FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. July 24, 2003



Similar documents
Antitrust Law & Economics: Exclusionary Behavior, Bundled Discounts, and Refusals to Deal

Do Gasoline Pricing Laws Affect Prices? It Depends on the Plaintiff

AMD v. Intel: An Assault on Price Competition

Antitrust in the Digital Age: How Enduring Competition Principles Enforced by the Federal Trade Commission Apply to Today s Dynamic Marketplace

Syllabus -- Franchise and Distribution Law/Professor Devlin/Fall 2006

JURY INSTRUCTIONS. 2.4 Willful Maintenance of Monopoly Power

RANKING EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT. By Susan Creighton. Director, Bureau of Competition. Federal Trade Commission. Fall Forum, November 15, 2005

COMMISSION AUTHORIZED

STATEMENT BY ASSISTANT ATTORNEY GENERAL R. HEWITT PATE REGARDING THE CLOSING OF THE WESTERN UNION MONEY TRANSFER INVESTIGATION

Research Ideas in Antitrust and Consumer Protection: A View from the FTC

COMMENTS OF THE ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW REGARDING

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE

Department Of Justice Washington, DC September 20, 1996

Click to edit Master title style

Market Definition Does Not Yield Evidence of Class-Wide Impact

Case 3:13-cv FLW-TJB Document 18 Filed 05/30/14 Page 1 of 31 PageID: 157 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF NEW JERSEY

PACIFIC BELL TELEPHONE COMPANY, DBA AT&T CALI- FORNIA, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. LINKLINE COMMUNICA- TIONS, INC., ET AL. No

Private anti-trust remedies under US law

Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP and the Scope of Antitrust Protection for Telecommunications

CPI Antitrust Chronicle Sep 2014 (1)

Internal Revenue Service

REPLY COMMENTS OF THE STAFF OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION(1)

United States Court of Appeals

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases

Going Vertical: The Hospital-Health Insurer Merger. By Christi J. Braun 1 Farrah Short

VIRGINIA: IN THE CIRCUIT COURT OF SOUTHWESTERN COUNTY 1

for Private Purchasers Engaged in Value Purchasing of Health Care

Case 3:07-cv MLC-JJH Document 80 Filed 09/10/2008 Page 1 of 15

2015 IADC Mid-Year Meeting. Marco Island, Florida. Medical Liability and Health Law Committee Meeting

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No D.C. Docket No. 0:09-cv PCH. versus

PRODUCT LIABILITY INSTRUCTIONS. Introduction

Number: Release Date: 9/8/2006 Internal Revenue Service. Department of the Treasury Washington, DC Index Number: 162.

JEFFREY AXELRAD S PRESENTATION FOR FDA TASK FORCE APRIL 14, 200 PUBLIC MEETING REGARDING IMPORTATION OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS

Asbestos Liability Unlikely For Replacement Parts

FEDERAL CIRCUIT HOLDS THAT HEIGHTENED PLEADING REQUIREMENTS APPLY TO FALSE MARKING ACTIONS

September 30, 2002 INTERNAL REVENUE SERVICE NATIONAL OFFICE STRATEGIC ADVICE

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF DENNIS CARLTON REGARDING PRICE CAPS FOR NEW gtld INTERNET REGISTRIES. March 2009

October 9, Honorable Orrin G. Hatch United States Senate Washington, DC Dear Senator:

the Code of Civil Procedure (Code) (735 ILCS 5/2-619 (West 2004)) of their claim that

A (800) (800)

Economics Chapter 7 Review

PREPARED STATEMENT OF MAUREEN K. OHLHAUSEN DIRECTOR, OFFICE OF POLICY PLANNING FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. before the ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMMISSION

Much Ado About Injury: Making Sense Of FTAIA Circuit Split

Interpretive Letter #835

Testimony of. J. Douglas Richards Partner, Cohen Milstein Sellers & Toll, PLLC

2:11-cv AC-RSW Doc # 21 Filed 02/03/12 Pg 1 of 7 Pg ID 331 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF MICHIGAN SOUTHERN DIVISION

Case: Document: Page: 1 Date Filed: 09/09/2009 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT. No.

Case 2:06-cv CM Document 114 Filed 03/10/09 Page 1 of 10 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF KANSAS

---X. Plaintiffs, Civ. No (Weinstein, J.) -against- MEMORANDUM OF LAW OF THE STATE C F NEW YORK AS AMICUS CURIA.:,

DOL Whistleblower Rule Will Have Far-Reaching Effects

How To Defend Yourself In A Court Case Against A Trust

Are Employee Drug Tests Going Up in Smoke?

SLIP OP UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION

A Note on Loyalty Discounts

Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Joshua D. Wright In the Matter of Fidelity National Financial, Inc. and Lender Processing Services, Inc.

ENERGISTICS CONSORTIUM, INC. ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE POLICY

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES STAFF ANALYSIS REFERENCE ACTION ANALYST STAFF DIRECTOR

LePage s, Cascade Health Solutions, and a Bundle of Confusion: What Is a Discounter To Do?

COMMENTS OF THE BUREAUS OF COMPETITION, CONSUMER PROTECTION, AND ECONOMICS OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. Washington, D.C February 23.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE Washington, DC Washington, DC September 20, 1996

Case 1:05-cv RAE Doc #47 Filed 11/10/05 Page 1 of 7 Page ID#<pageID> UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT WESTERN DISTRICT OF MICHIGAN SOUTHERN DIVISION

CC:DOM:FI&P:4/PLR October 27, 1998

Illinois Official Reports

Group Purchasing Organization (GPO) Purchasing Agreements and Antitrust Law

SUPREME COURT OF THE STATE OF ARIZONA

REPORT FOR THE HEARING in Case E-1/97

GUIDE FOR TAX REPORTING AND WITHHOLDING OF SETTLEMENT AWARDS

Proving Damages Suffered in a Fraud Case. Ralph Q. Summerford, CPA, ABV, CFE, CFF, CIRA Forensic Strategic Solutions, PC

Case 5:11-cv TBR Document 18 Filed 07/19/11 Page 1 of 8 PageID #: 1349

ARNOLD PORTER LLP. Realcomp II, Ltd. ADVISORY

FOCUS of 497 DOCUMENTS

The Florida Department of Agriculture and Consumer Services (FDACS) states:

F I L E D July 17, 2013

Automobile Negligence Lawsuits

Pay-for-Delay: How Drug Company Pay-Offs Cost Consumers Billions. An FTC Staff Study January Federal Trade Commission ftc.

UNDERSTANDING ANTITRUST LAWS

In the Indiana Supreme Court

In The Court of Appeals Fifth District of Texas at Dallas. No CV

Appendix 14.2 History of Tobacco Product Litigation

IN THE MISSOURI COURT OF APPEALS WESTERN DISTRICT

ERISA Causes of Action *

IN THE COMMONWEALTH COURT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

New Hampshire Association for Justice Focus on Workers Compensation Law

INTRODUCTION OLIGOPOLY CHARACTERISTICS OF MARKET STRUCTURES DEGREES OF POWER DETERMINANTS OF MARKET POWER

Summary of State "Price Gouging" Statutes and Regulations*

Case 2:14-cv TS Document 45 Filed 05/11/15 Page 1 of 9 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF UTAH

BRB No ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

Caregiver Discrimination. by Patti J. Skoglund

NEGLIGENCE PER SE II. BACKGROUND. Richard B. Kilpatrick*

The Attorney General focuses on two New York Statutes: Executive Law 63(12) The New York Consumer Protection Act, Article 22-A of the New York

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF FLORIDA TALLAHASSEE DIVISION. v. CASE NO. 4:13cv664-RH/CAS ORDER ON THE MERITS

SILVER ALERT INITIATIVES IN THE STATES

March 18, Dear XXXX:

How To Sue Allstate Insurance Company

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF THE STATE OF ILLINOIS

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF TENNESSEE WESTERN DIVISION

Case 4:13-cv Document 40 Filed in TXSD on 02/26/15 Page 1 of 6 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF TEXAS HOUSTON DIVISION

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No D.C. Docket No. 9:13-cv RNS. versus

Transcription:

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WASHINGTON, D.C. 20580 The Honorable Eliot Spitzer Attorney General 120 Broadway New York, New York 10271-0332 July 24, 2003 Dear General Spitzer: The staffs of the Federal Trade Commission s Office of Policy Planning and Bureau of Competition are pleased to respond to your request, sent to us on July 1, 2003 by Assistant Attorney General Richard Grimm, for comments on New York s Motor Fuel Marketing Practices Act ( MFMPA ), Bill Nos. A.8398 and S.4947. 1 The MFMPA would prohibit refiners and nonrefiners of motor fuel from selling motor fuels below 98% of the bill s definition of refiner and nonrefiner cost, respectively, where the effect is to injure competition. We believe that there is a significant risk that the MFMPA could harm consumers. Last August, FTC staff submitted comments to Governor Pataki on a virtually identical bill, S.4522-B, which the governor ultimately vetoed. In those comments (copy attached), FTC staff concluded that the bill was at best unnecessary and at worst could discourage pro-competitive pricing. The current bill suffers from the same flaws. The changes banning sales below 98% of cost, rather than cost, and creating a de minimis exception do not correct the fundamental problems in the previous bill. In particular, the 98% measure appears arbitrary, with no basis in Supreme Court precedent, federal antitrust law, basic economic theory, or empirical studies. Moreover, the de minimis exception, while better than no exception at all, still appears too narrow to allow vigorous competition. Our views on the entire bill are summarized below: Low prices benefit consumers. Consumers are harmed only if, because of low prices, a dominant competitor is able later to raise prices to supracompetitive levels. See Attached Letter at 6-7. 1 This letter expresses the views of the Federal Trade Commission s Bureau of Competition and Office of Policy Planning. The letter does not necessarily represent the views of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. The Commission has, however, voted to authorize us to submit these comments. 1

Economic and legal studies and court decisions indicate that below-cost pricing that leads to monopoly rarely occurs. Below-cost sales of motor fuel that lead to monopoly are especially unlikely. See Attached Letter at 8-11. The federal antitrust laws deal specifically with below-cost pricing that has a dangerous probability of leading to monopoly. The FTC, the Department of Justice s Antitrust Division, state attorneys general, and private parties can bring suit under the federal antitrust laws in response to anticompetitive below-cost pricing. See Attached Letter at 5-6. When there is no danger that a monopoly might later be created, consumers are harmed by public policies that have the effect of increasing low prices that are the product of the competitive process. See Attached Letter at 7-8. The MFMPA has the potential to discourage pro-competitive price reductions. Under the bill s definition of competition, a supplier likely could face antitrust liability for pricing below a single competitor, even if consumers benefit from the lower prices and even if there is no risk that the supplier could recoup its lost profits. Moreover, the 98% of cost measure appears arbitrary, while the MFMPA s de minimis exception appears too narrow to allow vigorous competition. Analysis of the MFMPA The MFMPA bans fuel sales below 98% of the nonrefiner or refiner cost, where the effect is to injure competition. The Act defines competition as the vying for motor fuel sales between any two or more sellers in the same relevant geographic market. The Act defines Refiner Cost as the refiner s posted terminal price of motor fuel adjusted for several factors, including taxes, freight charges, direct labor costs, and imputed rental value of the refiner s retail outlet. It defines Nonrefiner Cost as the invoice cost of motor fuel, adjusted for the same factors. A. The MFMPA s definition of competition As the Supreme Court has recognized, federal antitrust laws are designed for the protection of competition, not competitors. 2 The federal antitrust laws recognize that price-cutting benefits consumers and competition, because it forces producers to minimize costs and prices, and to increase quality. Vigorous price competition promotes consumer welfare, because consumers reap the benefits of lower prices, increased productivity, greater variety, and higher quality goods and services. Accordingly, low prices, and even below-cost prices, do not harm consumers unless sustained above-cost prices can occur later on: 2 Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1977) (quoting Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962)). 2

[T]he short-run loss is definite, but the long-run gain depends on successfully neutralizing the competition. Moreover, it is not enough simply to achieve monopoly power, as monopoly pricing may breed quick entry by new competitors eager to share in the excess profits. The success of any predatory scheme depends on maintaining monopoly power for long enough both to recoup the predator s losses and to harvest some additional gain. 3 Therefore, even if a below-cost pricing strategy succeeds in temporarily reducing the number of competitors, the price-cutter must find a way to keep competitors from returning after it tries to raise prices again. Otherwise, the below-cost pricing strategy, which requires that the firm incur losses on every sale, will not succeed. When a firm fails to recoup short-run losses (from sales at below-cost prices) in the long run, consumers enjoy a windfall, and without harm to consumers, an antitrust violation does not occur. Along these lines, the Supreme Court has stated that [t]he second prerequisite to holding a competitor liable under the [federal] antitrust laws for charging low prices is a demonstration that the competitor had a reasonable prospect, or, under 2 of the Sherman Act, a dangerous probability, of recouping its investment in below-cost prices....evidence of below-cost pricing is not alone sufficient to permit an inference of probable recoupment and injury to competition....although unsuccessful predatory pricing may encourage some inefficient substitution toward the product being sold at less than its cost, unsuccessful predation is in general a boon to consumers....that belowcost pricing may impose painful losses on its target is of no moment to the antitrust laws if competition is not injured. 4 Like the previous bill, however, the MFMPA defines competition in a way that likely would focus on protecting competitors, not consumers and competition. The bill defines competition as the vying for motor fuel sales between any two or more sellers in the same relevant geographic market. In other states, courts have interpreted similar definitions of harm to competition to include harm to a single competitor. 5 As Governor Pataki stated, because of this significant flaw, a below-cost sale as defined by the MFMPA could constitute a violation so long as the effect was to injure even a single competitor. 6 As a result, the MFMPA is likely to discourage pro-competitive pricecutting, which in turn could ultimately harm consumers by increasing the prices they pay at the pump for gasoline. B. The MFMPA s arbitrary 98% of cost measure In addition to defining competition in a way that does not protect competition or consumers, the MFMPA defines cost in a way that is inconsistent with most antitrust precedent and economic and legal literature. The Supreme Court has defined predatory pricing as pricing below an appropriate measure of [the defendant s] cost for the 3 Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 589 (1986). 4 Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224, 226 (1993). 5 See, e.g., McGuire Oil Co. v. Mapco, Inc., 612 So. 2d 417 (Ala. 1992); Racetrac Petroleum, Inc. v. Delco Oil, Inc., 721 So. 2d 376 (Fla. App. 1998). 6 See Veto letter at 1 (copy attached). 3

purpose of eliminating competitors in the short run and reducing competition in the long run. 7 Although the Court has not stated what the appropriate measure of cost should be, prominent antitrust scholars and several federal circuit courts have concluded that the price-cutter s marginal costs, or a close proxy such as average variable costs, should be the yardstick. Many authorities conclude that average variable cost is the best yardstick, for two reasons. First, a price at or above average variable cost is highly unlikely to drive efficient competitors from the market. Once a firm has invested in fixed assets (such as a service station), it is economically rational for the firm to continue operating as long as it can cover its variable costs, even if prevailing prices sometimes fall below average total cost. Second, a firm can price at average variable cost due to a wide variety of market circumstances; penalizing a firm for doing so would therefore penalize pro-competitive price cutting. 8 The MFMPA, however, defines refiner and nonrefiner cost to include costs other than average variable costs, including factors such as direct labor costs and the imputed rental value of the retail outlet. 9 By including these factors, the MFMPA (like the previous bill) defines cost in a way that is higher than economically sensible, which could have the effect of deterring pro-competitive price-cutting. Although the bill tries to separate direct labor costs attributable to motor fuel sales from other sales, and thereby to approximate average variable costs for motor fuel sales, as a practical matter, this figure would be very difficult (and expensive) for retailers to calculate. For these reasons, the MFMPA s definition of cost would deter pro-competitive price-cutting. Finally, the MFMPA s use of a 98% measure appears completely arbitrary. FTC staff could locate no support for the 98% measure from any authority on competition policy, including Supreme Court precedent, federal antitrust law, basic economic theory, or empirical studies. Nothing suggests that the 98% measure would benefit consumers or promote competition. Moreover, that measure does nothing to address the MFMPA s more fundamental problem, which is that it defines cost inappropriately. 7 Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 117 (1986). 8 See Kelco Disposal, Inc. v. Browning-Ferris Indus., 845 F.2d 404, 407 (2d Cir. 1988), aff d on other grounds, 492 U.S. 257 (1989) (finding that [p]rices that are below reasonably anticipated marginal cost, and its surrogate, reasonably anticipated average variable cost... are presumed predatory ); International Air Indus. v. American Excelsior Co., 517 F.2d 714, 724 (5th Cir. 1975) (holding that plaintiff must show that either (1) a competitor is charging a price below his average variable cost... or (2) the competitor is charging a price below its short-run, profit maximizing price and barriers to entry are great enough to enable the discriminator to reap the benefits of predation before new entry is possible ); P. Areeda and H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, 724; P. Areeda and D. Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 697 (1975). In Brooke Group, the parties both agreed that average variable cost should be the appropriate measure. See Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 222 n.1. 9 Labor costs can be considered variable if the number of hours worked varies with the level of sales. For large changes in sales this may occur, but for small changes it is unlikely that labor costs will vary with the level of sales. In addition, the legislation specifies that the labor cost included in the cost calculation must at a minimum include the cost of one full-time employee, which effectively treats at least a portion of labor costs as fixed costs. 4

C. The MFMPA s de minimis exception The second principal difference between the MFMPA and S.4522-B is the creation of a de minimis exception. The bill would grant authority to the state consumer protection board to dismiss complaints that, in the board s view, result from a de minimis injury to competition. As a practical matter, however, the exception likely would not encourage pro-competitive price cutting, and instead likely would simply increase uncertainty about the scope of the bill s below-cost sales ban. This uncertainty, in turn, could lead to higher prices for consumers. The bill provides no guidance to the consumer protection board or to suppliers about how to evaluate de minimis injuries. There is no information about how much of an injury, in terms of dollar amount or percentage of sales, should be considered de minimis, nor is there any information on whether an injury to a single competitor should be considered de minimis (the bill s text suggests that injury to one competitor would constitute a violation of the MFMPA, even if there are dozens of competitors in the relevant geographic market). The MFMPA s narrow, ambiguously defined de minimis exception would not encourage vigorous competition. Accordingly, it does not alleviate the significant risk that the bill could harm consumers. Conclusion For these reasons, and the reasons outlined in the attached letter, FTC staff concludes that this version of the MFMPA, like its predecessor, is more likely to harm than to promote competition. Sincerely, Todd J. Zywicki Director Office of Policy Planning Joseph J. Simons Director Bureau of Competition 5