Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination



Similar documents
Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance

Why Default Rates Cannot Shed Light on Mortgage Discrimination

Mortgage Lending Discrimination and Racial Differences in Loan Default

Comparing Loan Performance Between Races as a Test for Discrimination

Discrimination in Mortgage Lending Anthony M. Yezer

Mortgage Performance and Housing Market Discrimination

Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance

Mortgages, Minorities and Discrimination: A Bank-Specific Approach

A Review of Statistical Problems in the Measurement of Mortgage Market Discrimination and Credit Risk. Anthony M. Yezer

Hot Topics in Fair Lending

Discrimination in Access to Finance: Evidence from the United States Small Business Credit Market

The ability to get a mortgage is often the key to an individual s ability to

New and Re-emerging Fair Lending Risks. Article by Austin Brown & Loretta Kirkwood October 2014

A Test of Cultural Affinity in Home Mortgage Lending *

Simultaneity bias in mortgage lending: A test of simultaneous equations models on bank-specific data

Disparate Impact Considerations for Private Education Loans

Mortgage Lending Discrimination: A Review of Existing Evidence

Fair Lending, UDAAP and CRA: Protecting Your Bank from Allegations of Fair and Responsible Lending Violations

Have the GSE Affordable Housing Goals Increased. the Supply of Mortgage Credit?

Fair Lending Update Banker Outreach Program

WHO RECEIVES A MORTGAGE MODIFICATION? RACE AND INCOME DIFFERENTIALS IN LOAN WORKOUTS

Fair Lending Overview. Division of Depositor and Consumer Protection

Is there Discriminatory Mortgage Pricing against Immigrants in the Spanish Lending Market?

ESTIMATION OF DEMAND FOR MORTGAGE LOANS USING LOAN-LEVEL DATA

Subprime vs. Predatory Lending

Mark W Olson: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act

Policy Issues Concerning Racial and Ethnic Differences in Home Loan Rejection Rates

The Pricing of Home Mortgage Loans to Minority Borrowers: How Much of the APR Differential Can We Explain?

Subprime Foreclosures: The Smoking Gun of Predatory Lending?

The 2009 Consumer Financial Literacy Survey Final Report. The National Foundation for Credit Counseling

Banker s Guide To Risk-Based Fair Lending Examinations

Logan City. Analysis of Impediments to Fair Housing

Community socioeconomic status and disparities in mortgage lending: An analysis of Metropolitan Detroit

Susan Costonis, C.R.C.M. Compliance Training & Consulting for Financial Institutions

REGULATORY ALERT NATIONAL CREDIT UNION ADMINISTRATION 1775 DUKE STREET, ALEXANDRIA, VA DATE: June 5, 1997 NO.: 97-RA-9. TO: All Credit Unions

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE JANUARY 8, 2015 MORTGAGE LENDER COMMUNITY INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION NEW FED MORTGAGE CORP. MC1881

DISCRIMINATION IN MORTGAGE LENDING. Webb A. Brewer Brewer Barlow, PLC

SUMMARY OF FINDINGS Consumer Testing of Mortgage Broker Disclosures

Racial and Ethnic Disparities in 2011 Ohio Mortgage Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

DISCRIMINATION IN THE SMALL BUSINESS CREDIT MARKET. David G. Blanchflower. Phillip B. Levine. David J. Zimmerman

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT THE NEW HMDA DATA. General Background

Fair Lending Analysis Made Easy. Presented by: Ian Dunn CEO,

Mortgage Loans. Understand the Terms of Your Loan before You Sign. Mortgage Loans. Standard Home Equity Loans or Second Mortgages

MORTGAGE LOAN PREQUALIFICATIONS:

Guide to Fair Mortgage Lending and Home Preservation

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE. February 3, 2011 MORTGAGE LENDER COMMUNITY INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION IFREEDOM DIRECT CORPORATION ML3122

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

AT THE STORE CONSUMER CREDIT AND PROTECTION

6 Mortgage Industry Flaws. Cost You Thousands!

Obtain Information from Several Lenders

Regulatory Practice Letter January 2013 RPL 13-01

Credit Scoring and Disparate Impact

Consumer Protection and Regulatory Changes in the Dodd-Frank Bill

DISCRIMINATION IN THE SMALL BUSINESS CREDIT MARKET. David G. Blanchflower. Phillip B. Levine. David J. Zimmerman

ACCESS TO CREDIT FOR MINORITY-OWNED BUSINESSES

The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) was passed by Congress in The goal of

DISCRIMINATION IN THE SMALL BUSINESS CREDIT MARKET. David G. Blanchflower. Phillip B. Levine. David J. Zimmerman

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT THE NEW HMDA DATA. General Background

WHAT YOU NEED TO KNOW ABOUT BUYING AND SELLING A HOME

Obtain Information from Several Lenders

PUBLIC DISCLOSURE FEBRUARY 12, 2015 MORTGAGE LENDER COMMUNITY INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE EVALUATION NE MOVES MORTGAGE, LLC MC2584

TITLE 18 INSURANCE DELAWARE ADMINISTRATIVE CODE Consumer Rights. 906 Use of Credit Information [Formerly Regulation 87]

What You Should Know About Home Equity Lines of Credit and Important Terms of FlexEquity SM

Understanding Your Credit Score

Home Mortgage Disclosure Act - Regulation C

TITLE I SAFETY AND SOUNDNESS. Subtitle A Deposit Insurance Funds

Assuming a Can Opener: Economic Theory s Failure To Explain Discrimination in FHA Lending Markets

Unfair or Deceptive Acts or Practices by State-Chartered Banks March 11, 2004

A CONSUMER GUIDE TO FAIR LENDING

MLO COMPENSATION, REGULATION Z, AND DODD-FRANK ACT

The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau Should Rein in Mortgage Servicers Use of Force-Placed Insurance

Looking for the Best Mortgage?

A Case for Variable Rate Mortgages ( P. d. Last Fall's Policy Changes: A Sound Program for Reducing Inflation < P. 5) Winter 1979

OCC OCC BULLETIN

COPING WITH MORTGAGE PENALTIES IN CANADA. Richard Beaumier, FCA, CFA, MBA VICE-PRESIDENT, GOVERNMENT RELATIONS COMMITTEE

Florida Foreclosure/Real Estate Law. E-Book. A Simple Guide to Florida Foreclosure/Real Estate Law. by: Florida Law Advisers, P.A.

One method of measuring the prices of deposit and loan services is to view the differentials

Amendment to the AFR Wholesale Broker Agreement regarding Amendments to Regulation Z. Table of Contents

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF NEVADA

Discrimination in the Small Business Credit Market

An Approach to Stress Testing the Canadian Mortgage Portfolio

Ten Ways to Avoid Common HMDA Reporting Errors

Fair Housing Act. Reference Guide to Regulatory Compliance. 42 USC Ch through 3619

Reporting Issues Under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act

The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

HOME OWNERSHIP EQUITY PROTECTION ACT OF Raymond Natter 1

CRA and fair lending regulations: Resulting trends in mortgage lending

GENERAL TIPS FOR BUYING/SELLING A HOME Office of the Staff Judge Advocate, MacDill Air Force Base, Florida (813)

The Role of Race in Mortgage Lending: Revisiting the Boston Fed Study*

Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen

Uniform Residential Loan Application

INSIGHTS INTO THE MINORITY HOMEBUYING EXPERIENCE

SETTLEMENT AGREEMENT AND CONSENT ORDER OCWEN FINANCIAL CORPORATION AND OCWEN LOAN SERVICING, LLC

Published by American Bankers Association in March/April 2012 issue of ABA Bank Compliance magazine

Weststar Mortgage Corporation Albuquerque, NM

Fair Lending S. Union Park Ave. Suite 260 Midvale, UT P

An analysis of subprime lending patterns, homeownership and foreclosures among people of color in Oklahoma City and Tulsa MSAs

Risk Bearing, Implicit Financial Services, and Specialization in the Financial Industry

FREE YOUR MIND Stop House Repossession

Transcription:

Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination Stephen L. Ross University of Connecticut Abstract This critique examines the proposal that loan defaults can be used to test for the existence of discrimination in the mortgage approval process. The critique then shows that a test based on loan defaults is biased against finding evidence of discrimination and that some of these key biases do not arise in a direct test using loan approval data. Finally, the critique examines and rejects a similar proposal to use information on lender loss upon default to test for differential treatment during the foreclosure process. Recent studies by Berkovec, Canner, Gabriel, and Hannan (BCGH) (1994, 1995) have led to renewed debate concerning discrimination in mortgage lending. BCGH follow a default approach to test for discrimination, arguing that if minority borrowers are held to higher standards than nonminority borrowers, only high-quality minority loans will be approved and minority loans will have lower default rates than nonminority loans. They find that for African Americans the theoretical prediction is not supported by empirical evidence; rather, African-American borrowers have higher default rates. Mortgage lenders cite the studies as evidence that they do not systematically discriminate against African Americans. Canner cautions, however, that this interpretation is inaccurate, because there are forms of discrimination that the studies do not address (Karr, 1995). For example, BCGH admit that the default approach cannot test for statistical discrimination, in which lenders face an economic incentive to discriminate because minority borrowers are more likely to default on loans for reasons that are unobservable at the time of loan approval. BCGH are, in essence, testing for discrimination due to prejudice, in which the lenders face a trade-off between their prejudice and bank profits and only approve minority loans that are very good risks. This critique argues that the default approach is not a good test for discrimination due to prejudice. The first section maintains that the default approach is a poor test if the correlation between unobservable characteristics in the loan approval and default equations is small. The second section shows that the assumptions made in the default approach are inconsistent with current findings of racial differences in loan approval, such as the results Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research Volume 2, Number 1 February 1996 U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development Office of Policy Development and Research Cityscape 41

Ross of Munnell, Browne, McEneaney, and Tootell (1992). The third section concludes that a second test conducted by BCGH, in which they test for discrimination in loan foreclosure using an analysis of lender loss upon default, suffers from many of the same problems as the default approach and argues that some of those problems could have been avoided. Finally, this critique raises the possibility that minority loans may be riskier than nonminority loans after controlling for variables that are observable at loan approval and addresses the policy issues arising from this possibility. Correlation Across Equations The default approach is based on the fact that the loan approval process is likely to lead to a selected sample of approved loans. If minorities are held to a higher standard for loan approval, approved minority loans will be of higher quality with regard to characteristics observed by the lender at the time of loan approval but not measured by researchers (unmeasured characteristics). If these unmeasured characteristics are correlated with borrower default, minority loans should have lower default rates than nonminority loans after controlling for loan characteristics observed at the time of loan approval. By the same argument, however, if there is no correlation between unmeasured characteristics and default, default rates cannot be influenced by the loan approval process. This correlation may, in fact, be very weak. Loan default is determined by many factors that arise after loan approval, such as changes in local housing and labor markets. These factors may have a much larger effect on the probability of loan default than unmeasured characteristics. Likewise, the impact of racial differences on default may consist almost entirely of differences that were not evident at the time of loan approval. A similar argument can be applied to tests for discrimination based on loan approval data. If unmeasured characteristics are correlated with race, the loan approval-based tests may be biased. If the correlation is negligible, however, the unmeasured characteristics must have little effect on default, and their use cannot be justified by business necessity. Therefore, unexplained racial distinctions made by lenders can be interpreted as discrimination, and the existence of unmeasured characteristics does not bias the loan approval-based tests. Unfortunately, accurate estimates of this correlation are not available. Simultaneous estimations of loan approval and default equations do not exist, because no mortgage data set combines both denied loan applications and outcomes of approved loans. Racial Differences in Loan Approval As stated above, the default approach tests whether minority loans have lower default rates than nonminority loans and implies that discrimination based on prejudice does not exist if minority loans have the same rate of default or a higher one. This implication is based, however, on the assumption that minority and nonminority tendencies toward defaulting are identical if there is no discrimination based on prejudice and after controlling for loan characteristics observable at the time of loan approval. 1 This assumption is not valid. To understand why that is so, one must first assume that there is no discrimination based on prejudice. Then one should note that Munnell et al. find lower loan approval rates for minorities after controlling for observed characteristics. Since the assumption is that these findings do not arise as a result of lender prejudice, this critique offers two alternative sources for the findings: Unmeasured characteristics that are correlated with race and predict loan default (omitted-variable bias). 42 Cityscape

Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination Unobserved characteristics that are correlated with race, explain default, and provide lenders with an economic incentive to discriminate (statistical discrimination). 2 For the first alternative, one should assume that the findings of Munnell et al. are due to omitted-variable bias. The resulting distribution of minority and nonminority unmeasured characteristics is illustrated by figure 1. In this situation minority loan applications are less likely to be approved, because the average quality of minority loans is lower for unmeasured characteristics. Since it is assumed that there is no discrimination due to prejudice, observationally identical minority and nonminority borrowers are held to the same standard (C) on unmeasured characteristics, nonminority loans are more likely to be approved, and the resulting nonminority loans have a higher average quality level after controlling for observed characteristics. Under these conditions, nonminority loans should have lower, not equal, default levels, which contradicts the basic assumption of the default approach and biases it away from finding discrimination due to prejudice (see Ross, forthcoming). Figure 1 Distribution of Unmeasured Characteristics for Loan Application Quality: Case of Omitted-Variable Bias Low C Nonminority High Low Minority C High Cityscape 43

Ross For the second alternative, one should assume that there are no systematic racial differences in unmeasured characteristics and that the findings of Munnell et al. are due to statistical discrimination. In other words, there are unobserved characteristics that create an economic incentive for lenders to hold minorities to a higher standard. The result is shown in figure 2, in which the distribution of minority and nonminority loan quality is identical but minority loans are held to a higher standard (C+D). Statistical discrimination raises the average quality of approved minority loans, but the unobserved characteristics directly lower the quality of approved minority loans. Since there is no reason to believe that these two effects would cancel each other out, minority and nonminority samples of approved loans may not have the same average quality in regard to unobserved characteristics. The assumption that minority and nonminority default rates are equal when there is no discrimination due to prejudice is again contradicted. Figure 2 Distribution of Unmeasured Characteristics for Loan Application Quality: Case of Statistical Discrimination Low C Nonminority High Low Minority C+D High In fact, Ross (forthcoming) examines this possibility for loan defaults. The author assumes that lenders hold minorities to a higher standard in order to equalize the expected propensity to default, finds that the relative decrease in minority defaults resulting from statistical discrimination is smaller than the existing difference resulting from unobservable 44 Cityscape

Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination characteristics, and concludes that the default approach is biased away from finding discrimination due to prejudice. 3 The intuition behind this conclusion is that the lender holds minority loans to a standard that exactly cancels out the racial differences in loan quality. These racial differences, however, affect loan default directly, while statistical discrimination affects loan default by creating a selected sample of loans. The two shifts in loan quality are the same size, but one shift enters the default process through a selection bias term. If the unobservable variables are distributed normally, the slope of this selection term is less than 1, and the effect of statistical discrimination on default is less than the impact of existing racial difference on default due to unobservable characteristics. Foreclosure and Lender Loss The default approach may also be biased because lenders may act to foreclose minority loans more aggressively than nonminority loans. BCGH examine this possibility using a lender loss approach, which is very similar to the default approach. They argue that if lenders foreclose more quickly on minority loans, then minority defaults should exhibit lower lender loss, because a quick foreclosure tends to limit losses on defaulted loans. They estimate a model of lender loss, do not find lower minority losses, and conclude that lenders do not foreclose more quickly on minority loans. In other words, they conclude that lenders do not discriminate against minorities in the loan foreclosure process. However, the foreclosure decision is based on all of the information available to the lender when the loan is actually at risk of default. If lenders discriminate against minorities in foreclosure, minority loans must have lower losses after controlling for all characteristics available at the time of foreclosure. BCGH have estimated the wrong model by including only information available at the time of loan approval. If minorities have worse experiences on average after loan approval, minority defaults may result in larger loan losses. The omission of these observable, postloan approval characteristics biases the lender loss approach away from finding discrimination in the foreclosure process. In addition, BCGH estimate the race coefficient for the sample of defaulted loans, but the lender loss approach is based on the argument that the default process creates a selected sample of defaulted loans. In the default approach, the effect of the approval process on loan default cannot be directly estimated; however, the selection effect in the lender loss approach is estimable. The effect can be found by estimating both the race coefficient in a model of potential lender loss for all approved loans and the race coefficient in a model of actual lender loss for defaulted loans. The selection effect due to the default process is the difference of these two race coefficients. However, BCGH have only estimated the race coefficient for actual lender loss. If minority loans have higher potential lender loss for approved loans, BCGH s approach is biased away from finding discrimination in foreclosure. 4 As discussed above, a key problem in any examination of loan default is the inability to distinguish between racial differences in borrower propensity to default and in lender propensity to foreclose. This problem also pervades any attempt to analyze lender loss. It is very difficult to separate the effects of lender and borrower behavior when default, by its very nature, results from a failed negotiation between the borrower and the loan officer. 5 This problem can be resolved only by a detailed analysis of the behavior of borrowers and lenders when a loan is at risk of default. Cityscape 45

Ross Fair Lending and Statistical Discrimination The preceding pages raise the possibility that African Americans are more likely to default on loans and that these defaults may result in larger lender losses. If this possibility is true, it gives lenders an economic incentive to use race as a signal of possible high-risk loans and also to be more selective in approving African-American loan applications and more aggressive in foreclosing on these loans. As noted earlier, such behavior is called statistical discrimination and is illegal. However, both the default and lender loss approaches will fail to find evidence of discrimination when lenders have an economic incentive to discriminate. If performancebased analyses such as these are used to justify lender behavior, lenders may practice statistical discrimination with impunity. This situation leaves Federal regulators with a choice of one of the following short-term policy options: Enforce the statutes that prohibit any form of discrimination by examining the loan approvals, as is currently being done. Allow lenders to use race as a signal of high default risk and hold minorities to higher standards. Subsidize African-American loans in order to compensate lenders for racial differences in loan outcomes, thus eliminating the economic incentive for discrimination. If the first option is followed, banks will be forced to incur the additional default costs associated with minority loans. These costs will be passed on to borrowers and possibly to depositors in the form of higher mortgage interest rates and lower interest payments on deposits. If the second option is followed, the additional default costs will fall primarily on African-American households, because they will be denied mortgages more often and their mortgages will be foreclosed more rapidly. The third option will spread the cost broadly by using tax dollars to eliminate a lender s economic incentive to discriminate. I believe that the first option is the only reasonable choice. The third option is not politically feasible, and the second contradicts a basic principle of equal treatment in our society. Regardless of whether a protected class performs badly on average, an institution cannot exclude an individual on the basis of race, ethnicity, or gender if that individual is qualified on the basis of observable characteristics. I believe that compromising on this principle would do great harm. A basic notion of fairness in this Nation is that people should be judged on their accomplishments, not punished for the actions of others in their race or ethnic group. In addition, the cause of racial differences in rates of default is unknown. These differences may arise because of discrimination in other sectors of the economy, which increases the probability that African- American borrowers will experience adverse outcomes after loan approval. If so, is it fair to discriminate against an individual on the basis of unobservable differences that may occur because of expected discrimination? It may seem unfair to force homeowners and depositors to bear the costs associated with more frequent African-American loan defaults, but it is the only feasible option unless society is willing to pay for that cost directly with public dollars. Summary and Conclusions The correlation between unobservable characteristics in the loan approval and default equations is the key to understanding current disagreements over discrimination in mortgage markets. If the correlation is very low, lenders have little excuse for excluding 46 Cityscape

Flaws in the Use of Loan Defaults To Test for Mortgage Lending Discrimination minorities on the basis of characteristics that have not been well specified and do not explain loan performance. If the correlation is high, the sample selection caused by the loan approval process could be substantial, and the default approach may provide some insights concerning the nature of discrimination. At present, however, no data set exists that allows the estimation of this correlation. Even if the correlation is high, the default approach may be a biased test of discrimination due to prejudice. If such discrimination exists, it may be hidden by racial differences in default rates. Such differences may be caused by unmeasured characteristics observed by the lender. Alternatively, unobserved racial differences in loan quality may exist. Even if all lenders maximize their profits by engaging in statistical discrimination, racial differences in default rates may remain and may hide discrimination due to prejudice. Finally, an analysis of loan foreclosure using lender loss suffers from the same flaws as the default approach. This lender loss approach cannot distinguish between differential treatment in foreclosure and racial differences in propensity to default. Loan default and/or foreclosure is a negotiated process, and the significance of racial default differences will remain a mystery until the nature of this negotiation is explored in detail. The most important result of BCGH is their careful documentation of racial differences in loan default. These differences should be of concern to policymakers, because defaults may impose large costs on minority borrowers and a high minority propensity toward defaulting may create an incentive for lender discrimination that government policy cannot overcome. BCGH make no attempt, however, to explain the origin of the default differences, and without such an explanation nothing about the nature of lending discrimination can be learned from default rates. This omission is even more disturbing when combined with attempts by others to use their study as a justification for racial differences in the loan approval process. Author Stephen Ross, an assistant professor in the Department of Economics at the University of Connecticut, received his Ph.D. from Syracuse University in August 1994. Dr. Ross has an active research agenda on housing and mortgage lending discrimination. His other research interests include theoretical and empirical topics in urban economics and local public finance. Notes 1. Specifically, the default approach assumes that default rates are equal if minority and nonminority loan applicants are held to the same standard. This is the same as an assumption that there is no discrimination due to prejudice as long as prejudice does not result in entirely random actions of loan denial without regard to the borrower s qualifications. Munnell et al. use a statistical framework, which also assumes that discrimination is not random. 2. This discussion is not intended to address the issues of endogeny raised by Rachlis and Yezer (1993). 3. Ross (1994) observes that loan performance approaches are biased for discrete dependent variables such as loan default, because the approval process affects the estimated coefficients through both the mean and the variance of the error distribution. As a result, the author examines a performance approach based on a continuous index of Cityscape 47

Ross loan profitability. If the variance bias identified is large, the default approach is hopelessly flawed. Alternatively, if the variance bias is small, the author s analysis for a profitability index also applies to the default approach, and that approach is biased away from finding discrimination due to prejudice. 4. A similar procedure for loan profitability is presented in Ross (1994). 5. The same concern applies to Yezer, Phillips, and Trost (1994), who argue that loan terms are endogenous and conclude that this fact biases approval-based tests for discrimination towards finding discrimination. This result arises, however, because the author s approach intrinsically views loan terms as being chosen freely by the borrower rather than as the result of a negotiation between the borrower and the loan officer. References Berkovec, J., G. Canner, S. Gabriel, and T. Hannan. 1994. Race, Redlining, and Residential Mortgage Loan Performance, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 9:263 294.. 1995. Discrimination, Default, and Loss in FHA Mortgage Lending. Paper presented at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Annual Meeting. Karr, A. January 26, 1995. Fed Study Challenges Notion of Bias Against Minorities in Mortgage Lending, Wall Street Journal, p. A12. Munnell, A., L. Browne, J. McEneaney, and G. Tootell. 1992. Mortgage Lending in Boston: Interpreting HMDA Data. Working paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Rachlis, M., and A. Yezer. 1993. Serious Flaws in Statistical Tests for Discrimination in Mortgage Markets, Journal of Housing Research 4:315 336. Ross, S. Forthcoming. Mortgage Lending Discrimination and Racial Differences in Loan Default, Journal of Housing Research.. 1994. Mortgage Lending Discrimination and Racial Differences in Loan Performance. Working paper. University of Connecticut. Yezer, A., R. Phillips, and R. Trost. 1994. Bias in Estimates of Discrimination and Default in Mortgage Lending: The Effects of Simultaneity and Self-Selection, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 9:197 216. 48 Cityscape