NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LABOR MARKET FLOWS IN THE CROSS SECTION AND OVER TIME. Steven J. Davis Jason Faberman John C.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LABOR MARKET FLOWS IN THE CROSS SECTION AND OVER TIME. Steven J. Davis Jason Faberman John C."

Transcription

1 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LABOR MARKET FLOWS IN THE CROSS SECTION AND OVER TIME Steven J. Davis Jason Faberman John C. Haltiwanger Working Paper NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA August 2011 This paper was presented at the Spring 2011 Carnegie-Rochester Conference. We thank Jennifer Hayden for excellent research assistance. We thank seminar participants at EUI, Princeton, Chicago, Rochester, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, workshop participants at various conferences and Ay egül ahin, Hermann Gartner, Christopher Reicher, Tom Cooley and Yongsung Chang for comments on an earlier draft. We thank the Kauffman Foundation and the Booth School of Business at the University of Chicago for financial support. The views expressed are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official positions or policies of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve System, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, the U.S. Bureau of the Census, the National Bureau of Economic Research, or the views of other staff members. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications by Steven J. Davis, Jason Faberman, and John C. Haltiwanger. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

2 Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time Steven J. Davis, Jason Faberman, and John C. Haltiwanger NBER Working Paper No August 2011 JEL No. E24,J63,J64 ABSTRACT Many theoretical models of labor market search imply a tight link between worker flows (hires and separations) and job gains and losses at the employer level. Partly motivated by these theories, we exploit establishment-level data from U.S. sources to study the relationship between worker flows and job flows in the cross section and over time. We document strong, highly nonlinear relationships of hiring, quit and layoff rates to employer growth in the cross section. Simple statistical models that capture these cross-sectional relationships greatly improve our ability to account for fluctuations in aggregate worker flows. We also evaluate how well various theoretical models and views fit the patterns in the data. Aggregate fluctuations in layoffs are well captured by micro specifications that impose a tight cross-sectional link between worker flows and job flows. Aggregate fluctuations in quits are not. Instead, quit rates rise and fall with booms and recessions across the distribution of establishment growth rates, but more so at shrinking employers. Finally, we use our preferred statistical models in combination with data on the cross-sectional distribution of establishment growth rates to construct synthetic JOLTS-type measures of hires, separations, quits and layoffs back to Steven J. Davis Booth School of Business The University of Chicago 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Chicago, IL and NBER Steven.Davis@ChicagoBooth.edu John C. Haltiwanger Department of Economics University of Maryland College Park, MD and NBER haltiwan@econ.umd.edu Jason Faberman Economic Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 230 S. LaSalle St. Chicago, IL jfaberman@frbchi.org An online appendix is available at:

3 1. Introduction Many theoretical models of labor market search carry strong implications for the relationship of hires and separations to job gains and losses at the employer level. Partly motivated by these theories, we exploit establishment-level data from U.S. sources to study the empirical relationship between worker flows and job flows in the cross section and over time. The evidence supports a hybrid view that incorporates aspects of several distinct theories of labor market dynamics. Tracking the cross-sectional distribution of establishment growth rates, and applying simple models of cross-sectional behavior, greatly improves our ability to account for aggregate fluctuations in hires, separations, quits and layoffs. Previous work has not delivered a thorough and convincing explanation for the relationship between worker flows and job flows. One difficulty is that worker flow and job flow measures typically derive from different data sources, and are comparable only at high levels of aggregation. Even then, standard sources of data on these measures differ in scope, sampling frequency and other respects that hinder direct comparison. We overcome these difficulties by exploiting micro data from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS). JOLTS data yield internally consistent measures of hires, separations, quits, layoffs, job creation and job destruction at the establishment and aggregate levels. To deal with weaknesses in the JOLTS sample design, we rely on the comprehensive Business Employment Dynamics (BED) to track the cross-sectional distribution of establishment-level growth rates over time. Specifically, we combine BED data on the establishment growth rate distribution with JOLTS data for hires, separations, layoffs and quits conditional on establishment growth rates to measure the aggregate worker flow rates. Combining JOLTS and BED data also enables us to construct synthetic data on worker flows back to 1990, nearly doubling the time-series length of JOLTS-type worker flow measures. 1

4 To guide our empirical work, we consider several theoretical models. Models in the spirit of seminal work by Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) (hereafter MP) imply a tight link between job flows and worker flows. Our empirical work assesses how closely models with these tight links fit the data. We also consider empirical specifications motivated by models that stress the role of search on the job, learning about match quality, firm profitability, and the impact of aggregate conditions on the propensity to quit. We evaluate alternative specifications in terms of their fit to cross-sectional patterns in the establishment-level data, their ability to generate the observed movements in aggregate worker flows, and their marginal explanatory power for aggregate worker flows after conditioning on aggregate variables. Figures 1 and 2 plot our quarterly, seasonally adjusted time series for JOLTS-type worker flow measures, along with job creation and destruction rates from the BED. 1 All rates cover the nonfarm private sector and are expressed as a percent of employment. We define job creation as the sum of employment gains at new and expanding establishments as in Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996). We define job destruction analogously. Figure 1 shows that job destruction and layoffs move together over time, while quits move counter to both. Job destruction and layoffs exhibit pronounced spikes in late 2008 and early 2009 and then decline in nearly parallel fashion. Figure 2 shows that job creation and hires rates decline from 2006, bottom out in 2009Q1, and then partly recover. The hiring rate moves much more than the job creation rate over this period. Our study explores the micro level sources of these aggregate movements. Looking across establishments, hiring and separation rates exhibit powerful elements of the iron-link behavior implied by MP-style search models. That is, hires are tightly linked to job creation, 1 To conform to the BED sampling frequency, we cumulate monthly establishment-level JOLTS observations to the quarterly frequency. We then construct our aggregate worker flow series by combining the cross-sectional relationships of worker flows to establishment-level growth rates in JOLTS micro data with employment growth rate distributions from the BED. This approach, described more fully in Section III below, follows Davis, Faberman, Haltiwanger and Rucker (2010). Worker flows prior to 2001Q3 in Figures 1 and 2 are synthetic data, constructed as described in Section V below. 2

5 and separations are tightly linked to job destruction. When plotted as functions of establishment-level growth rates, hiring and separation rates exhibit nonlinear hockey-stick shapes. The hires relation is nearly flat to the left of zero growth (contracting employers) and rises more than one-for-one with employment growth to the right of zero (expanding employers), with a pronounced kink at zero. The separations relation is a mirror image of the hires relation. The hockey-stick shape for separations is starkly at odds with the simplifying assumption adopted in many search models of a uniform separation rate. Turning to the components of separations, both quits and layoffs rise with job destruction, but layoffs dominate the adjustment margin for rapidly contracting establishments. We also consider how the cross-sectional relations vary with aggregate conditions. As it turns out, the cross-sectional layoff relation is highly stable over time. In contrast, the cross-sectional quit relation varies markedly with aggregate conditions. Specifically, the quit relation shifts downward when aggregate conditions are weak, especially at contracting establishments. Several theoretical models provide insight into the reasons for departures from an iron-link relationship between worker flows and job flows. Faberman and Nagypál (2008) consider a model of on-the-job search that delivers an abandon-ship effect at struggling employers. Firms vary in their idiosyncratic profitability and grow faster when more profitable. Because wages increase with firm profits in their model, workers at low-profitability firms are more likely to accept an outside offer. Consequently, quit rates decline with the idiosyncratic component of firm profitability. Barlevy (2002) considers a model with on-the-job search and a match-specific component of productivity. Because firms create fewer vacancies when aggregate conditions are weak, employed workers encounter better matches at a slower pace during recessions. As a result, workers tend to remain longer in poor matches, which Barlevy refers to as the sullying effect of recessions. In sum, Faberman and Nagypál highlight the role of cross-sectional variation in firm-level circumstances for quit rates, whereas Barlevy 3

6 highlights the role of variation over time in aggregate conditions. Our evidence indicates that both effects are at work. In Jovanovic (1979, 1985) and Moscarini (2005), gradual learning about match quality leads to a separation rate that declines with match tenure. Because more rapid growth involves a higher share of young matches, these models suggest that separations rise with the growth rate of expanding employers. Pries and Rogerson (2005) integrate elements of Jovanovic-style learning into an MP model. Separations occur because of job destruction, as in the MP model, and because of learning effects about match quality. Thus, the model of Pries and Rogerson generates elements of iron-link behavior in hires and separations while rationalizing a positive relationship between separations and growth at expanding employers. The data support this hybrid view of the cross-sectional relationship between hires, separations and employer growth. Motivated by these theoretical ideas, we develop parsimonious statistical models of how worker flows vary in the cross section, and how the cross-sectional relations move over time. The statistical models serve three objectives. First, they provide guidance in evaluating, developing and calibrating theoretical models of labor market flows. Second, they allow us to investigate whether tracking the cross-sectional growth distribution adds to our understanding of aggregate movements in labor market flows. Third, they yield a framework for constructing synthetic data on aggregate hires, separations, quits and layoffs in the period before the advent of JOLTS. When we consider specifications that impose time-invariant relations of worker flows to employer growth rates in the cross section, the statistical models perform reasonably well in tracking the aggregate movements of hiring and layoff rates. However, the same type of model fails miserably in tracking the aggregate behavior of quits. Consequently, it also fares poorly in accounting for the 4

7 aggregate separations rate. When we allow the worker flow-employer growth relationships to vary with aggregate conditions, our ability to track aggregate quits and separations improves dramatically. Our work in this paper has many antecedents. There is a large body of previous research on job flows and worker flows. We review research in this area in Davis and Haltiwanger (1999) and Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger (2006). Labor market flows and job vacancies play central roles in modern theories of unemployment based on search and matching models. See, for example, Pissarides (2000), Rogerson, Shimer and Wright (2005) and Yashiv (2007) for reviews of work in this area. Models that treat hires as the outcome of a matching function carry implications for the relationship between hires and vacancies in the cross section and over time. We explore some of those implications in Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger (2010). The paper proceeds as follows. Section II discusses the conceptual underpinnings that guide our empirical work. We start with the model of Cooper, Haltiwanger and Willis (2006), which extends the basic MP model to multi-worker firms. We then consider models that endogenize the worker s quit decision, as in Faberman and Nagypál (2008) and Barlevy (2002), and conclude with models of learning about match quality, such as Jovanovic (1979). Section III describes our data and empirical measures. Section IV presents our statistical models and investigates how well they account for worker flows in the cross section and over time. Section V constructs synthetic JOLTS-type data on worker flows, and Section VI concludes. 2. Conceptual Underpinnings and Theoretical Implications In thinking about worker flows and job flows, it is useful to begin with an identity: e it = eit 1 + h it l it q it, (1) where e it is employment at establishment i in period t and h, l and q denote hires, layoffs and quits. Separations are the sum of quits and layoffs. Theory provides guidance about how employers use hires, 5

8 layoffs and quits to adjust employment and about the factors that lead to worker turnover in excess of employment changes. In what follows in this section, we first consider search and matching models that involve an iron link between hires and job creation on the one hand and separations and job destruction on the other. We then consider theories that relax the iron link. Lastly, we discuss aggregate implications and motivate our empirical specifications Models with an Iron Link Every hire reflects a newly created job in the canonical search and matching model of Mortensen and Pissarides (1994), and every separation reflects a job that vanishes. That is what we mean by an iron link between worker flows and job flows. One goal of our study is to assess how well this iron link characterizes the data. However, the basic MP model has no role for multi-worker employers, an essential aspect of our empirical work. So we borrow from Cooper, Haltiwanger and Willis (2007, CHW) to illustrate the implications of the iron link in a multi-worker version of MP. 2 Employers in the CHW model face common and idiosyncratic shocks and produce output according to a strictly concave function of the labor input. When hiring new workers, employers incur fixed and variable costs of posting vacancies. Workers separate for exogenous reasons, and some employers layoff additional workers subject to fixed and variable firing costs. Employers choose layoffs and vacancies effectively, hires as well to maximize the present discounted value of profits. Workers do not search on the job. The following law of motion links employment changes and worker flows in CHW: e it = ( 1 q ) e 1 + η( U, V ) v it t t it l it, (2) 2 Other recent search-theoretic analyses with multi-worker firms include Elsby and Michaels (2008), Veracierto (2009), Fujita and Nakajima (2010), Schaal (2010) and Trapeznikova (2010). 6

9 where q is the quit rate, η U t, V ) is the job-filling rate, and v is the number of vacancies posted at the ( t it beginning of the period. 3 The job-filling rate derives from a standard matching function with constant returns to scale in the aggregate numbers of unemployed workers and vacant jobs. Period-t hires for the employer are h = η( U, V ) v. it t t it An employer in the CHW model operates in one of three regions each period, depending on the aggregate and idiosyncratic shock values: (i) positive vacancies and zero layoffs, (ii) zero vacancies and positive layoffs, or (iii) an inaction region with zero vacancies, no layoffs and no replacement hiring. Solving the model yields a stochastic equilibrium path for the cross-sectional distribution of employment changes, hires, quits and layoffs. The realized path depends in complex ways on the interaction of the aggregate and idiosyncratic driving forces and the key parameters of the revenue, cost and matching functions. Aggregate shocks shift the entire cross-sectional distribution of growth rates, while parameters governing adjustment costs and the variance of idiosyncratic shocks strongly influence its shape. Model-based outcomes exhibit an iron-link mapping of job flows to hiring, layoffs, and quits. Figure 3 depicts the iron link. It shows the relationship of the hiring, layoff, and quit rates to employer growth rates in the cross section. There is a mass point with no hiring or layoffs at growth rate q. To the right of q, employers post vacancies and hire new workers. Employers in this range have zero layoffs, and hiring rises one-for-one with increases in employment. To the left of q, employers engage in no hiring and the layoff rate rises one-for-one with the rate at which the employer contracts. Given the iron link relations illustrated in Figure 3, the cross-sectional distribution of employment growth rates fully determines aggregate hires and layoffs. This feature of the model has interesting implications. For example, modest recessions that shift the central tendency of the cross- 3 We use uppercase letters for aggregate quantities and lowercase letters for establishment outcomes. 7

10 sectional distribution from positive values to a value near zero produce large drops in aggregate hires with relatively little increase in aggregate layoffs. In contrast, a deep recession that shifts much of the mass in the cross-sectional distribution across the kink point in Figure 3 produces a large jump in layoffs. Thus, the highly nonlinear micro relations in Figure 3 imply differential responses of hires and layoffs to mild and deep recessions. Below, we treat the aggregate implications of cross-sectional worker flow relations in a more formal manner Relaxing the Iron Link There are several ways to relax the iron link feature of MP-style models. If we exogenously vary the quit rate in the CHW model, we obtain the implications shown in Figure 4. As the quit rate varies, the kink point moves and the layoff and hires relations shift accordingly. Specifically, a fall in the quit rate from q ( G0 ) to q G ) causes the cross-sectional hiring and layoff relations to shift rightward. That ( 1 is, the fall in the quit rate creates an environment where employers require fewer hires when expanding and more layoffs when contracting to achieve a given growth rate. More generally, if the quit rate varies systematically with labor market slack, then so do the cross-sectional relations for hires and layoffs. This insight applies in more complex models as well. Models with endogenous quit behavior deliver other interesting implications. As discussed in the introduction, the model of Faberman and Nagypál (2008) implies that quit rates decline with employer growth rates in the cross section. Workers are more likely to abandon struggling employers because they pay lower wages and cannot match outside offers from more profitable employers. Inspecting Figures 3 and 4, it is apparent that a nonlinear quit relation implies nonlinear relations for one or both of hires and layoffs as well. Somewhat paradoxically, weaker employers face greater needs for replacement hiring to offset, at least partly, a greater attrition rate. Thus, the model of Faberman and Nagypál can deliver a negative slope in the hires relation over some range. In the model of Barlevy 8

11 (2002), employers post fewer vacancies when aggregate conditions are weak. As a result, poorly matched employees encounter new job opportunities at a slower rate, and they quit less frequently. This implication of the Barlevy model provides an explanation for the downward shift in the quit rate in Figure 4 and the resulting shifts in the layoff and hiring relations. Models that feature learning about match quality as in Jovanovic (1979) yield additional insights. Under weak conditions, these models imply that employment relationships dissolve at a rate that declines with match duration. A newly hired worker is more likely to quit because he learns a job is not to his liking, or to be fired because his employer learns he cannot perform. Naturally, the proportion of new employees tends to rise with an employer s expansion rate. Thus, learning about match quality can cause quits and layoffs to rise with the growth rate of employment at expanding employers. Learning also leads to additional separations at shrinking employers when recent replacement hires do not work out. More generally, learning about match quality implies that worker flows beget further worker flows, as stressed by Hall (1995), Pries (2004), and Pries and Rogerson (2005). The lesson of this discussion is that the stark relations depicted in Figures 3 and 4 are too simple to fully capture the patterns in the data. Nevertheless, we think Figures 3 and 4 are useful starting points for two reasons. First, they provide a straightforward exposition of the links between worker flows and establishment-level growth in a prominent class of search models. We will investigate how closely the data conform to the relations exhibited in Figures 3 and 4. Second, our discussion provides guidance for formulating statistical models that relate worker flows to employer growth rates Implications for Aggregate Outcomes and the Relationship to Cross-Sectional Behavior To draw out the aggregate implications of the iron link relation and the other theoretical effects discussed above, express the aggregate hiring rate as 9

12 H f ( g) h ( g), (3) t = g t t where h t (g) is the mean hiring rate for establishments with growth rate g at time t, and f t (g) is the corresponding share of employment with growth rate g at t. This equation implies that movements in the aggregate hiring rate arise from changes over time in the cross-sectional relationship between hires and establishment growth rates, shifts in the growth rate distribution, and interactions between the two. Analogous remarks apply to separations, quits and layoffs. Of course, equation (3) is simply an accounting identity. Moving beyond the identity requires behavioral models of the micro relationships between worker flows and employer growth rates. Consider, for example, the CHW model with its time-invariant iron link between worker flows and establishment growth. Substituting the behavioral relations shown in Figure 3 into (3) yields the following expressions for aggregate rates of hires, layoffs and quits: H L t t = = g g f ( g) h( g), t f ( g) l ( g), and (4) t Q = f ( g) q = q t. t In the empirical work below, we fit, and relations using JOLTS micro data pooled over the 2001 to 2010 period. In doing so, we allow the quit rate to vary with employer growth, and we let the data freely determine the kink points, if any, in the cross-sectional relations. We also allow for hires in excess of job creation and separations in excess of job destruction. Even under these relaxed conditions, equations (4) preserve a key aggregate implication of the iron link: fluctuations in aggregate worker flows arise entirely from movements in the cross-sectional distribution of establishment growth rates. We will evaluate how well this implication describes the behavior of aggregate worker flows. g t 10

13 ~ More generally, the cross-sectional behavioral relations vary over time, and we write ht ( g ), ~ lt ( g ), and q ~ for the hiring, layoff and quit relations in period t. Proceeding as before, and replacing t ~ ~ the time-invariant relations in (4) with ht ( g ), lt ( g ), and q ~, yields the corresponding aggregate flow rates. When the cross-sectional behavioral relations vary over time, movements in the establishmentlevel growth rate distribution no longer suffice to fully account for fluctuations in aggregate worker flows. Nevertheless, we can still obtain informative characterizations of the aggregate flows in terms of ~ ~ statistical models for ht ( g ), lt ( g ), and q ~. Moreover, we can combine these models with data on f t (g) to construct synthetic measures of aggregate worker flows outside the period covered by JOLTS data. Figure 4 illustrates a case where the cross-sectional relations exhibit iron-link behavior in any given period, but they shift up and down over time with the aggregate quit rate. In this case, the behavioral relation for the hires rate takes the form t ~ ( g ) =, where X is a vector of ht indicators for aggregate labor market conditions and is a parameter vector that governs the size of the upward and downward shifts in the cross-sectional hires relations. Analogous remarks apply to the cross-sectional relations for separations, layoffs and quits. We investigate statistical models of this form and evaluate their ability to account for the cross-sectional and aggregate behavior of worker flows. We also investigate more flexible models that allow the shape of the cross-sectional relations to vary systematically with aggregate conditions. t 3. Data and Measurement We now turn to the description of the two data sources used and describe the key methodological concepts for the analysis. 11

14 3.1. Data Sources This study relies on two micro data sources, Business Employment Dynamics (BED) and the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS), both produced by the BLS. The BED contains longitudinally linked administrative records for all businesses covered by state unemployment insurance agencies virtually a census of nonfarm private business establishments. The data are quarterly and include employment and payroll for each establishment plus information on industry, location and whether the establishment belongs to a multi-unit firm. The BLS uses the BED to produce quarterly statistics on gross job creation and destruction from 1992, although micro data exist back to Our BED micro data run from 1990Q2 through 2010Q2. Data access restrictions preclude our use of BED data for Connecticut, Florida, Massachusetts, Michigan, Mississippi, New Hampshire, New York, Pennsylvania, and Wyoming. Time-series data on job creation and destruction rates generated from our version of the BED closely mimic the published series that cover all states. The JOLTS samples about 16,000 establishments each month and includes data on employment in the pay period covering the 12 th of the month. Establishments report hires, quits, layoffs, and other separations (deaths, retirements, and intra-firm transfers) over the course of the month. For quits, the establishments identify employees who left voluntarily (excluding retirements and intra-firm transfers). For layoffs, the establishments identify involuntary separations initiated by the employer. 5 The survey begins in December 2000 and covers the nonfarm economy. Our JOLTS micro data run from January 2001 through June For more details on the BED, see Spletzer et al. (2004). The BLS does not publish job flow statistics for because of issues related to administrative changes during that period. We follow Faberman (2008b) to address those changes. 5 The JOLTS survey instructions for layoffs and discharges include the following examples: layoffs with no intent to rehire, layoffs lasting more than 7 days, discharges resulting from mergers, downsizing, or closings, firings or other discharges for cause, terminations of permanent or short-term employees, terminations of seasonal employees (whether or not they are expected to return next season). For more details on the JOLTS, see Clark and Hyson (2001), Faberman (2008a) and Davis, Faberman, Haltiwanger, and Rucker (2010). Details on recent revisions to JOLTS methodology are available at 12

15 To construct quarterly worker flows at the establishment level, we require observations in all three months of the quarter. Dropping observations that violate this requirement reduces the number of establishments in our JOLTS sample by about 12 percent. This sample restriction produces slightly lower aggregate worker flow rates, but it does not alter their cyclical patterns. We also address other measurement issues related to the JOLTS data: timing differences in the measurement of worker flows and employment, the construction of sample weights at a quarterly frequency, and imputed worker flow rates for opening and closing establishments. The latter are covered by the BED but are not captured in the JOLTS sample frame. The appendix explains in detail how we address these matters. Our final sample contains over 277,000 establishment-quarter observations The Cross-Sectional Distribution of Establishment Growth Rates We compute employment growth as the difference between employment in the third month of the current quarter and the third month of the previous quarter, and we divide by the simple mean of current and previous employment to obtain a rate. (We use the same average of current and previous employment to compute worker flow rates.) This approach yields consistent aggregation and ensures that all growth rates are bounded, with entry and exit corresponding to values of +2 and -2. Given the comprehensive nature of the BED, we compute the cross-sectional distribution of employment growth rates directly from the micro data without need to adjust for sample weights. We focus on employmentweighted outcomes throughout the paper, unless noted otherwise. Figure 5 displays kernel density estimates of the establishment-level growth rate distribution in 2006Q1-2006Q4, a period of expanding aggregate employment, and 2008Q3-2009Q2, a period of sharp contraction. There is a clear leftward shift of the growth rate distribution from 2006 to the period. Table 1 reports summary statistics for the growth rate distribution in selected expansion and contraction periods. Establishments with steady employment levels over the quarter account for 13.9 to 13

16 16.1 percent of aggregate employment, depending on time period. Establishments that grow or shrink by more than 10 percent in the quarter account for 31 percent of employment in 1991, 29 percent in , and 26 percent in 2006 and 2008Q3-2009Q2. This evolution towards a more compressed growth rate distribution is also apparent in the behavior of aggregate worker flows Measuring Aggregate Worker Flows To measure aggregate worker flow rates, we combine JOLTS-based estimates of mean worker flow rates by growth rate bin with BED-based measures of the growth rate distribution. This method exploits identities of the sort described by equation (3). We use 195 bins that partition the full range of feasible growth rates, with narrower bins near the mode of zero growth. In defining bins, we allow for mass points at -200, 0 and 200 percent growth corresponding to exit, no change and entry. Letting w t (g) denote the mean worker flow rate for bin g in quarter t, we measure aggregate worker flow rates as W f ( g) w ( g). (5) t = g t t Because our JOLTS sample covers continuing establishments only, we do not have JOLTSbased worker flow rates for exits and entrants. Thus, we impute worker flow rates for entrants and exits when implementing (5). See the appendix for details. We prefer the aggregate worker flows computed according to (5) by combining BED and JOLTS data to the published JOLTS data, because our approach encompasses worker flows at exits and entrants, and because the BED provides a more accurate measure of the cross-sectional growth rate density. See Davis, Faberman, Haltiwanger and Rucker (2010) for additional discussion and analysis on this point. 4. Worker Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time Guided by the theoretical discussion in Section II, we specify statistical models of how worker flows vary with employer growth in the cross section and how the cross-sectional relations move over 14

17 time. We fit the models to establishment-level data and asses them in terms of cross-sectional fit, ability to replicate the time-series behavior of aggregate worker flows, and the marginal explanatory power of model-implied values for aggregate worker flows after conditioning on business cycle indicators. We also use the estimated statistical models to evaluate certain implications of the theoretical models Empirical Specifications Our first specification treats hires, separations, layoffs, and quits as time-invariant functions of establishment-level growth rates. Specifically, for each worker flow rate we regress the establishmentlevel observations on a vector of dummy variables for the 195 growth rate bins, w ( g) = α( g) + ε ( g) et et (6) where e indexes establishments, g indexes growth rate bins, and t indexes quarters. Fitted values in (6) given by wˆ D ( g) = ˆ α( g) describe the average cross-sectional worker flow relations in our JOLTS sample. This fixed cross section specification is consistent with the iron link feature of MP models, but it is flexible enough to accommodate learning about match quality as in Pries and Rogerson (2005) and the abandon-ship effect in Faberman and Nagypál (2008). Note that a strict MP-type iron link implies a perfect fit for (6). We examine R-squared values for fitted versions of (6) to quantify how closely the data conform to this implication. We also examine the shape of the fitted relationships to gauge whether and how closely they match the implications of various theoretical models. Recall that quit rates, and therefore hiring and separation rates, rise and fall in a pro-cyclical manner in the model of Barlevy (2002). To accommodate such behavior, our baseline specification relaxes (6) to let the cross-sectional relations shift up and down as functions of business cycle indicators: w et (g) = α (g) + β 1 G t + + β 2 G t + β 3 G t + β 4 JF t + ε et (g) (7) 15

18 where is the growth rate of aggregate employment, G = max{0, }, G = min{0, }, G t + t G t t G t G = G G t t t 1 is an accelerator term, and JF t is the job-finding rate calculated from Current Population Survey data on unemployment by duration. 6 To let the cross-sectional relations respond to business cycle conditions in more complicated ways, we extend the baseline specification by adding terms that involve interactions between the cycle indicators and the establishment-level growth rates. Specifically, we introduce a set of five indicator variables, I( g), for establishment-level growth rates less than or equal to -10 percent, greater than -10 percent but less than zero, exactly zero, positive but less than 10 percent, and greater than or equal to 10 percent. Thus, our flexible specification is given by w ( g) = α( g) + β G + + β G + β G + I ( g) δ G + I( g) δ JF + ε ( g). (8) et 1 t 2 t 3 t 1 t 2 t et Specification (8), unlike (7), allows the worker flow response to aggregate conditions to differ among establishments based on how rapidly they grow or shrink Worker Flows and Employer Growth in the Cross Section Figure 6 displays worker flow relations estimated from the fixed cross-section specification (6). The figure shows clear similarities to the theoretical relations in Figure 3. For example, the hiring relation exhibits a hockey-stick shape similar to the one implied by MP models. There are also clear departures from the implications of MP models. First, hires rise more than one-for-one with job creation to the right of zero. As discussed in Section II, this pattern suggests that a higher incidence of recently formed matches at more rapidly growing establishments leads to higher rates of learning about match quality, generating higher separation rates and more need for replacement hires. Second, hires occur at 6 We use standard methods to calculate the job-finding rate from data on unemployment by duration. For details, see Davis, Faberman, Haltiwanger, Jarmin and Miranda (2010). We use the published data from Current Employment Statistics to compute the growth rate of aggregate employment. 16

19 all growth rates, another piece of evidence that points to replacement hiring. Third, while there is a pronounced kink in the hiring relation, it occurs at zero growth rather than the mean quit rate. Finally, the hires rate declines with establishment growth rates over much of the range to the left of zero. This pattern is consistent with an abandon-ship effect in which more rapidly declining employers face a greater need for replacement hiring. Many of these same effects appear in the separations relation, which is nearly a mirror image of the hires relation. For example, separation rates rise with job creation rates to the right of zero, in line with the view that rapidly growing employers experience high turnover rates among recent hires. To the left of zero, separations rise more rapidly than job destruction, in line with the abandon-ship effect and a greater need for replacement hires at more rapidly shrinking employers. Turning to the breakdown of separations into quits and layoffs, several other patterns emerge. Layoffs rise sharply with job destruction, and they dominate the employment adjustment margin among rapidly shrinking employers. In contrast, quits account for a larger share of separations at establishments that shrink by less than 20 percent in the quarter and at growing establishments. In the appendix, we display a version of Figure 6 that covers a wider range of growth rates. The zoomed-out version of Figure 6 reveals even more clearly that quit rates top out at about 20 percent per quarter, and that layoffs are the primary margin of employment adjustment at rapidly contracting establishments. Quit and layoff rates, like the hiring rate, are smallest at employers with stable employment levels. 7 The patterns in Figure 6 differ from the cross-sectional relationships found by Abowd, Corbel, and Kramarz (1999) using establishment-level data for France. They find that hiring is the primary margin of employment adjustment at the establishment level, even for contracting establishments. This 7 For visual clarity, Figure 6 omits the cross-sectional relation for other separations (deaths, retirements, and intra-firm transfers). They are very small on average, amounting to about a half percent of employment, and somewhat greater at rapidly contracting establishments. 17

20 interesting point of contrast between their results and ours may reflect differences between France and the United States in the nature of labor adjustment. The topic warrants investigation in future work. Table 2 presents regression R-squared values for several specifications fit to the establishmentlevel JOLTS data. A potential concern about our specifications is that the 195-bin partition is too coarse to adequately approximate the underlying relationships of worker flows to employer growth rates. To investigate this concern, we augment each specification by adding 192 bin-specific slope terms. (There is no reason to introduce slope terms for the zero-width bins at -2, 0 and +2.) Comparing the first two columns in Table 2 reveals, however, that the bin-specific slope terms yield very modest gains in the regression fit of the fixed cross-section specification. For the sake of simplicity and parsimony, we drop the bin-specific slope terms in the rest of the paper. As discussed above, the strict iron-link feature of MP-type models implies a perfect fit for the fixed cross-section specification. We do not take this implication literally, because MP models deliberately abstract from many real-world features that play a role in worker flows. Still, it is interesting to ask how fully employer growth alone accounts for establishment-level variation in worker flows. According to Table 2, the fixed cross-section specification accounts for 54 percent of establishment-level variation in hiring rates and 51 percent for separation rates. It accounts for 47 percent of the variation in layoff rates and 16 percent of quit rate variation. These R-squared values fall well short of a perfect fit, but we are somewhat surprised by the extent to which the fixed cross-section model accounts for establishment-level variation in hires, separations and layoffs. In this regard, it is worth mentioning some of the many factors omitted from the model. In particular, it contains no controls for industry, employer size or age, wages, job tenure, education and other worker characteristics, the longer-term growth trajectory of the employer, local labor market conditions, and aggregate labor market conditions. Despite these omissions, this simple specification accounts for more 18

21 than half of the variation in hiring and separation rates across employers. Clearly, the employer growth rate is a major proximate determinant of worker flows. The remaining columns of Table 2 show the gains in fit from introducing cycle indicators and allowing for interactions between the cycle indicators and establishment-level growth rates. The baseline specification, which adds cycle indicators only, yields very modest gains in fit. The flexible specification, which also includes the interaction terms, improves the fit by several percentage points for each type of worker flow. Evidently, the relationship of worker flow rates to employer growth rates varies with aggregate labor market conditions. Table 2 also shows that even the flexible specification accounts for only about a quarter of the cross-sectional variation in establishment-level quit rates. The large role for establishment-level variation in quit rates conditional on own growth rate is an interesting finding, but it need not matter for movements in aggregate quit rates. To see this point, consider a multi-worker MP model with quit rates that vary exogenously among establishments. In particular, suppose the idiosyncratic component of the establishment-level quit rate is drawn from a common, time-invariant distribution. This assumption generates dispersion in worker flow rates among establishments with the same employment growth rate. Suppose, in addition, that the common component of quit rates varies with aggregate conditions as in our earlier discussion of Figure 4. Under these assumptions, there is dispersion in worker flow rates among establishments with the same employment growth rate, but common factors drive the average shape and location of the cross-sectional worker flow relations. For the analysis that follows, what matters is how well our statistical specifications capture variation in worker flow rates at the level of growth rates bins crossed with time periods. These binquarter outcomes provide building blocks for aggregation and the construction of our synthetic worker flow series. To obtain the bin-quarter outcomes, we compute the employment-weighted worker flow 19

22 rates for all 195 bins by quarter. To evaluate how well our statistical models capture the bin-quarter variation in worker flow rates, we estimate analogs of (6)-(8) at the bin-quarter level of aggregation. We summarize the main results of our regressions at the bin-quarter level here and report the full results in the appendix. The fixed cross-section specification accounts for 93 percent of the bin-quarter variation in the hiring rate and 92 percent for the separation rate. It accounts for 88 percent of the binquarter variation in layoff rates and 65 percent for the quit rate. The baseline and flexible specifications yield very modest improvements in fit for hires, separations and layoffs. The gains in fit are larger for the quit rate, with an R-squared value of 69 percent for the flexible specification. The flexible specification yields modest gains in fit relative to the baseline specification for quits and tiny gains for hires, separations and layoffs. That is, except perhaps for quit rates, the R-squared metric provides little evidence that the shapes of the cross-sectional relations vary systematically with the cycle indicators. The success of our statistical specifications in accounting for bin-quarter variation in worker flow rates bodes well for their ability to capture the behavior of aggregate worker flows Aggregate Behavior Implied by the Fixed Cross-Section Specification We now investigate how well our cross-sectional statistical models account for the behavior of aggregate worker flows. To start, we compare the actual worker flows to the aggregate flows implied by the fixed cross-section specification. To generate the implied flows, we replace the functions in (5) with wˆ D ( g) = ˆ α( g) obtained by fitting the fixed cross-section model to JOLTS data from 2001Q1 to 2010Q2. Plugging in the BED data for and the wˆ D ( g) functions yields the model-implied worker flow rates. 20

23 Figure 7 plots seasonally adjusted versions of the model-implied rates alongside the actual worker flow rates. 8 As seen in the figure, the layoff series implied by the fixed cross-section model captures much of the time-series variation in the actual layoff rate. The fixed cross-section model fares less well in replicating the actual hires and separations rate, and it completely fails to replicate the actual quit rates. In fact, the quit rate series implied by the fixed cross-section model is essentially a flat line for most of the period. It also predicts a rise in the quit rate during the downturn, which is nothing like the behavior of actual quit rates in this period. Table 3 quantifies the extent to which the fixed cross-section model replicates movements in the actual worker flow rates. (Like Figure 7, Table 3 includes results for other specifications that we discuss below). The first column of Table 3 reports the standard deviation of the actual worker flow rates. The remaining columns in the top panel report the root mean squared value of the difference between the model-implied and actual rates. For hires, the rate implied by the fixed cross-section model accounts for 36 percent of the time-series variation in the actual hires rate, computed as 100 times [1 (0.872/1.366)]. The correlation between the model-implied and actual hiring rate is For layoffs, the model-implied rate captures 41 percent of movements in the actual layoff rate, and the correlation between the two series is The model performs less well in replicating the behavior of the separations rate, and it captures very little of the time-series variation in the quit rate. We turn next to the cyclical behavior of the cross-sectional worker flow relations Shifts in the Cross-Sectional Relations over Time Before proceeding to the baseline and flexible specifications, we fit the fixed cross-section specification separately for three periods: 2001Q2 2003Q1 (a mild recession followed by a prolonged 8 We seasonally adjust the model-implied and actual worker flow rates using the Census X-11 procedure. We also drop the time series observations for 2001Q1 and Q2, because the JOLTS sample is much smaller in these early quarters about 2,700 observations per quarter as compared to more than 6,300 in other quarters. 21

24 jobless recovery ), 2006Q1 2006Q4 (an expansion period), and 2008Q3 2009Q2 (a deep recession). Each period covers four or eight consecutive quarters to ensure that seasonal effects do not drive the estimation results. For this exercise, we restrict attention to quarterly growth rates from -30 to 30 percent to focus on bins with ample observation counts. Establishments in this growth rate range account for about 90 percent of aggregate employment. Figure 8 displays the results. The layoff relation displays considerable stability over time. Rapidly shrinking establishments rely more heavily on layoffs (conditional on own growth) during the severe recession of , but the layoff relation is nearly time invariant throughout the rest of the growth rate range. In other words, there is a strong element of iron-link behavior in the cross-sectional layoff relation. In marked contrast, the quit relation shifts up and down as aggregate employment expands and contracts. Conditional on own-establishment growth, the quit rate is several percentage points lower in than in the other two periods. This pattern holds for the entire growth rate range and is most pronounced at rapidly shrinking establishments. Moreover, for shrinking establishments there is a clear ordering of the cross-sectional quit relations over the cycle: quit rates are highest in the 2006 expansion period, somewhat lower in the weak labor market early in the decade, and much lower in the severe recession of Extending our earlier metaphor, workers abandon ship at higher rates at more rapidly contracting employers, but they are much more likely to go down with the ship when stormy seas prevail. The separation relation largely inherits the cyclical behavior of the quit relation, although there are partly offsetting shifts in the underlying quit and layoff relations at rapidly shrinking establishments. Otherwise, the shifts in the separation relation look smaller only because the vertical scale covers a larger range. The cross-sectional hiring relation exhibits more stability over time than the separation 22

New Evidence on Job Vacancies, the Hiring Process, and Labor Market Flows

New Evidence on Job Vacancies, the Hiring Process, and Labor Market Flows New Evidence on Job Vacancies, the Hiring Process, and Labor Market Flows Steven J. Davis University of Chicago Econometric Society Plenary Lecture 3 January 2010, Atlanta Overview New evidence The role

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIRING, CHURN AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE. Edward P. Lazear James R. Spletzer

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIRING, CHURN AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE. Edward P. Lazear James R. Spletzer NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIRING, CHURN AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE Edward P. Lazear James R. Spletzer Working Paper 17910 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17910 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? No. 11-1 Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? Geoffrey M.B. Tootell Abstract: This public policy brief examines the relationship between trend inflation and commodity price increases and

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 010- November 8, 010 Is Structural Unemployment on the Rise? BY ROB VALLETTA AND KATHERINE KUANG An increase in U.S. aggregate labor demand reflected in rising job vacancies has not

More information

Dice DFH Measure of National Mean Vacancy Duration, January 2001 to October 2014

Dice DFH Measure of National Mean Vacancy Duration, January 2001 to October 2014 December 2014 Report Eight Job Vacancy Duration and Recruiting Intensity Hold Steady in October The Dice DFH Mean Vacancy Duration Measure stood at 24.5 working days in October, little changed from a revised

More information

Analysis of the U.S. labor market is a difficult

Analysis of the U.S. labor market is a difficult Openings and Labor Turnover Job Openings and Labor Turnover New tools for labor market analysis: JOLTS As a single, direct source for data on job openings, hires, and separations, the Job Openings and

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Association Between Variables

Association Between Variables Contents 11 Association Between Variables 767 11.1 Introduction............................ 767 11.1.1 Measure of Association................. 768 11.1.2 Chapter Summary.................... 769 11.2 Chi

More information

Quarterly Economics Briefing

Quarterly Economics Briefing Quarterly Economics Briefing March June 2015 2016 Review of Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation The exhibits below are updated to reflect the current economic

More information

On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy

On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy Daiki Asanuma Abstract This paper examines whether the survival of low-productivity firms in Japan has prevented economic recovery since the bursting of the financial bubble

More information

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix De Loecker Jan - Warzynski Frederic Princeton University, NBER and CEPR - Aarhus School of Business Forthcoming American Economic Review Abstract This is

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE I. Alternatives to Comparative Advantage Economies of Scale The fact that the largest share of world trade consists of the exchange of similar (manufactured) goods between

More information

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet) DEREE COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS EC 1101 PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS II FALL SEMESTER 2002 M-W-F 13:00-13:50 Dr. Andreas Kontoleon Office hours: Contact: a.kontoleon@ucl.ac.uk Wednesdays 15:00-17:00 Study

More information

Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics. 1. Unemployment and Vacancies over the Business Cycle

Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics. 1. Unemployment and Vacancies over the Business Cycle 14.461: Advanced Macroeconomics I Suman S. Basu, MIT Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics Part II of 14.461 covers topics in the macroeconomic analysis of labor markets. The purpose

More information

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3 Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3 1. When firms experience unplanned inventory accumulation, they typically: A) build new plants. B) lay off workers and reduce

More information

Equilibrium Unemployment Theory

Equilibrium Unemployment Theory Equilibrium Unemployment Theory Model Modifications Matthias S. Hertweck University of Basel March 26, 2012 Matthias S. Hertweck Equilibrium Unemployment Theory 1/38 Lecture Outline The Volatility Puzzle

More information

Analysis of JOLTS Research Estimates by Size of Firm

Analysis of JOLTS Research Estimates by Size of Firm Analysis of JOLTS Research Estimates by Size of Firm Katherine Bauer Klemmer 1 1 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2 Massachusetts Ave. NE, Washington DC 2212 Abstract The Job Openings and Labor Turnover

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 15, 2008 The recent dramatic rise in income inequality in the United

More information

Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve?

Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve? FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve? Regis Barnichon Federal Reserve Board of Governors Michael Elsby University of Michigan and

More information

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Updated for the 9th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement

More information

12.1 Introduction. 12.2 The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

12.1 Introduction. 12.2 The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve Chapter 12 Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve By Charles I. Jones Media Slides Created By Dave Brown Penn State University The short-run model summary: Through the MP curve the nominal interest rate

More information

This article presents a simple framework

This article presents a simple framework Net flows in the U.S. labor market, 990 200 Except in the most recent recession, net flows were from unemployment to employment (even in previous recessions), from employment to not in the labor force

More information

ON THE JOB SEARCH AND WORKING CAPITAL

ON THE JOB SEARCH AND WORKING CAPITAL IBS WORKING PAPER 6/2016 MAY 2016 ON THE JOB SEARCH AND WORKING CAPITAL Jacek Suda ibs working paper 6/2016 may 2016 ON THE JOB SEARCH AND WORKING CAPITAL Jacek Suda * Abstract We study the steady-state

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Top Ten Signs of Declining Business Dynamism and Entrepreneurship in the U.S.* John Haltiwanger University of Maryland and NBER.

Top Ten Signs of Declining Business Dynamism and Entrepreneurship in the U.S.* John Haltiwanger University of Maryland and NBER. Top Ten Signs of Declining Business Dynamism and Entrepreneurship in the U.S.* By John Haltiwanger University of Maryland and NBER August 2015 * This paper was written for the Kauffman Foundation New Entrepreneurial

More information

Hawaii New Business Formation an analysis of business birth, deaths, and survival rates

Hawaii New Business Formation an analysis of business birth, deaths, and survival rates an analysis of business birth, deaths, and survival rates November 2014 1 P a g e Table of Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 3 I. INTRODUCTION 7 II. BIRTHS AND DEATHS OF HAWAII BUSINESS ESTABLISHMENTS 10 III.

More information

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Key Concepts Aggregate Supply The aggregate production function shows that the quantity of real GDP (Y ) supplied depends on the quantity of labor (L ),

More information

Unemployment and Economic Recovery

Unemployment and Economic Recovery Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 11-17-2009 Unemployment and Economic Recovery Brian W. Cashell Congressional Research Service Follow this and

More information

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY Learning goals of this chapter: What forces bring persistent and rapid expansion of real GDP? What causes inflation? Why do we have business cycles? How

More information

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Employment and Pricing of Inputs Employment and Pricing of Inputs Previously we studied the factors that determine the output and price of goods. In chapters 16 and 17, we will focus on the factors that determine the employment level

More information

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17 Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17 Multiple Choice Questions 1. Built-in stability means that: A. an annually balanced budget will offset the procyclical tendencies created by state and local finance and thereby

More information

New York State Employment Trends

New York State Employment Trends New York State Employment Trends August 2015 Thomas P. DiNapoli New York State Comptroller Prepared by the Office of Budget and Policy Analysis Additional copies of this report may be obtained from: Office

More information

Case Study of Unemployment Insurance Reform in North Carolina

Case Study of Unemployment Insurance Reform in North Carolina Case Study of Unemployment Insurance Reform in North Carolina Marcus Hagedorn Fatih Karahan Iourii Manovskii Kurt Mitman Updated: March 25, 2014 Abstract In July 1, 2013 unemployed workers in North Carolina

More information

Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment

Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment Multiple Choice Questions 1. A mathematical expression relating the amount of output produced to quantities of capital and labor utilized is the (a) real

More information

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model University of California-Davis Economics 1B-Intro to Macro Handout 8 TA: Jason Lee Email: jawlee@ucdavis.edu I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model In this chapter we develop a model

More information

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r),

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Chapter 0 Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Section 0-: Overview We have already explored the basics of describing single variable data sets. However, when two quantitative variables

More information

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money.

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money. Macroeconomics ECON 2204 Prof. Murphy Problem Set 4 Answers Chapter 10 #1, 2, and 3 (on pages 308-309) 1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand

More information

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance There are two common approaches to forecasting: qualitative and quantitative. Qualitative forecasting methods are important when historical data is not available.

More information

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN C H A P T E R12 MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN LEARNING OBJECTIVES After reading and studying this chapter, you should be able to: Understand that both fiscal and monetary policy can

More information

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position Chapter 27: Taxation 27.1: Introduction We consider the effect of taxation on some good on the market for that good. We ask the questions: who pays the tax? what effect does it have on the equilibrium

More information

CALCULATIONS & STATISTICS

CALCULATIONS & STATISTICS CALCULATIONS & STATISTICS CALCULATION OF SCORES Conversion of 1-5 scale to 0-100 scores When you look at your report, you will notice that the scores are reported on a 0-100 scale, even though respondents

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Suvey of Macroeconomics, MBA 641 Fall 2006, Final Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Modern macroeconomics emerged from

More information

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets Chapter 6 Competitive Markets After reading Chapter 6, COMPETITIVE MARKETS, you should be able to: List and explain the characteristics of Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition Explain why a

More information

How To Calculate Size Class

How To Calculate Size Class Employment dynamics: small and large firms over the business cycle The use of the dynamic-sizing approach to measuring employment growth by size of firm provides information useful in the debate on small

More information

The United States has long been viewed as having among the world s most

The United States has long been viewed as having among the world s most Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 28, Number 3 Summer 2014 Pages 3 24 The Role of Entrepreneurship in US Job Creation and Economic Dynamism Ryan Decker, John Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda

More information

Section A. Index. Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1. Page 1 of 11. EduPristine CMA - Part I

Section A. Index. Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1. Page 1 of 11. EduPristine CMA - Part I Index Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1 EduPristine CMA - Part I Page 1 of 11 Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting

More information

Volume Title: Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data. Volume Author/Editor: Timothy Dunne, J. Bradford Jensen, and Mark J.

Volume Title: Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data. Volume Author/Editor: Timothy Dunne, J. Bradford Jensen, and Mark J. This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data Volume Author/Editor: Timothy Dunne, J. Bradford

More information

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D.

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Economic fluctuations, also called business cycles, are movements of GDP away from potential

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 9-1 Explain what relationships are shown by (a) the consumption schedule, (b) the saving schedule, (c) the investment-demand curve, and (d) the investment schedule.

More information

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION 7 The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION Since the 1970s one of the major issues in macroeconomics has been the extent to which low output and high unemployment

More information

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Burcu Eke UC3M Linear equations with one variable Recall what a linear equation is: y = b 0 + b 1 x is a linear equation with one variable, or equivalently, a straight

More information

The performance of immigrants in the Norwegian labor market

The performance of immigrants in the Norwegian labor market J Popul Econ (1998) 11:293 303 Springer-Verlag 1998 The performance of immigrants in the Norwegian labor market John E. Hayfron Department of Economics, University of Bergen, Fosswinckelsgt. 6, N-5007

More information

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 We focus on three aspects of a cut in payroll taxes as a stabilizer in a recession: (1)

More information

99.37, 99.38, 99.38, 99.39, 99.39, 99.39, 99.39, 99.40, 99.41, 99.42 cm

99.37, 99.38, 99.38, 99.39, 99.39, 99.39, 99.39, 99.40, 99.41, 99.42 cm Error Analysis and the Gaussian Distribution In experimental science theory lives or dies based on the results of experimental evidence and thus the analysis of this evidence is a critical part of the

More information

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year. Answers To Chapter 2 Review Questions 1. Answer a. To be classified as in the labor force, an individual must be employed, actively seeking work, or waiting to be recalled from a layoff. However, those

More information

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1 West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1 Labor market developments in the West Bank and Gaza (WBG) since the 1994 Oslo accords have reflected relatively sluggish growth performance.

More information

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Review of Fundamental Mathematics Review of Fundamental Mathematics As explained in the Preface and in Chapter 1 of your textbook, managerial economics applies microeconomic theory to business decision making. The decision-making tools

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

Higher and Rising (Figure 1)

Higher and Rising (Figure 1) Higher and Rising (Figure 1) Employer contributions to public school teacher pensions and Social Security are higher than contributions for privatesector professionals, the gap more than doubling between

More information

Engrossed Substitute Senate Bill 5373: Professional Employers Organizations A report to the Governor and Legislature December 2010

Engrossed Substitute Senate Bill 5373: Professional Employers Organizations A report to the Governor and Legislature December 2010 Engrossed Substitute Senate Bill 5373: Professional Employers Organizations A report to the Governor and Legislature December 2010 Prepared by the Employment Security Department Budget, Performance & Research

More information

Variable Compensation. Total Compensation

Variable Compensation. Total Compensation VARIABLE COMPENSATION AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL COMPENSATION: Variable compensation as a percentage of total compensation is a measurement that demonstrates how much of an organization s total compensation

More information

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization 2.1. Introduction Suppose that an economic relationship can be described by a real-valued

More information

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER Government Budget and Fiscal Policy 11 CHAPTER The National Budget The national budget is the annual statement of the government s expenditures and tax revenues. Fiscal policy is the use of the federal

More information

Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT WHAT THE TABLE SHOWS:

Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT WHAT THE TABLE SHOWS: Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT 7 8 9 5 United States Real GDP $ billions (fourth quarter) $,996 $,575 $,5 $,9 $5, $5,5 $5,9 $6,5 $7, % change over the four quarters.9% -.8% -.%.8%.%.%.6%.5%.8%

More information

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts Appendix LABOR UNION Key Concepts Market Power in the Labor Market A labor union is an organized group of workers that aims to increase wages and influence other job conditions. Craft union a group of

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

JOB OPENINGS AND LABOR TURNOVER APRIL 2015

JOB OPENINGS AND LABOR TURNOVER APRIL 2015 For release 10:00 a.m. (EDT) Tuesday, June 9, Technical information: (202) 691-5870 JoltsInfo@bls.gov www.bls.gov/jlt Media contact: (202) 691-5902 PressOffice@bls.gov USDL-15-1131 JOB OPENINGS AND LABOR

More information

Consumer Price Indices in the UK. Main Findings

Consumer Price Indices in the UK. Main Findings Consumer Price Indices in the UK Main Findings The report Consumer Price Indices in the UK, written by Mark Courtney, assesses the array of official inflation indices in terms of their suitability as an

More information

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach Texas Christian University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Department of Economics Texas Christian University Working

More information

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY Aggregate Supply represents the ability of an economy to produce goods and services. In the Long-run this ability to produce is based on the level of production

More information

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model Acknowledgement: Ed Sexton and Kerry Webb were the primary authors of the material contained in this lesson. Section : The Aggregate Expenditures Model Aggregate

More information

Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity

Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity Page 1 of 6 This report is also available as a PDF file. Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity The Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research met

More information

The Cost of Production

The Cost of Production The Cost of Production 1. Opportunity Costs 2. Economic Costs versus Accounting Costs 3. All Sorts of Different Kinds of Costs 4. Cost in the Short Run 5. Cost in the Long Run 6. Cost Minimization 7. The

More information

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts. Agenda What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycles.. 11-1 11-2 Business cycles are the short-run fluctuations in aggregate economic activity around its long-run growth path. Y Time 11-3 11-4 1 Components

More information

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EMPLOYMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE TEN LARGEST STATES

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EMPLOYMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE TEN LARGEST STATES Examining the Relationship Between Employment and Economic Growth in the Ten Largest States EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EMPLOYMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE TEN LARGEST STATES William Seyfried,

More information

Online Job Search and Unemployment Insurance during the Great Recession

Online Job Search and Unemployment Insurance during the Great Recession Online Job Search and Unemployment Insurance during the Great Recession Ioana Marinescu, University of Chicago Abstract The 2007 2009 U.S. recession led to large increases in the potential duration of

More information

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. The short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal at: A) a level of output determined by aggregate demand. B) the natural level of output. C) the level of output at which the

More information

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy Introduction Remember that countries trade either because they are different from one another or

More information

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework APPENDIX 3 TO CHAPTER 4 Supply and Demand in the arket for oney: The Liquidity Preference Framework Whereas the loanable funds framework determines the equilibrium interest rate using the supply of and

More information

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005) ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005) I. Multiple-Choice Questions (80%) 1. A compensating wage differential is A) an extra wage that will make all workers willing to accept undesirable

More information

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53 What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 *University of Modena and Reggio Emilia RECent (Center for Economic Research) Address:

More information

Section 14 Simple Linear Regression: Introduction to Least Squares Regression

Section 14 Simple Linear Regression: Introduction to Least Squares Regression Slide 1 Section 14 Simple Linear Regression: Introduction to Least Squares Regression There are several different measures of statistical association used for understanding the quantitative relationship

More information

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Wyatt Brooks University of Notre Dame Pau Pujolas McMaster University February, 2015 Abstract In this paper we use production and trade data to measure gains from

More information

The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model

The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model The AD-AS Model The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model Chapter 9 The AD-AS Model addresses two deficiencies of the AE Model: No explicit modeling of aggregate supply. Fixed price level. 2

More information

Duration and Bond Price Volatility: Some Further Results

Duration and Bond Price Volatility: Some Further Results JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE EDUCATION Volume 4 Summer 2005 Number 1 Duration and Bond Price Volatility: Some Further Results Hassan Shirvani 1 and Barry Wilbratte 2 Abstract This paper evaluates the

More information

Topic 1 - Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics?

Topic 1 - Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics? Topic 1 - Introduction to Labour Economics Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370 What is Labour Economics? Let s begin by looking at what economics is in general Study of interactions between decision

More information

Discussion of Bacchetta, Benhima and Poilly : Corporate Cash and Employment

Discussion of Bacchetta, Benhima and Poilly : Corporate Cash and Employment Summary Discussion of Bacchetta, Benhima and Poilly : Corporate Cash and Employment Vivien Lewis (KU Leuven) "New Developments in Business Cycle Analysis : The Role of Labor Markets and International Linkages"

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Chapter 11 Perfect Competition - Sample Questions MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Perfect competition is an industry with A) a

More information

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 11 FISCAL POLICY* Key Concepts The Federal Budget The federal budget is an annual statement of the government s expenditures and tax revenues. Using the federal budget to achieve macroeconomic

More information

Web Appendix for Business Volatility, Job Destruction, and Unemployment

Web Appendix for Business Volatility, Job Destruction, and Unemployment **NOT INTENDED FOR PUBLICATION Web Appendix for Business Volatility, Job Destruction, and Unemployment By Steven J. Davis, R. Jason Faberman, John Haltiwanger, Ron Jarmin and Javier Miranda 1 August 2009

More information

June 2015. Federal Employee Participation Patterns in the Thrift Savings Plan 2008-2012

June 2015. Federal Employee Participation Patterns in the Thrift Savings Plan 2008-2012 June 2015 Federal Employee Participation Patterns in the Thrift Savings Plan 2008-2012 Federal Employee Participation Patterns in the Thrift Savings Plan, 2008-2012 Executive summary This report examines

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

The impact of the recession on the labour market

The impact of the recession on the labour market The impact of the recession on the labour market 14 May 2009 Chapter 4: Pensioner income and expenditure Pension Trends Impact of the recession on the labour market Introduction Chapter 1: Recent changes

More information

The Life Cycle of Nazarene Churches Kenneth E. Crow, Ph.D.

The Life Cycle of Nazarene Churches Kenneth E. Crow, Ph.D. The Life Cycle of Nazarene Churches Kenneth E. Crow, Ph.D. Churches, like people, change as they grow older. While there are important differences between the stages of human and organizational development,

More information

Labor Demand The Labor Market

Labor Demand The Labor Market Labor Demand The Labor Market 1. Labor demand 2. Labor supply Assumptions Hold capital stock fixed (for now) Workers are all alike. We are going to ignore differences in worker s aptitudes, skills, ambition

More information

Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT WHAT THE TABLE SHOWS:

Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT WHAT THE TABLE SHOWS: Economic Forecast OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT 7 8 9 1 11 1 13 1 15 United States Real GDP $ billions (fourth quarter) $1,996 $1,575 $1,5 $1,9 $15, $15,5 $15,9 $16,51 $17,1 % change over the four quarters 1.9%

More information

TEACHING AGGREGATE PLANNING IN AN OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT COURSE

TEACHING AGGREGATE PLANNING IN AN OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT COURSE TEACHING AGGREGATE PLANNING IN AN OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT COURSE Johnny C. Ho, Turner College of Business, Columbus State University, Columbus, GA 31907 David Ang, School of Business, Auburn University Montgomery,

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 2015-10 March 30, 2015 Majority of Hires Never Report Looking for a Job BY CARLOS CARRILLO-TUDELA, BART HOBIJN, PATRYK PERKOWSKI, AND LUDO VISSCHERS Every month, millions of workers

More information