CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue)



Similar documents
FRAND Commitment - The case against improper antitrust intervention

Department of Justice

IPR Policy as Strategy ISBN: December The Battle to Define the Meaning of FRAND

Observations from the NAS Committee Study on IP Management in SSOs. Keith Maskus Toulouse Conference May 16, 2013

January 8, The U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division (DOJ), and the U.S. Patent &

The Advantages of Annual Patent Patenting

IN THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY HIGH COURT OF JAPAN. Defendant.

FRAND COMMITMENTS THE CASE FOR ANTITRUST INTERVENTION PHILIPPE CHAPPATTE * A. INTRODUCTION

Open Source Code: Understanding and Managing the Risks. May 8, Renee L. Jackson. Christopher K. Larus. When You Think IP,

Valuing Standard Essential Patents in the Knowledge Economy:

Antitrust Risks in Standard-Setting Organizations

FSFE response to Consultation on Patents and Standards: A modern framework for standardisation involving intellectual property rights

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

Knowledge. Practical guide to competition damages claims in the UK

Resolving IP and Technology Disputes Through WIPO ADR. Getting back to business

Business Models of Innovation Closed Innovation and Open Innovation (Topic 7 (c))

Position no. 4/2015 January 2015

CPI Antitrust Chronicle February 2014 (2)

Present Situation of IP Disputes in Japan

BSA GLOBAL CYBERSECURITY FRAMEWORK

A Practical Guide to Patent Policies of Standards Development Organizations

Case 2:15-cv Document 1 Filed 01/14/15 Page 1 of 14 PageID #: 1

ASEAN IPR SME Helpdesk Guide: Protecting your IP at Trade Fairs in Southeast Asia. Contents. 1. Protecting your IP at trade fairs. 2.

Dollars For Genes: Revenue Generation by the California Institute for Regenerative Medicine

patent enforcement, inaccessible. In other words, in some cases, nobody wins. However, there are alternatives to these costly practices.

Marketers must: The Political, Legal, and Regulatory Environments of Global Marketing. Nation-States and Sovereignty. The Political Environment

Board of Software Standardisation and Control (BSSC) Software Intellectual Property Rights and licensing. Uffe K. Mortensen

ENHANCED HOST CONTROLLER INTERFACE SPECIFICATION FOR UNIVERSAL SERIAL BUS (USB) ADOPTERS AGREEMENT

Case 1:14-cv UNA Document 1 Filed 01/17/14 Page 1 of 44 PageID #: 1 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELAWARE

Emerging coordination mechanisms for multi-party IPR holders: Linking Research with Standardization

Program: Master s of Intellectual Property Law (Comprehensive) Syllabus

ETSI Guidelines for Antitrust Compliance Version adopted by Board #81 on 27 January 2011

Intellectual Property. Policy and Procedures

PHOTOGRAPH LICENSE BETWEEN YOU AND DEATH TO THE STOCK PHOTO

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

Patent Litigation with Endogenous Disputes

Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation

Licensing agreements for intellectual property

By post and

Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes

The basics of an Intellectual Property Program

ILNAS/OLN/A001 ILNAS IPR Policy on Patent and Copyright

3. IP Management and Commercialisation Strategy

We believe it is important to distinguish between white hat and black hat patent monetization:

Attached is ACT's amended comments on Patent Applications (78 Fed. Reg. 2). Please use this version and not the version sent earlier this evening.

Intellectual Property The Basis for Venture Capital Investments

IP Litigation in Europe and in Germany

CONTRIBUTION AGREEMENT VERSION 1.1

An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements

CLIENT MEMORANDUM. I. The Basics. June 18, 2013

The Common Public License (CPL)

[Contractor] and. [European Space Agency] ESA Intellectual Property Licence for the Agency s Own Requirements

The Role of Clear SSO Rules and Flexible IPR Policies in Fostering Innovation

PIONEER TELEPHONE COOPERATIVE, INC. PIONEER LONG DISTANCE, INC. CELLULAR NETWORK PARTNERSHIP D/B/A PIONEER CELLULAR TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF SERVICE

CPR Patent Mediation Task Force Findings and Recommendations

Alternative Dispute Resolution

Unjustified threats on intellectual property rights: Government Response

Zope Foundation Trademark License

Mediation: The Big Lie Thursday, 29 January :17 - Last Updated Thursday, 29 January :03

Defining Relevant Markets for Leased Lines: the Interface with Local Loop Unbundling

Chapter 2 Fields of Intellectual Property Protection

Smart TV Alliance Antitrust Policy

Adoption of technical standards by Original Equipment Manufacturers (OEMs) A Proactive approach to Intellectual Property Strategy

Introduction. This answering guide has been prepared in order to make the task of responding to the questionnaire easier for citizens.

High-Tech Patents and High-Caliber Training PROTECTING YOUR IP

Provisions, Contingent Liabilities and Contingent Assets

VOLUNTARY GUIDELINES ON THE GOVERNANCE OF TENURE. At a glance

DENTISTRY, A SUITABLE CASE STUDY FOR ADR CONTENTS

Debt collection in Russia

CONTRACT BASICS. This Fact Sheet has been made possible by the funding received by the Creative People s Centre from the New Zealand Law Foundation.

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment

Commercialization Procedures: Licensing, Spinoffs and Start-ups Yumiko Hamano

Big Risks and Disadvantages of Arbitration vs. Litigation

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB ISSN

Intellectual Property Rights in the USA

Kaiser Permanente Affiliate Link Provider Web Site Application

Marketing Ingenuity and Invention an Innovation Guidebook

Resolution on Consumer Protection in Cloud Computing

Discussion of A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money by Guillermo Baquero and Marno Verbeek. By Chester S.

IN THE MATTER OF AN INTEREST ARBITRATION BETWEEN: The Council of Academic Hospitals of Ontario. and

ALTERNATIVE DISPUTE RESOLUTION IN ADMINISTRATIVE MATTERS

In 2006, the Australian Government requested

prevailing of JAMS/Endispute. The arbitrator's award shall be binding and may be entered as a judgment in any court of competent jurisdiction.

STRATEGIC PATENT ACQUISITIONS

Ibis RMC SOFTWARE LICENSE AGREEMENT v2015

SOUTH CAROLINA. EXCLUSIVE RIGH`T TO REPRESENT BUYER Buyer Agency Agreement [Consult "Guidelines" (Form 201G) for guidance in completing this form]

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA POSTAL REGULATORY COMMISSION WASHINGTON, DC COMMENTS OF THE NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF LETTER CARRIERS, AFL-CIO

CLAIMS AGAINST TELEPHONE ANSWERING SERVICES: THE TRILOGY OF PREVENTION, HANDLING AND RESOLUTION PART TWO: WHAT TO DO WHEN A CLAIM HAPPENS

Overview Software Assurance is an annual subscription that includes: Technical Support, Maintenance and Software Upgrades.

Chapter 8: Open Standards and Intellectual Property Rights. To appear in Open Innovation: Researching a New Paradigm (Oxford University Press)

Investing in Invention TM

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKSHOP AND COMMENT PROCEEDING ON PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES

Intellectual Property Litigation Insurance Proposal Form

Guide to WIPO Services

A Guide to Intellectual Property Management & Commercialisation

STUDENT PRESS LAW CENTER SAMPLE YEARBOOK STAFF MEMBER LICENSE

Comments on the List of Issues from Japan (Traditional Knowledge)

Patents and Standards

USB 3.0 ADOPTERS AGREEMENT

Consumer Protection and Regulatory Changes in the Dodd-Frank Bill

Transcription:

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue) Standard Setting Organizations Can Help Solve the Standard Essential Patents Licensing Problem Kai-Uwe Kühn, Fiona Scott Morton, & Howard Shelanski www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc. 2013 Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone other than the publisher or author.

Standard Setting Organizations Can Help Solve the Standard Essential Patents Licensing Problem Kai-Uwe Kühn, Fiona Scott Morton, & Howard Shelanski 1 I. INTRODUCTION Intellectual property rights were established in both the United States and Europe to protect inventors, to stimulate innovation, and to benefit consumers. We are concerned that specific circumstances affecting some industries like the information and communication technology ( ICT ) sector may limit the effectiveness of intellectual property rights in achieving these goals. In particular, in the case of standard essential patents ( SEPs ), ambiguities in the definition of licensing restrictions as well as weaknesses in the process of intellectual property enforcement appear to contribute to what economists call holdup problems that may threaten innovation incentives and harm consumers. 2 While these problems are generally difficult to resolve, intellectual property policies of standard setting organizations ( SSOs ) could play a special role by setting up intellectual property rights ( IPR ) policies that would limit hold-up more effectively. In this article we propose reforms to the current intellectual property policies that we believe would greatly improve efficiency in patent licensing. II. THE ROLE OF SSOs In the ICT sector, rates of patenting have exploded and with the convergence among communications technology, device hardware, and software products have become more complex. Many of the ICT products and services most valuable to consumers require a common standard for interoperability. For example, UMTS, or 3G, is a standard incorporated into many mobile handsets that allows those handsets to send signals to, or receive them from, towers with UMTS equipment installed. A standard will embody specific technology, which industry participants all employ, to allow interoperability. The creation of such a standard and the choice of technology to include in it is the responsibility of SSOs and their members. Members of an SSO are typically organizations that operate in the industry; membership is voluntary. SSOs usually have established procedures by which they choose a technological path for a standard. That path might involve technology in the public domain, or it might involve patented innovations. If the standard cannot be implemented without practicing (using) a particular patent, the patent is said to be an SEP. 1 Kai-Uwe Kühn, Chief Economist, DG Competition, European Commission; Fiona Scott Morton, former Chief Economist, Antitrust Division, US Department of Justice (2011-12); Howard Shelanski, Director, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission. The views expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Commission, Department of Justice, or Federal Trade Commission. 2 We define the concept of hold-up in detail below. 2

SSOs rules will typically include an IPR policy. Such polices establish what member firms must disclose concerning their IPR and at what point during the standard-setting process; IPR policies also specify what licensing obligations members must commit to should they wish their IPR to be included in the standard. A common licensing restriction requires members to commit to license any IPRs they own that are essential to the standard on Reasonable And Non-Discriminatory terms, or Fair, Reasonable, And Non-Discriminatory terms (collectively, F/RAND terms). SSOs typically specify very little as to the meaning of fair or reasonable, perhaps partially because there is heterogeneity among the firms, technologies, and products within a given SSO. Not surprisingly, there are frequently disputes among different parties about what a reasonable royalty might be for a particular portfolio of intellectual property. SSOs constrain the license terms for SEPs because of the substantial market power necessarily enjoyed by the owner of an SEP in a successful standard. Moreover, this market power is achieved through the joint action of entities the SSO members that might be in competition with each other outside the SSO. This joint action is acceptable for society because it trades off possible technology competition among SSO members for production of a standard that can speed innovation and expand output. III. THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM The risk to society, however, is that once a standard is in place, an SEP owner can use its resulting market power to engage in hold-up. Hold-up occurs when the SEP owner approaches firms practicing the standard after those firms have invested in developing their products that depend on the standard with an onerous licensing demand. Assuming the patent is indeed essential and valid, the firm s product must practice the patent in order to be interoperable, placing the firm in a poor bargaining position. These problems with the existing restrictions on licensing terms arise due to the many uncertainties surrounding both the exact definition of F/RAND offers and the validity of the patent. Potential licensees may claim that the licensing demand is not a F/RAND offer or that the patent is not valid or essential in the first place. However, even when the potential licensee is likely to be correct in the assessment, the owner of the SEP can still make it very costly to resolve such disputes. For example, threatening to engage in expensive litigation, or pursuing an injunction or an exclusion order if the licensee does not pay the requested royalties, creates a powerful incentive for the licensee to settle, even on poor terms. Thus the SEP owner can obtain payment far in excess of the ex ante value of the technology, and appropriate the profits due to the later investments of others. Such behavior raises licensing costs in the industry, distorts markets for innovation and investment, and discourages adoption of standards. In other words, the current processes for resolving disputes on standard essential patents allow the hold-up problem to persist. IV. USING SSOs TO REDUCE THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM SSOs can substantially reduce the problem of hold-up and litigation in this sector by reforming their IPR policies. It is the actions of the SSO, a group of competitors jointly creating the standard, which create SEP market power. They have the responsibility to ensure that this 3

market power is constrained so that consumers can benefit as much as possible from standardsetting activity, and so that SEP owners cannot discourage innovation by engaging in hold-up. In the view of all three of us, many existing SSO policies are not strong or clear enough to achieve the above goals reliably or efficiently. In particular, we believe that stronger commitments to a clearer F/RAND licensing process can go a long way towards mitigating holdup problems, reducing litigation costs, and speeding innovation. Any F/RAND commitment should also be understood to include a commitment to certain processes of dispute resolution and transfer of F/RAND obligations. In this spirit we propose the following improvements to current IPR policies of SSOs: IPR policies should create as strong a commitment as possible to bind future owners of the IPR to any F/RAND commitments made to the SSO. Clearly a F/RAND commitment that becomes weaker or more vague upon the sale of a patent (or undermines a commitment to effective dispute resolution) will not to be as effective in protecting consumers as one in which all F/RAND obligations must be transferred in a sale. A F/RAND commitment should include a process that is faster and lower cost for determining a F/RAND rate, or adjudicating disputes over F/RAND, than litigation. The expensive nature of litigation creates frictions in the market for ideas, is a high transaction cost for licensees, and renders this market less accessible for smaller firms. Each SSO can consider alternatives (even if leaving litigation as one possible option) that it thinks will work well for its members and technologies. The types of solutions we have in mind, without meaning to suggest that any one is the right solution in any particular instance, include arbitration and alternative dispute resolution within the SSO. These procedures could be made more efficient by the SSO defining, for example, the specification of the base to which a royalty should apply or other factors that would simplify the assessment as to whether a particular licensing offer is F/RAND. The goal we have in mind is that a third party, such as a judge or arbitrator, should be able to quickly and cost-effectively determine whether an offer is F/RAND. The F/RAND dispute resolution process should require that the licensor specify a cash price for its SEPs as an alternative to other pricing arrangements to aid in evaluation of the proposed license terms by the third party. Determining if a complex package of crosslicenses satisfies F/RAND is difficult for a third party. If the licensee has the option to choose a F/RAND cash price, but instead chooses to cross-license, then clearly it is better off. The F/RAND commitment should include a process that SEP owners must follow before they can seek an injunction or exclusion order by the licensor. This process would include specifying what steps must be taken by parties to resolve disputes over a F/RAND s rate, validity, essentiality, or infringement before an injunction or an exclusion order may be sought against the licensee. Reducing the ability of licensors to threaten to exclude a product from the market will reduce the ability of the licensor to extract royalties above the F/RAND rate and other significant licensing conditions from willing licensees. The essence of the F/RAND commitment is that the firm has voluntarily chosen to accept royalties rather than pursue a business model based on exclusion. This suggests that there 4

can be no irreparable harm from the use of the SEP. Limits on the use of injunctions or exclusion orders are therefore appropriate. 5