Medical Innovation: A Challenge to Society and Insurance



Similar documents
Economics 4259: Economics of Health Services Grading and Assignments

Prevention and Private Health Insurance in the UK

Prevention and Private Health Insurance in the U.K.

VOLUNTARY HEALTH INSURANCE AS A METHOD OF HEALTH CARE FINANCING IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

The national debate over health reform in recent years. Employment-based health benefits in small and large private establishments.

The Role of a Public Health Insurance Plan in a Competitive Market Lessons from International Experience. Timothy Stoltzfus Jost

Role of government, social health insurers, and private health insurers

Institut d'économie appliquée. Health and Labor Economics (Public)

Medical Progress and Supplementary Private Health Insurance

THE EFFECT OF THE TAX LAWS ON HEALTH INSURANCE AND MEDICAL COSTS. Statement by. Alice M. Rivlin Director Congressional Budget Office.

ECONOMICS INTERACTIONS WITH OTHER DISCIPLINES Vol. I - Costs of Health Care Throughout the World - R.E. Santerre

ECONOMICS FOR HEALTH POLICY

Social Security 44th Edition

Background Briefing. Hungary s Healthcare System

Age and Choice in Health Insurance: Evidence from Switzerland

Life & Health Insurance Advisor

Chapter 8: Just in Case Additional Material

SPECIAL QUESTIONS. August 26, 2014

The Experience of Switzerland and the Netherlands with Individual Health Insurance Mandates: A Model for the United States? Timothy Stoltzfus Jost

Demand and supply of health insurance. Folland et al Chapter 8

HEALTH INSURANCE COVERAGE AND ADVERSE SELECTION

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

Government Intervention in Health Insurance Markets

Managed care has attracted considerable interest as a possible way to

Executive Summary... 1 The Ancillary Costs of Smoking Ancillary Costs v. External Costs The Decision to Smoke... 3

Health Care Reform: Major Provisions and Bargaining Strategies for Retirees

The Supply of Medical Care, The Market for Health Insurance and Market Competition. Lecture 25. Economics 157 Health Economics Summer 2003

Committee on Ways and Means Subcommittee on Health U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing on Examining Traditional Medicare s Benefit Design

Mandatory Private Health Insurance as Supplementary Financing

Out of pocket costs in Australian health care Supplementary submission

MGMT 298D and PUBPLC 290 Health Care Finance and Management Spring 2014 Syllabus: Revised 2/14/2014

The case for risk-based premiums in public health insurance

Insurance Markets Ready or Not: Consumers Face New Health Insurance Choices. Employer-based. Insurance Premium. Contribution.

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

findings brief New Research Highlights Effects of Medigap Reform

Using Partial Capitation as an Alternative to Shared Savings to Support Accountable Care Organizations in Medicare

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER

HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED?

Chapter 11 SUPPLEMENTARY FINANCING OPTION (4) VOLUNTARY PRIVATE HEALTH INSURANCE. Voluntary Private Health Insurance as Supplementary Financing

Medicare Advantage: The overlooked cornerstone of healthcare reform

Medicines Benefits in Korea

DRUG COVERAGE INSURANCE AS A NOVEL ELEMENT OF PRIVATE HEALTH INSURANCE IN POLAND

Summer Mind the gap. Income protection gap study Western Europe

2015 Benefit Chart of Medicare Supplement Plans Outline of Coverage mhinsurance.com

Statement of Dan L. Crippen Director Congressional Budget Office. on The Financial Status of Medicare

Introduction. What is Transparency in Health Care?

Canadian Doctors for Medicare Neat, Plausible, and Wrong: The Myth of Health Care Unsustainability February 2011

Choosing the Right Health Insurance Plan What is the different between PPO, HMO, POS and HSA plans?

PHYSICIANS th St. NW, Suite 800, Washington DC

Course Description: 1) Health insurance

Basic, including 100% Part B coinsurance. Foreign Travel Emergency

Pension reforms in the UK: what can be learned from other countries?

Medicare Supplement Coverage

Summary: Health Care spending in Massachusetts: To: Mass Care. From: Gerald Friedman 1

Econ 149: Health Economics Problem Set IV (Extra credit) Answer Key

Comparative Health Care Systems. Folland et al Chapters 22

A Conversation About Medicare Part A, B, C and D

Learning Objectives 26. What Is Insurance? 3. Coverage Concepts 8. Types of Insurance 10. Types of Insurers 11. Introduction 26

Health Insurance / Learning Targets

Basic, including 100% Part B coinsurance. Skilled Nursing Facility Coinsuranc e Part A Deductible Part B

Private Health Insurance Options in Egypt Discussion with EISA Chairman and senior staff

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Our paper in the Fall 1996 issue of

Why a Floating Exchange Rate Regime Makes Sense for Canada

POLICYBRIEF. By John Garen, Ph.D.

The Cypriot Pension System: Adequacy and Sustainability

Understanding Medicare Fundamentals

Evaluating and Comparing Health Coverage

Demand for and Supply of Supplementary Health Insurance in Shanghai Wen Chen 1, Xiaohua Ying 1, Shanlian Hu 1, Guozhen Sun 2, Li Luo 1, Wenwei Tang 2

How Can We Bend the Cost Curve? Risk-Adjusting the Doughnut Hole to Improve Efficiency and Equity

Although managed-care health

Decoding the language of health-care financing: a primer

Health Care Reform without the Individual Mandate

Glossary. Adults: Individuals ages 19 through 64. Allowed amounts: See prices paid. Allowed costs: See prices paid.

Thinking of introducing social health insurance? Ten questions

An explanation of social assistance, pension schemes, insurance schemes and similar concepts

Health Insurance. A Small Business Guide. New York State Insurance Department

)LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\

What can China learn from Hungarian healthcare reform?

HEALTHCARE FINANCE: AN INTRODUCTION TO ACCOUNTING AND FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT. Online Appendix B Operating Indicator Ratios

IIB. ECONOMIC ISSUES IN THE PRESIDENTIAL CAMPAIGN

Senate-Passed Bill (Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act H.R. 3590)**

A Guide to Understanding Medicare Benefits

100% of Medicare-eligible expenses Beyond the additional 365 $0 $0 $0 $0

WILL HEALTH CARE REFORM CAUSE EMPLOYERS TO DROP THEIR EMPLOYEE HEALTH CARE PLANS?

Commission on the Future of Health and Social Care in England. The UK private health market

What we ll be discussing

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

Adapting Pharmaceutical Reimbursement Policies to Manage Spending on High-Cost Drugs

Legislative Council Panel on Health Services Subcommittee on Health Protection Scheme

Submission to the Private Health Insurance

The Psychotherapeutic Professions in Switzerland. Ulrich Schnyder & Peter Schulthess

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem

Texas Department of Insurance

Introduction of a national health insurance scheme

Coinsurance A percentage of a health care provider's charge for which the patient is financially responsible under the terms of the policy.

The Impact of the Medicare Drug Benefit on Health Care Spending by Older Households

100% of Medicare-eligible expenses Beyond the additional 365 $0 $0 $0 $0

Health Care Reform Management Alert Series Roadmap of Plan Changes Needed For Upcoming Plan Years

Transcription:

The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Vol. 28 No. 2 (April 2003) 194 202 Medical Innovation: A Challenge to Society and Insurance by Peter Zweifel 1. Introduction and overview This contribution starts with a riddle. Why is it that health insurers and policymakers are afraid of medical innovation whereas technological innovation is considered the source of cost savings in the remainder of the economy? To see that there is a riddle at all here, one merely needs to take the example of computers. One generation ago, mainframe computers used to occupy an entire room that needed to be airconditioned. Today, a laptop has more computing power than mainframe computers while costing maybe 1 per cent of their price. By way of contrast, health insurers and policymakers sigh everytime the media announce the development of new medical technology. In an attempt to explain this riddle, an important distinction between product innovation and process innovation is introduced in the next section. In the case of process innovation, the same good or service is produced at a lower cost; in the case of product innovation, the good or service in question is provided with new quality attributes, possibly at an increased cost. It is then shown that while a good deal of process innovation occurs in the remainder of the economy, the existence of health insurance serves to bias the mix between the two in favour of product innovation. Thus, the bias in favour of cost-increasing product innovation in healthcare may explain why technological innovation in medicine is viewed as a mixed blessing by many. A separate section is devoted to the specific issue of medical innovation in an ageing society. The amazing finding will be that the most recent and costly medical technology often is applied to patients with very short remaining life expectancy. This finding poses another riddle: why should people want to invest heavily in healthcare if the payback period to their investment is so short? While there are several answers to this question, there are policy options to deal with this apparent anomaly. The final section contains a survey and evaluation of these options. Although age-dependent rationing of medical services is advocated in many quarters, economic theory suggests more efficient alternatives such as the development of insurance contracts that induce a more judicious use of medical innovation towards the end of human life. 2. The economic distinction between process and product innovation In economic theory, it has become customary to distinguish between two types of innovation, process and product innovation (Table 1). In the case of process innovation, the good or service in question is produced at a lower cost, which typically means that the production process occurs at a faster pace. For this reason, product innovation often meets Professor of Economics, Socioeconomic Institute of the University of Zurich, Switzerland. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK.

MEDICAL INNOVATION: A CHALLENGE TO SOCIETY AND INSURANCE 195 Table 1: Aspects of process and product innovation Aspect Process innovation Product innovation Basic idea Consumer s willingness to pay The same but less costly, faster Unchanged New attributes, may also cost more Increased and enhanced by a limited monopoly (patents) Response within the firm Considerable resistance Support Market result The mix of the two types of innovation depends on cost benefit considerations on the part of consumers with a good deal of resistance on the part of the workforce. It may suffice for the reader to imagine the medical director of a hospital department ordering the use of a new therapy that does not improve the prospect of recovery but requires nursing staff to work faster. Such an innovation would certainly be greeted with much scepticism by staff. The same is true of firms in the remainder of the economy; it is the pressure of worldwide price competition that forces firms to adopt unpopular process innovations. By way of contrast, the idea behind product innovation is to add new quality attributes to a good or service (Lancaster, 1971). Since consumers are willing to pay for these attributes, the new product will fetch a higher price. However, this means that the cost of production may go up without the firm losing its competitiveness. A higher cost base provides employees with a margin of manoeuvre, which may be used for perks that make work life more pleasant such as outsourcing onerous tasks or hiring additional help, introducing new machinery, or reducing work hours. Admittedly, the two types of innovation occur often in a way that makes it difficult to distinguish them in actual medical practice. 1 Still, it has proven fruitful to distinguish the two types at the conceptual level because their consequences are different. Indeed, if a country is successful in launching product innovations, it can allow itself an increase in the cost of labour which is nothing more than higher wages for its workforce. However, since consumers willingness to pay for improved quality attributes is always limited, firms also need to continually introduce process innovations as well. Conclusion 1: Firms compete with improved quality and lower price. This causes a certain mix of process and product innovation in a market economy subject to international competition. 3. The impact of health insurance on innovation mix Health insurance has the effect of changing the mix between process and product innovation in the healthcare sector (Zweifel and Manning, 2000). Quite likely, the willingness 1 See Zweifel and Breyer (1997), ch. 11.3.

196 ZWEIFEL to pay of consumers, who are patients or prospective patients in the present context, is higher to begin with. After all, product innovation in medicine means improved chances of recovery and even survival, features that are highly valued by most individuals. Nevertheless, health insurance serves to magnify this tendency in favour of product innovation in medicine (Table 2). Table 2: The specific influence of health insurance on the innovation mix Influence Process innovation Product innovation On patients On physicians, hospitals On suppliers of innovation (pharmaceuticals, diagnostics) Result Little interest, since minimal share in savings achieved Little interest, since minimal share in savings achieved Only of interest if potential for cost reduction large A lot of interest; reduction of effective total cost possible 2 A lot of interest since new products are crucial for competition for patients Given that the innovation is insured, market success almost guaranteed Health insurance biases the mix between the two types of innovation in favour of product innovation For simplicity s sake, the argument will be based on the case of a fully-insured patient, as is found, for example, in any public ward of a Swiss hospital. Given that patients do make a contribution (10 per cent of out-patient care in Switzerland), the conclusions reached would have to be modified slightly. Put very simply, a fully-insured patient is not interested in process innovation in medicine at all. At the time when he or she decides to initiate a treatment episode, the health insurance premium has already been paid, constituting a fixed cost that has no relevance for decision-making anymore. Indeed, it does not matter to the insured whether a medical therapy costs U.S.$ 1,000 or 10,000, the effective out-of-pocket cost is zero at any rate. For physicians and hospitals, it thus makes little sense to try to attract patients by offering a low price. Accordingly they have little incentive either to adopt cost-reducing process innovations. Of course this would change if insurers had the right to engage in selective contracting, allowing them to seek out those providers that offer a favourable quality price ratio. This lack of interest in process innovations finally spills over to suppliers of medical innovation such as pharmaceutical companies. They are hesitant to invest in new products that promise to reduce the cost of service in hospitals and medical practices. Things are entirely different in the case of product innovation. Given that they are fully 2 For an explanation, see Table 3 below.

MEDICAL INNOVATION: A CHALLENGE TO SOCIETY AND INSURANCE 197 insured, patients have every incentive to opt for the highest quality available since even the newest therapy has an out-of-pocket price of zero to them. Physicians and hospitals in turn know full well that they can attract insured patients by offering the newest medical technology. Finally, it is easy for the suppliers to sell a new product. Once their product has made it onto the list of benefits paid by the health insurance company, its success in the market is almost guaranteed. In sum, the very existence of health insurance imparts a bias in favour of product innovation for the healthcare sector while cost-saving process innovation takes second place. This only changes if insurers have the right to selective contracting allowing them to retain only those physicians and hospitals that have a favourable quality cost ratio. A favourable ratio factors into a favourable quality premium ratio with which a health insurer can compete in the market for members. Conclusion 2: The existence of health insurance imparts a bias in favour of product rather than process innovation in medical care, which is most marked when there is no selective contracting. Existing product Table 3: Medical innovation and effective cost to the insured U.S.$ Willingness to pay of insured (assumed) 60 Maximum price of product on the market (assumed rate of coinsurance 200 10 per cent) Time cost to patient (assumed 1 hour at U.S.$ 30) 30 Total effective cost to patient 50 Product innovation Maximum willingness to pay of insured (assumed) 80 Maximum price of product on the market (assumed rate of coinsurance of 250 10 per cent) Time cost to patient (assumed 0.5 hour at U.S.$ 30) 15 Total effective cost to patient 40 The conclusion holds true also in the presence of a (small) copayment. This can be seen from the following example (Table 3). Initially, let the maximum willingness-to-pay of a patient be U.S.$ 60, for example, for a drug. The assumed market price is U.S.$ 200, of which the patient pays U.S.$ 20. Moreover, assume that the actual purchase and administration of the drug uses one hour s worth of patient time, which is valued at U.S.$ 30. Therefore, initially the effective cost of the therapy is U.S.$ 50 to the insured patient. Now let there be a product innovation, with two effects. First, the maximum willingness to pay increases to U.S.$ 80 (say) in view of improved quality attributes, with the market price of the drug also rising by 25 per cent to U.S.$ 250. Second, another improved feature of the drug may well be its less frequent administration. Let the patient time needed drop from one

198 ZWEIFEL hour to 30 minutes. Accordingly, taking the new drug entails a time cost of U.S.$ 15 rather than U.S.$ 30 as before. In this example, the total effective cost to the patient decreases from U.S.$ 50 to U.S.$ 40. Therefore, more patients are likely to demand product innovation. At the same time, its monetary price (which must be reimbursed by the health insurer) has increased, from U.S.$ 180 (90 per cent of 200) to U.S.$ 270 (90 per cent of 300). This simple example illustrates why health insurers are so nervous about medical innovation. 4. Medical innovation in an ageing society Insurers and policymakers are particularly sceptical when costly medical innovation is applied to elderly patients. Being beyond retirement age, these patients do not contribute anymore to the financing of healthcare, at least in systems financed by payroll taxes (such as in Germany). In addition, the cost of medical care increases with age, seemingly implying that there will be a future cost explosion due to population ageing. However, research undertaken by health economists has consistently shown that the probability of initiating a treatment episode does not increase with age as soon as health status is controlled for statistically (Newhouse and Phelps, 1976; Newhouse and The Insurance Experiment Group, 1993, Table 4.8). This is important because the initiation of a treatment episode is a decision taken by the patient largely uninfluenced by the physician. Thus, it would reflect a true moral hazard effect, which economic theory predicts as a consequence of insurance coverage. At the same time, no one can be blamed for seeking medical care in response to a given deterioration of health status. For health policy, the absence of a relationship between age and initiation of treatment undermines the idea of controlling moral hazard specifically among the aged. Given that a treatment episode is initiated, the question still remains whether healthcare expenditure (HCE) increases with age on average. Health economics research has shown that there is a clear age effect, which may already mirror the influence of the physician adjusting his or her practice style to age. This adjustment can occur in collusion with the patient, thus reflecting moral hazard once more. For this reason, population ageing might still result in a future cost explosion. One way to counteract this tendency is to make physicians participate in the financial result of the insurer. This is what Health Maintenance Organisations (HMOs) and more generally bonuses for physicians paid for non-incurred HCE do. Another policy response is to limit the treatment alternatives available to elderly patients, which already amounts to a form of rationing. More recent research, starting with Lubitz and Prihoda (1984) using U.S. Medicare data, has found that HCE increases sharply with closeness to death. From an economic point of view this is puzzling, because lavishing resources shortly before death does not seem a sensible investment since the payback period is so short. One may of course resort to fear of death to explain this phenomenon. The implication for health policy of such behaviour seems to be clear: it provides the justification for age-dependent rationing of medical care, especially of costly product innovations. However, some very recent research suggests that the relationship between HCE and closeness to death is independent of the age of the individual (Zweifel, Felder and Meier, 2000). Indeed, drawn from a sample of Swiss deceased, the evidence points to a reduction of HCE with closeness to death among individuals aged 65. The theoretical interpretation of this finding is that heroic efforts on the part of the physician occur to save the life of a

MEDICAL INNOVATION: A CHALLENGE TO SOCIETY AND INSURANCE 199 Observation Table 4: The (lacking) relationship between HCE and age Theoretical interpretation Implication for health policy The probability of initiating a treatment episode does not increase with age, given health status Medical expenditure per treatment episode increases with age Medical expenditure increases sharply with closeness to death Medical expenditure increases sharply with closeness to death regardless of age For given health status and insurance coverage, there are no grounds to suspect increased moral hazard among the aged The true source of moral hazard could be as physicians, who adjust practice style to age (possibly in collusion) ageing of population results in a future cost explosion Not a sensible investment of resources since payback period short Reflects tendency towards heroic efforts on the part of physician Reflects fear of death on the part of the patient as the cause of extreme moral hazard No justification for controlling moral hazard among the aged by, e.g., mandating increased cost sharing for aged insureds Make physicians participate in the financial result of the insurer (HMOs, houses for physicians) Limit treatment alternatives available to aged patients Age-dependent rationing of medical care (especially costly product innovations) No justification for agedependent rationing Self-rationing of insureds through their choice of plan as an alternative deathbound person. It also may reflect fear of death on the part of the patient, implying an extremely strong moral hazard effect. From the policy point of view, there is no reason anymore for a future cost explosion due to ageing (at least at the level of the individual). Whereas at present the two expensive last years of life occur at ages 75/76 on average, in the future they may occur at ages 85/86, implying no more than that the costly phase of human life is deferred by ten years. Such a deferral, however, provides no justification for age-dependent rationing. Age-dependent rationing would also appear to be unfair because at age 70 (say) one individual may have a remaining life expectancy of only one year, whereas another may still have ten years. However, the issue remains that individuals who presumably know that their remaining life expectancy is so short nonetheless spend such a great deal on medical care, which is paid by others. The solution might be to induce self-rationing on the part of the aged by making them choose an insurance plan that imposes restrictions on the use of medical care, in return for a reduced contribution, of course. These policy options are expounded in the next section. 5. Reform options Clearly, medical innovation poses a problem both to insurers and policymakers. The preferred policy choice in dealing with this problem has been the planning of innovation by public authorities or by a cartel of health insurers. For example, the public authority may state

200 ZWEIFEL its intention to only finance so many magnetic resonance imaging (MRIs) per 10,000 population. Social health insurers, acting in concertation as a cartel, can impose similar restrictions (Table 5). Such planning certainly has its advantages. In particular, it makes controlling future HCE much easier for health insurers (or public authorities). However, it also has important disadvantages. Since public planning does not take into account consumer preferences, the healthcare sector delivers less value for money, being too expensive for what it provides. Thus, cost benefit ratios in healthcare deteriorate in the long run, causing a loss of competitiveness of the country s healthcare system and of the economy as a whole. By way of contrast, planning of medical innovation could be done by the individual insurer itself, acting on behalf of its clientele. For example, insurers could launch plans that only include medical innovations of demonstrated efficiency, in return for a reduced contribution. If they are subject to competition for members, they must pattern their benefits according to member preferences. Thus, consumers can express their individual preferences in their choice of plan. For those who do not want to pay the higher premium for having the latest medical technology included in the benefit package, a plan with delayed access to such technology would provide a partial escape from the cost escalation driven by product innovation in healthcare. Such self-selected restrictions certainly have their disadvantages too. In particular, insureds will frequently regret their past decisions. It may well be that when approaching death, many would want to have access to the latest medical technology in spite of earlier commitments to the contrary. However, scope for regret is the necessary correlate of free choice. For example, individuals make a long-term commitment in their choice of occupation, Table 5: Reform options for the management of medical innovation Alternative Advantages Disadvantages Planning of innovation by public authorities or by a cartel of health insurers Health insurance plans that include medical innovations only when having demonstrated efficiency (in return for reduced contributions) Health insurance plans selecting innovations for which willingness to pay is high Future healthcare expenditure easier to control by health insurers Deteriorating cost benefit ratios on the long run; loss of competitiveness of healthcare system Permits consumers to Frequent regret of earlier express their individual decision, in particular when preferences; provides partial approaching death escape from cost escalation Insurance benefits structured according to consumer preferences; insurer balances benefits and costs (i.e. additional premium) on behalf of consumers Challenge to the holders of incumbent slots in the catalogue of benefits

MEDICAL INNOVATION: A CHALLENGE TO SOCIETY AND INSURANCE 201 marriage partner, and family size. These decisions can be changed at considerable cost, if at all. Yet the freedom of individual choice is preserved in these domains. One might ask the question: how are insurers able to structure their benefit packages on behalf of their members? Here, recent developments in experimental economics offer some good news. Willingness to pay for medical innovation can be estimated using, for example, a so-called Conjoint Analysis. 3 This is a tool that has been developed in marketing. Respondents are faced with a series of scenarios where treatment alternatives vary in terms of their quality attributes (such as pain, probability of success, amenities, and out-of-pocket price to the patient). All respondents have to do is to accept or reject a particular combination of attributes. From the responses, trade-offs can be filtered out which indicate the willingness to pay for a particular attribute. The total willingness to pay for a treatment can then be estimated by combining the different attributes. In this way, insurers will in the future be able to structure their benefits according to the preferences of their members. Their objective will be to balance the benefits against the costs (i.e. additional premium) on behalf of consumers. Admittedly, this development is likely to be slow because the holders of slots in existing benefit packages (especially in social insurance) will be challenged. Thus, they have little interest in having members willingness-to-pay revealed. Conclusion 3: The response to costly medical innovation benefiting in particular elderly patients need not be rationing and public planning. There are more consumer-friendly alternatives such as health insurance plans offering increased cost-sharing beyond a certain age to contain the moral hazard or offering delayed access to the newest medical technology in return for reduced contributions. Weeding out benefit packages from products that do not provide value for money is in the best long-run interest of the healthcare sector because it fosters its competitiveness. Indeed, the economy as a whole benefits from such a process because it too gains in competitiveness. 6. Summary and conclusion This contribution started with a riddle: why is it that innovation is viewed as progress in the remainder of the economy while being so much feared in the healthcare sector? The answer to this question seems to lie in a distinction between process innovation (which is costreducing) and product innovation (which is quality improvement but may be cost-increasing). It was shown that the very existence of health insurance biases the mix of the two types of innovation in favour of product innovation. This bias becomes the more problematic as evidence accumulates that the latest medical technology is applied to patients who are in their last years of life. Accordingly, even countries with a market economy have resorted to public regulation of innovation in the healthcare sector. However, there are market-oriented alternatives: specifically, competing health insurers could be encouraged to develop new types of policies that give those insured access to new medical technologies only with a time lag. In the meantime, their cost benefit ratio can be established. In this way, medical innovation is tied more closely to the preferences of consumers, which can be measured in the guise of willingness to pay, using modern tools of experimental economics. The requirement that health insurers are competing merits emphasis at this point. If permitted to act as a cartel, health insurers will not differ much from politicians because they 3 See, for example, Telser and Zweifel (2002).

202 ZWEIFEL collectively do not have to respect the preferences of their clients. Thus, countries that have initiated market-oriented reforms of their healthcare sectors (such as Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland) must pay increased attention to their competition policies with regard to health insurance. REFERENCES LANCASTER, K., 1971, Consumer Demand: A New Approach. New York: Columbia University Press. LUBITZ, J. and PRIHODA, R., 1984, Use and costs of Medicare services in the last years of life, Health Care Financing Review, 5 (1), Spring, pp. 117 131. NEWHOUSE, J.P. and PHELPS, C.E., 1976, New Estimates of price and income elasticities of medical care services, in Rosett, R.N. (ed.), The Role of Health Insurance in the Health Services Sector. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 261 312. NEWHOUSE, J.P. and THE INSURANCE EXPERIMENT GROUP, 1993, Free for All? Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. TELSER, H. and ZWEIFEL, P., 2002, Measuring willingness-to-pay for risk reduction: An application of conjoint analysis, Health Economics, 11, pp. 129 139. ZWEIFEL, P. and BREYER F., 1997, Health Economics. New York: Oxford University Press. ZWEIFEL, P., FELDER, S. and MEIER, M., 2000, Aging of population and health care expenditure: A red herring?, Health Economics, 8 (6), pp. 485 496. ZWEIFEL, P. and MANNING, W.G., 2000, Moral hazard and consumer incentives in health care, in Culyer, A.J. and Newhouse, J.P. (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics. Boston: Elsevier, ch. 8.