IN THE DEFERRED ANNUITIES MARKET, THE PORTION OF FIXED- RATE ANNUITIES in annual



Similar documents
arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 25 Aug 2011

Valuation of Equity-Linked Insurance Products and Practical Issues in Equity Modeling. March 12, 2013

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

BUYER'S GUIDE TO EQUITY-INDEXED ANNUITIES WHAT ARE THE DIFFERENT KINDS OF ANNUITY CONTRACTS?

Underlying (S) The asset, which the option buyer has the right to buy or sell. Notation: S or S t = S(t)

Living to 100: Survival to Advanced Ages: Insurance Industry Implication on Retirement Planning and the Secondary Market in Insurance

An Introduction to Exotic Options

TABLE OF CONTENTS. A. Put-Call Parity 1 B. Comparing Options with Respect to Style, Maturity, and Strike 13

Goals. Options. Derivatives: Definition. Goals. Definitions Options. Spring 2007 Lecture Notes Readings:Mayo 28.

Loaded Participation Rates for Equity-Indexed Annuities

Management of Asian and Cliquet Option Exposures for Insurance Companies: SPVA applications (I)

Forward Price. The payoff of a forward contract at maturity is S T X. Forward contracts do not involve any initial cash flow.

Fixed Deferred Annuities

Pricing American Options without Expiry Date

Chapter 14 Review Note Sample Excerpt

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

More Exotic Options. 1 Barrier Options. 2 Compound Options. 3 Gap Options

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

BUYER S GUIDE TO FIXED DEFERRED ANNUITIES. The face page of the Fixed Deferred Annuity Buyer s Guide shall read as follows:

Hedging Variable Annuity Guarantees

BINOMIAL OPTIONS PRICING MODEL. Mark Ioffe. Abstract

Oscillatory Reduction in Option Pricing Formula Using Shifted Poisson and Linear Approximation

S 1 S 2. Options and Other Derivatives

Computational Finance Options

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives

Finance 436 Futures and Options Review Notes for Final Exam. Chapter 9

Important Information about your Annuity Investment

Consumer s Guide to. Fixed Deferred Annuities

Mathematical Finance

Options Markets: Introduction

Equity Indexed Annuities Look Before You Leap

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach

Introduction to Options

Important Information about your Annuity

Valuation of the Surrender Option Embedded in Equity-Linked Life Insurance. Brennan Schwartz (1976,1979) Brennan Schwartz

Options 1 OPTIONS. Introduction

Options CHAPTER 7 INTRODUCTION OPTION CLASSIFICATION

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

A SNOWBALL CURRENCY OPTION

BUYER S GUIDE TO FIXED DEFERRED ANNUITIES WITH APPENDIX FOR EQUITY-INDEXED ANNUITIES

14 Greeks Letters and Hedging

Answers to Concepts in Review

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Introduction to Options. Derivatives

LECTURE 9: A MODEL FOR FOREIGN EXCHANGE

The Black-Scholes Formula

Option Values. Determinants of Call Option Values. CHAPTER 16 Option Valuation. Figure 16.1 Call Option Value Before Expiration

CHAPTER 20: OPTIONS MARKETS: INTRODUCTION

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Binary options. Giampaolo Gabbi

American Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan American Options

Understanding fixed index annuities

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

Option Properties. Liuren Wu. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Options Markets. (Hull chapter: 9)

Return to Risk Limited website: Overview of Options An Introduction

ASSESSING THE RISK POTENTIAL OF PREMIUM PAYMENT OPTIONS

Variance swaps and CBOE S&P 500 variance futures

Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application to annuity conversion options

Valuation of Structured Products

Bond Options, Caps and the Black Model

Option Pricing. Chapter 9 - Barrier Options - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 9th December 2013

Fair Valuation and Hedging of Participating Life-Insurance Policies under Management Discretion

Hedging. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Hedging

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

Lecture 6 Black-Scholes PDE

ASSESSING THE RISK POTENTIAL OF PREMIUM PAYMENT OPTIONS IN PARTICIPATING LIFE INSURANCE CONTRACTS

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

Options/1. Prof. Ian Giddy

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Guaranteed Annuity Options

6 Hedging Using Futures

Market and Exercise Price Relationships. Option Terminology. Options Trading. CHAPTER 15 Options Markets 15.1 THE OPTION CONTRACT

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

Exam MFE Spring 2007 FINAL ANSWER KEY 1 B 2 A 3 C 4 E 5 D 6 C 7 E 8 C 9 A 10 B 11 D 12 A 13 E 14 E 15 C 16 D 17 B 18 A 19 D

Quantitative Strategies Research Notes

How To Become A Life Insurance Agent

WHAT YOU DON'T KNOW ABOUT ANNUITIES CAN HURT YOU FINANCIALLY

Understanding Fixed Indexed Annuities

From Binomial Trees to the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formulas

American and European. Put Option

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

Mid-Term Spring 2003

Rolf Poulsen, Centre for Finance, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, SE Gothenburg, Sweden.

Options on an Asset that Yields Continuous Dividends

Numerical Methods for Pricing Exotic Options

Monte Carlo Simulation

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

ANNUITY DISCLOSURE MODEL REGULATION. Standards for the Disclosure Document and Buyer s Guide Report to Contract Owners *****

From Exotic Options to Exotic Underlyings: Electricity, Weather and Catastrophe Derivatives

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

Transcription:

W ORKSHOP B Y H A N G S U C K L E E Pricing Equity-Indexed Annuities Embedded with Exotic Options IN THE DEFERRED ANNUITIES MARKET, THE PORTION OF FIXED- RATE ANNUITIES in annual sales has declined from one-half in 1994 to one-quarter in 1999. This is due in part to relatively low interest rates and a bullish stock market. The new economic environment has led actuaries to design new types of annuity products that link return to stock market performance. One of these products is equity-indexed annuities (EIAs). When a stock index, typically the S&P 500, goes up, EIAs provide policyholders with a rate of return connected to the return of the index. When the index goes down, EIAs provide policyholders with a minimum guaranteed return. HANGSUCK LEE IS A PH.D CANDIDATE IN THE DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS AND ACTUARIAL SCIENCE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF IOWA IN IOWA CITY.THIS PAPER WAS THE WINNER OF THE FIRST U.S. ACTUARIAL PRIZE AWARDED JOINTLY BY SCOR U.S. AND THE COLLEGE OF INSURANCE. HE CAN BE REACHED AT HLEE@STAT.UIOWA.EDU. Since the first offering in 1995, sales of EIAs have rapidly increased. In 1996, 1997, 1998, 1999, and 2000, sales were at $1.5, $3.0, $4.3, $5.1, and $5.4 billion, respectively. There are several reasons for the increasing popularity of EIAs. First, they offer returns that are linked to the performance of an equity index and never fall lower than a minimum guaranteed return (usually 3 percent per annum). EIAs may be the most suitable products for those who normally are reluctant to buy traditional fixed annuities because of low returns and are also reluctant to buy mutual funds and stocks for fear of high volatility in the stock market. Second, EIAs may serve as tax deferral investment vehicles and possess a tax advantage relative to mutual funds and other bank products. Third, EIAs also appeal to insurance companies and agents because companies selling them don t have to register with the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and agents don t need a special license to sell them. However, pricing, hedging, and reserving EIAs are challenging problems due to the complex payoff structure. Although insurers have experience in managing interest risk and mortality risk, the minimum guarantees related to the equity market are relatively new to them. Unlike traditional life products, EIAs cannot be hedged through diversification. First of all, pricing EIAs is the prerequisite for hedging and reserving them. Evaluating the guarantee embedded in an EIA is difficult and often requires advanced stochastic modeling techniques. Two key factors for pricing EIAs are participation rate and indexing method. The participation rate is the percentage of the index return to be credited. Thus, the insurance company credits the EIA policy either the index return times the participation rate or a minimum guaranteed return, whichever is greater. For example, if we assume that the index return is 20 percent, the participation rate is 90 percent, and the minimum guaranteed return is 15 percent, then the actual return credited to the policy will be 18 percent. An indexing method is the method the insurer uses to calculate the index return based on the index values in the contract term. There are several indexing methods such as point-to-point, Asian, lookback, and annual reset. A point-to-point EIA, for example, measures the index increment from the start to the end of a contract term. The increment divided by the start index is the index return. As pointed out in Tiong s paper Valuing Equity- Indexed Annuities, sales of EIAs rapidly increased since the first offering, but growth rate has recently shown signs of slowing down because the current volatile equity market increases the costs of guarantees in the EIAs and hence decreases the participation rates. Thus, new EIAs with higher participation rates need to be designed EIAs that are similar to existing ones and have a cheaper guarantee such as that provided by a barrier option or a partial lookback option. To make EIAs more attractive to customers, I propose three types of EIAs with higher participation rates: a barrier EIA, an annual reset EIA with barrier, and a partial lookback EIA. In addition, I shall pre- BONOTOM STUDIO, INC. 34 Contingencies January/February 2002

Although insurers have experience in managing interest risk and mortality risk, the minimum guarantees related to the equity market are relatively new to them. Unlike traditional life products, EIAs cannot be hedged through diversification. sent pricing formulas for them, using the method of Esscher transforms under a Black-Scholes framework. Probability Distributions and Esscher Transforms The payoffs of the proposed EIAs depend on the underlying index value and the maximum index value for a specified term. This section describes joint probability distributions and the method of Esscher transforms necessary for pricing them. Let S(t) denote the time-t price of an equity index. Assume that the index is constructed with all dividends reinvested. Assume that for t 0, S(t) = S(0)e X(t) where {X(t)} is a Brownian motion with drift µ, diffusion coefficient σ and X(0) = 0. Thus X(t) has a normal distribution with mean µt and variance σ 2 t. Let M(t) = max{x(τ), 0 t t} (2.1) be the maximum of the Brownian motion between time 0 and time t. It is known that for x m and m 0, Pr(X(t) x, M(t) m = Φ ( x µt 2µ2 ) e σ m Φ( x 2m µt ) (2.2) σ t σ t where φ 2 (.) denotes the standard normal distribution function. Furthermore, in pricing the partial lookback and barrier EIAs, it s useful to know the joint distribution function of random variables M(t) and X(T), 0 < t T, Pr(M(t) m, X(T) x) (2.3) = Φ 2 ( x µt, m µt ; t 2µ ) e σ 2 m, Φ 2 ( x 2m µt, m µt ; t ), T T σ T σ t σ t σ t where Φ 2 (a, b; ρ) denotes the bivariate standard normal distribution function. Finally, Gerber and Shiu (1994, 1996) developed a special case of the method of Esscher transforms. For a nonzero real number h, the moment generating function of X(t), E[e hx(t) ] exists for all t 0, because {X(t)} is the Brownian motion as described above. The stochastic process {e hx(t) E[e hx(t) ] -1 } is a positive martingale, which can be used to define a new probability measure Q. In technical terms, the process is used to define the Radon-Nikodym derivative dq/dp, where P is the original probability measure. We call Q the Esscher measure of parameter h. For a random variable Y that is a real-valued function of {X(t), 0 t T}, the expectation of Y under the new probability measure Q is calculated as E[Y ehx(t) ] (2.4) E[e hx(t) ] which will be denoted by E[Y; h]. Note that the process {X(t)} under the Esscher measure of parameter h is a Brownian motion with drift µ + hσ 2 and diffusion coefficient σ. The riskneutral Esscher measure is the Esscher measure of parameter h = h* with respect to which the process {e -rt S(t), 0 t T} is a martingale. Thus, E[e -rt S(t); h*] = S(0). (2.5) Therefore, h* is the solution of µ + h*σ 2 = r σ 2 /2. (2.6) Now, let us consider a special case of the factorization formula (Gerber and Shiu, 1994, p 177, 1996, p 188). For a random variable Y that is a real-valued function of {X(t), 0 t T}, the formula can be derived as follows: E[e X(T) Y; h*] = e rt E[Y; h* + 1]. (2.7) The formula (2.7) will simplify many calculations in pricing the proposed EIAs. Barrier EIA The payoff of a point-to-point EIA depends only on the price of an underlying index on the ending date of the policy. The advantages of the EIA are its simplicity, making it relatively easy to explain the payoff to agents and customers, and good performance in a bullish equity market. However, the payoff will be the same regardless of the path taken by the index to attain its final value. If customers believe that the underlying index will rise above a barrier in a certain period, then they may not want to pay a high premium for the option embedded in a pointto-point EIA and will be reluctant to buy one. The payoffs of barrier options are the same as those of their underlying plain-vanilla options if the path of an underlying asset satisfies an activating condition. Otherwise, they ll be zero. The barrier options are cheaper than their underlying plainvanilla options because the payoffs of the barrier options are less than or equal to those of the plain-vanilla options. Contingencies January/February 2002 35

In addition, sellers of barrier options may be able to limit their risk if they fail in hedging the options, because the payoffs are less volatile than those of their underlying plain-vanilla options. Barrier options have been substantially traded in the over-the-counter market since the late 1980s because they re attractive to both buyers and sellers. To increase the participation rate, let us now apply an upand-in barrier option to new EIAs as alternatives to point-topoint EIAs. The payoff of a barrier EIA is as follows: If the index rises above a barrier in a certain period, the return credited to the policy will be the greater of either a minimum guaranteed return or the index return times the participation rate. If the index doesn t rise, the minimum guaranteed return will be credited. The cost of the option embedded in an EIA is key to increasing the participation rate; the cheaper the option price, the higher the participation rate and therefore the greater the customer s return. Thus, the barrier EIA provides customers with a higher participation rate than pointto-point EIAs. Let s take a close look at the payoff of the barrier EIA with the monitoring period from time 0 to time t (t < T). Assume that the minimum guaranteed return is g for the contract term, the participation rate is α), and the barrier is B. Let u = log[b/s(0)] and k = log(1 + g/α) Then the payoff can be expressed as follows: S(0)[1 + α(e X(T) 1)], if X(T) > k and M(t) > u S(0)(1 + g), otherwise, (3.1) that is, S(0)[α(e X(T) α g)i(x(t) > k, M(t) > u) + (1 + g)], (3.2) where I(.) denotes the indicator function. By the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, the time-0 value of the payoff (3.2) is S(0)e -rt E[(αe X(T) α g)i(x(t) > k, M(t) > u) + (1 + g); h*] = S(0)[α e rt E[e X(T) I(X(T) > k, M(t) > u); h*] (α + g)e rt Pr(X(T) > k, M(t) > u; h*) + e rt (1+g)]. (3.3) It follows from (2.3) that we have the probability, Pr(X(T) > k, M(t) > u) = Φ 2 ( k µt, u+µt ; t ) + e σ 2µ2 u Φ 2 ( k 2u µt, u µt ; t ) σ T σ t T σ T σ t T =: P 1 (µ). (3.4) Applying the factorization formula (2.7) to the first expectation on the right-hand side of (3.3), the time-0 value of the barrier EIA is S(0)[αP 1 (r + σ 2 /2) (α+ g)e rt P 1 (r σ 2 /2) + e -rt (1+g)]. (3.5) In particular, the time-0 value of the barrier EIA with the monitoring period from time 0 to time T is S(0)[αP 2 (r + σ 2 /2, T) (α+ g)e rt P 2 (r σ 2 /2, T) + e rt (1+g)] =: V(T), (3.6) where P 2 (µ, T) := Φ( u µt 2µ2 ) + e σ u [Φ( u µt ) Φ( k 2u µt )]. σ T σ T σ T Annual Reset EIA with Barrier Unlike point-to-point EIAs, annual reset EIAs measure the annual returns on the index in each policy year and credit the policy annually compounded interest that is the greater of either the annual index return times the participation rate or a minimum guaranteed rate. These EIAs enable customers to profit in years the index goes up and never to lose in years the index goes down. Thus, the annual reset EIAs credit better interest to the policy in a volatile market. A drawback of annual reset EIAs is that the participation rate is relatively low because these EIAs have one embedded option in each policy year. (For numerical values of the participation rate, see Tiong, 2000a, p. 44.) Though actuaries have developed annual reset EIAs with a cap or a spread to increase the participation rate, these EIAs have a disadvantage in that relatively low interest is credited to the policy when the index goes up. Just as we previously applied barrier options to point-topoint EIAs, let us now apply barrier options to annual reset EIAs to increase the participation rates. In each period, the annual reset EIA will provide customers with the greater of either the annual index return times the participation rate or a minimum guaranteed rate if the maximum index value for each period rises above a barrier. Otherwise, the EIA will credit to the policyholder the minimum guaranteed rate as an annual return. Note that the total return is defined as the return plus one (Luenberger, 1998, p. 138). Let M i = max{x(s) X(t i 1 ), t i 1 s t i }, i = 1, 2,..., n (4.1) where t i t i 1 = T/n, t 0 = 0 and t n = T. Assume that the minimum guaranteed rate is g for each period from time t i 1 to time t i, and the participation rate is α for each period. Let k = log(1 + g/α) and u k. Assume X i = X(t i ) X(t i 1 ). Hence, the random vectors (X i, M i ) are independently and identically distributed with the random vector (X(T/n), M(T/n)). The total return of each period is as follows: 1 + α(e Xi 1), if X i > k and M i > u 1 + g, otherwise, (4.2) that is, (αe Xi α g)i(x i > k, M i > u) + (1 + g). (4.3) Thus, the payoff of the annual reset EIA with barrier is S(0)Π n i=1 [(αexi α g)i(x i > k, M i > u) + (1 + g)]. (4.4) 36 Contingencies January/February 2002

By the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, the time-0 value of the payoff (4.4) is calculated as follows: S(0)e rt E[Π n i=1 [(αexi α g)i(x i > k, M i > u) + (1 + g)]; h*] = S(0)Π n e rt/n E[(αe Xi α g)i(x i=1 i > k, M i > u) + (1 + g); h*] = S(0)[V(T/n)] n. (4.5) Partial Lookback EIA A lookback EIA credits the policy the interest based on the maximum index value attained during the life of the policy instead of the index value at maturity. It offers a minimum guaranteed return if the maximum index value is low. Even when the index has a high maximum value but drops substantially at maturity, the lookback EIA provides customers with higher interest than a point-to-point EIA. However, the option embedded in the lookback EIA is more expensive than the option in a point-to-point EIA. For this reason, the participation rate of the lookback EIA is lower than, the pointto-point EIA. Heynen and Kat (1994a) suggest a way of reducing the price of a lookback option while preserving some of its good qualities. The solution, they say, lies in a partial lookback option with a floating strike that has a minimum and increases with the maximum value of an underlying asset. 1/4 SC International Page 37 Contingencies January/February 2002 37

The variable guaranteed return of the EIA will increase with the maximum index value for the monitoring period and will be bounded below by the minimum guaranteed return. If the index return multiplied by the participation rate is bigger than the variable guaranteed return, it will be the return credited to the policy. Otherwise, the EIAs will provide customers with the variable guaranteed return. Let s take a closer look at the payoff of the partial lookback EIA as follows: S(0)[α(e X(T) 1) + 1], if e X(T) > λemax(m(t), L) this is, S(0)[α(λe max(m(t), L) 1) + 1], otherwise, (5.1) S(0)[α(λe max(m(t), L) e X(T) ) + + α(e X(T) 1) + 1], (5.2) where g denotes the minimum guaranteed return for the contract period, L denotes log[(g/α+1)/λ], and λ lies between zero and one, and t T. Note that the variable guaranteed return is α(λe max(m(t), L) 1). By the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, it follows from the payoff (5.2) that the time-0 value of this partial lookback EIA is S(0){α e rt E[(λe max(m(t), L) e X(T) ) + ;h*] + α + e rt (1 α)}. (5.3) Applying conditional expectation with respect to the random variables X(t) and M(t), we can obtain the time-0 value of the partial lookback option embedded in the EIA, e rt E[(λe max(l, M(t)) e X(T) ) + ; h*] = Φ (f 1 ) Φ ( e 1 + log λ ) σ T t + λ 2(µ σ 2+1) σ Φ 2 2 (d 1 + log λ, e1 log λ ; 2r 1 t σ T σ T-t T λ σ2 e rt e 2(µ σ 2+1)L Φ 2 (f 1 2r t, d 1 2r T + log λ ; t. ) 2r σ σ σ T T + λ (1+ σ2 ) e r(t-t) Φ (f 1 ) Φ ( e 2 + log λ ) 2r σ T-t + λe rt e L Φ 2 ( d 2 + log λ, f 2 ; t. ) σ T T Φ 2 ( d 1 + log λ, f 1 ; t. σ T T 1/4 Mid-America Search Page 38 (5.4) where for i = 1 and 2, d i denotes L+(r+( 1)i 1 1 2 σ 2 )T, σ T 38 Contingencies January/February 2002