 Market shares 3. Market shares of the firm under investigation and its existing competitors, including their development during the past years, should be used as an indication or starting point for the dominance/substantial market power analysis. Comment 1: Market shares are generally used as the starting point for assessing market power. Market shares provide useful information about the firm s past market success. In most markets, a firm s market share is an important factor that provides a first indication as to whether a firm has market power and, if so, the degree of its market power. Comment 2: Market shares provide a useful first indication of the market structure and of the competitive importance of various firms active on the market (the relative market position of the firm under investigation compared to its competitors). However, since market shares fail to reflect certain important features of the competitive environment, in particular market dynamics, they should be put into perspective by consideration of other factors, such as potential entry, when assessing the degree of market power of the firm under investigation. Comment 3: Additional weight should be given to the assessment of whether market shares have been or could be maintained over a significant period of time. Such maintenance can be an indication of durable market power, while historic volatility could indicate its absence. 4. Agencies should give careful consideration to the calculation of market shares. Comment 1: Market shares are useful in the analysis of market power only when they are based on properly defined product and geographic markets. Market share calculations should be based on reliable data and sources, and sound assumptions. Comment 2: Market shares should be based on a measure that is appropriate to the characteristics of the market and they should be interpreted in the light of the relevant market conditions. Changes in market conditions should be considered in interpreting market shares. Comment 3: In practice, market shares, in particular for heterogeneous products, are most often defined in value terms, expressed by turnover. However, other methods of calculation, such as quantities, production capacities and volume of orders, can be useful.

4 Market Share Safe Harbors/Indicators 5. It can be beneficial to use market share-based thresholds as a safe harbor. Comment 1: Agencies can use market shares to establish a level under which an agency generally will not find dominance/substantial market power (a safe harbor ). Possession of a market share outside the safe harbor is generally necessary but insufficient for finding dominance/substantial market power. Whether a firm with a market share outside the safe harbor possesses dominance/substantial market power or not, requires a detailed analysis including additional factors. Comment 2: Jurisdictions use different types of safe harbors, based on different market share levels. Some agencies use safe harbors that guarantee that dominance/substantial market power will not be found below the safe harbor level, which maximizes certainty and reduces agency burdens, while others establish only a rebuttable presumption against a finding of dominance/substantial market power. The benefits of safe harbors have to be weighed against their risks, in particular potential over-emphasis on market shares and thus potential enforcement errors. 6. It can be beneficial to use market share-based thresholds as an indicator of dominance/substantial market power. Comment 1: In some jurisdictions, demonstration of a sufficiently high market share creates a presumption of dominance/substantial market power. In jurisdictions in which the presumption shifts the burden of proof to the firm under investigation to provide evidence of why it is not dominant, the agency should remain receptive toward evidence that may overcome the presumption (e.g., that the market operates competitively). In other jurisdictions, although high market shares serve as an initial indicator of potential dominance/substantial market power, the burden of carrying out a thorough market investigation establishing dominance/substantial market power remains with the agency. Comment 2: In determining an appropriate market share threshold for use as an indicator of dominance/substantial market power, the benefits, such as increased enforcement efficiency and legal certainty especially for businesses, should be weighed against the risks, including the potential for over-emphasizing market shares and thus potential enforcement errors. Comment 3: In the great majority of jurisdictions, a high market share is one of several factors that must be present before a finding of dominance/substantial market power is made. In most of these jurisdictions, no presumption of dominance/substantial market power arises from a high market share.

5 Entry Analysis 7. The assessment of durability of market power, with a focus on barriers to entry or expansion, should be an integral part of the analysis of dominance/substantial market power. Comment 1: Entry analysis provides information on the significance of potential competitors for competition in the market concerned and thus about market power and its durability, to the extent such power is found. Analysis of expansion provides information on the potential impact of expansion by competitors already active in the market. Agencies should assess not only whether entry/expansion is theoretically possible but also whether it will in fact pose a credible competitive constraint on the incumbent. Comment 2: If barriers to entry/expansion faced by actual or potential competitors are low, the fact that one firm has a high market share may not be indicative of durable market power. By contrast, substantial barriers to entry/expansion may imply the absence or limited importance of (potential) competitive constraints on the firm alleged to be dominant or in possession of substantial market power. Comment 3: Assessing the likelihood of entry/expansion is an important part of the analysis. Entry/expansion is likely to occur if it would be profitable. In this assessment, the cumulative impact of all barriers in a given market is considered. Depending on the circumstances of the particular case, several kinds of barriers can reduce incentives for potential competitors to enter the market or competitors to expand in the market. When assessing the ease of entry/expansion, agencies should focus on whether actual or potential competitors will consider entry/expansion to be profitable in light of factors such as: economies of scope and/or scale; a scarce natural resource that is an important input; technical capability; the reputation of incumbent firms; incumbent firms investment in excess capacity; the duration, termination, and renewal provisions in existing contracts; government regulations that may, for example, limit the number of market participants or impose substantial regulatory approval costs; and sunk costs that cannot be recovered if the entrant leaves the market. Comment 4: Agencies typically assess whether entry/expansion would occur in a timely manner (not just eventually ) to exert an appreciable effect on the incumbent s conduct. If barriers substantially delay entry/expansion, the incumbent would not currently be constrained by entry/expansion. Comment 5: It is also important to consider the scope of entry/expansion. It must be large enough, and of a character, to constrain the firm alleged to be dominant or in possession of substantial market power to a sufficient extent. This may not be the case if entry/expansion occurs only locally, on a small scale, or in niche markets.

6 Further Criteria 8. As appropriate in the specific circumstances of a particular case, agencies should use further criteria to analyze dominance/substantial market power. Comment: Jurisdictions use some or all of various further criteria, including buyer power, access to upstream markets/vertical integration, economies of scale and scope/network effects, market maturity/vitality, access to important inputs, and financial resources of the firm and its competitors. To ensure a sound assessment of dominance/substantial market power, agencies should consider these criteria, as appropriate in the circumstances of the case. III. Dominance/substantial market power assessment in small and/or isolated economies 9. The analytical framework used to assess market power is the same in small and/or isolated economies, but market factors may result in more limited competition. Comment: The basic framework used to assess dominance/substantial market power is not altered by an economy s relative size or openness to trade. However, such factors can influence the ultimate outcome of the dominance/substantial market power assessment. This influence stems from the relative isolation or openness of the economy, scale economies, and the corresponding effect on barriers to entry. If an economy is small and/or isolated from external trade, this may result in higher barriers to entry which could facilitate a finding of dominance/substantial market power. IV. Transparency 10. Agencies should seek to make their dominance/substantial market power assessments transparent, subject to the appropriate protection of confidential information. Comment 1: The degree of substantiality required for a finding of dominance/substantial market power and the nature and extent of the evidence required to establish dominance/substantial market power are important policy choices made by legislatures, agencies, and courts. Thus, it is important for agencies to be as transparent as possible with respect to their policies on dominance/substantial market power. Transparency also promotes consistency in agency decision-making, and tends to promote compliance. Comment 2: There are many ways that competition agencies can foster transparency. To give guidance, agencies can publish their decisions or enforcement guidelines or provide other formal guidance to the business community concerning dominance/substantial market power. In addition, competition officials can give speeches explaining their

7 policies and cases. To the extent feasible, such pronouncements should be updated periodically to reflect current practice. Comment 3: Efforts to provide transparency are limited by the obligation to protect confidential information. When agencies make information pertaining to a dominance/substantial market power assessment publicly available, they should provide for the protection of confidential information.