Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle"

Transcription

1 Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle Jess Benhabib Department of Economics New York University Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Abstract We show that under indeterminacy aggregate demand shocks are able to explain not only aspects of actual uctuations that standard RBC models predict fairly well, but also aspects of actual uctuations that standard RBC models cannot explain, such as the hump-shaped, trend reverting impulse responses to transitory shocks found in US output, investment, and hours. Indeterminacy arises in our model due to capacity utilization and mild increasing returns to scale. We wish to thank Jordi Gali, Stephanie Schmitt-Groh e, Karl Shell, and Martin Uribe for very useful discussions and comments. Technical support from the C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics at New York University is gratefully acknowledged.

2 1. Introduction Recently, general equilibrium real business cycle models have been subject to a number of criticisms. A basic criticism is the heavy reliance of such models on technology shocks to explain business cycle facts (for example, Blanchard, 1993; Cochrane, 1994; Evans, 1992; Gordon, 1993; Mankiw, 1989; Summers, 1986). Another is the lack of an endogenous ampli cation and propagation mechanism, which has resulted in the failure of standard RBC models to explain the large hump-shaped, trend-reverting output responses to transitory shocks (Cogley and Nason, 1995, Watson, 1993). Finally, real business cycle models have been criticized for failing to match the forecastable comovements of basic macroeconomic variables observed in the data (see Rotemberg and Woodford, 1996). 1 These problems are not unrelated. Demand shocks are thought to be important for generating the business cycle because components of aggregate demand, such as consumption and investment, may reinforce each other, resulting in a multiplier-accelerator mechanism that can generate highly persistent, trendreverting output dynamics. The mutual reinforcement among components of aggregate demand is possible if there exists unutilized resources that allow for the expansion of output with little or no increase in marginal costs in the short run, meeting or ful lling the rise of total demand. In contrast, all resources in equilibrium business cycle models are fully utilized because prices adjust quickly to clear the markets. Under the assumption of the diminishing marginal product of labor, demand shocks would have a crowdingout e ect, resulting in the negative comovements of the components of aggregate demand and in having minimal impact on aggregate employment and output. Consequently, standard RBC models have relied on supply shocks to explain the business cycle. In this paper we show how to capture the more \Keynesian" features of the demand-shock driven business cycle without abandoning the hypotheses of market clearing and exible prices. There are three essential elements in our model that when acting together, can generate the business cycle facts observed in data, 1 Recently many e orts have been made to nd ways to enrich the internal propagation mechanisms of RBC models driven by technology shocks. Prominent examples include Burnside and Eichenbaum, 1996, Andolfatto, 1996, and Carlstrom and Fuerst,

3 and meet the criticisms directed at the RBC model. The rst is variable capacity utilization. The second is the presence of demand shocks that exhibit some persistence. The third is the presence of small and empirically reasonable externalities that gives rise to indeterminacy. 2 We show that these three elements are essential and indispensable in order to generate a propagation mechanism that ampli es the impact of temporary demand shocks on output, investment and hours in a hump-shaped manner. 3;4 Variable capacity utilization has the e ect of increasing the marginal product of labor in the short-run by enhancing the output elasticity of labor. Coupled with a mild production externality that is consistent with recent empirical estimates, it makes the model behave as if there were short-run increasing returns to the labor input. This factor is crucial not only because it generates the desired forecastable comovements in consumption, investment, hours and output, but also because it gives rise to the indeterminacy that generates the hump-shaped, trend reverting time series observed in the data by enriching the internal dynamics of the model. We examine three di erent types of aggregate demand shocks: shocks to consumption demand, shocks to government spending, and sunspot shocks to investors' animal spirits. 5 We investigate whether the endogenous propagation mechanism induced by indeterminacy is capable of giving these demand shocks a primary role in explaining the business cycle. Among other things, we nd: a) All three types of demand shocks can each generate positive comovements among output, consumption, investment and hours that are comparable to predictions of standard RBC models under technology shocks. b) Small transitory demand shocks to consumption and government expenditure can generate large, hump- 2 For an excellent and thorough analysis of why models of indeterminacy driven by sunspots alone cannot improve much upon the standard RBC model, see Schmitt-Grohe (2000), and also Schmitt-Grohe, (1997). For a general survey of the literature of indeterminacy and sunspots in macroeconomics, see Benhabib and Farmer (1999). 3 Although small external e ects can give rise to indeterminacy, externalities that do not generate indeterminacy will not give rise to hump-shaped dynamics. In our model, the minimum degree of returns to scale induced by externalities necessary for indeterminacy is in the range of 1:06 1:104; which is plausible even judged by the more recent empirical estimates on returns to scale (e.g., Basu and Fernald, 1997; and Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, 1995). 4 The emergence of hump-shaped impulse responses to monetary shocks has been discussed in models with credit constraints when there are investment delays. See Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist, Sunspot shocks or extrinsic uncertainty were intoduced into the economics literature by Shell (1977) and by Cass and Shell (1983). 3

4 shaped, trend-reverting impulse responses for output, investment and hours. c) Combined with shocks to investors' animal spirits, each of these fundamental demand shocks can generate autocorrelation functions for output growth, investment growth, and hours growth that closely match the post-war US economy. 6 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we present further empirical evidence on the trend-reverting dynamics for the US economy. In particular, we show that the responses of consumption, investment, and hours to temporary demand shocks all have hump-shaped features, and they are strongly correlated with output. In section 3, we show that a general equilibrium model featuring indeterminacy is capable of explaining these stylized dynamics with aggregate demand shocks. The model is tested using the method proposed by Cogley and Nason (1995) in section 4. Section 5 concludes the paper. 2. Stylized Responses to Demand Following Blanchard and Quah (1989) and Cogley and Nason (1995), we decompose aggregate output, consumption, investment, and hours into two components, one that pertains to permanent shocks, and the other that pertains to transitory shocks. The transitory components in these variables are interpreted by Blanchard and Quah as uctuations due to aggregate demand shocks. We use the ratio of investment to output as the covariate in a series of bivariate VAR analyses to carry out the Blanchard -Quah decomposition. 7 Balanced growth in RBC models implies that the investment to output ratio is stationary. The demand shocks so identi ed have the natural interpretation of being disturbances that a ect shortrun aggregate savings, such as temporary changes in government spending, in consumers' preferences, and in rms' autonomous investment. These demand shocks are perfectly matched by our general equilibrium model. 8 6 Sunspots cannot by themselves generate the hump-shaped dynamics, as has been demonstrated by Schmitt-Grohe (2000). 7 Namely, the growth rate of output, consumption, investment, and hours are each paired with the investment to output ratio to identify the permanent and transitory components of each series. This is similar to Cochrane (1994) who uses consumption to output ratio as the covariate. 8 Cogley and Nason (1995) use per capita hours as the covariate in carrying out the Blanchard- Quah decomposition. We choose the investment to output ratio also because it seems to be more stationary than the per capita hours series for post-war US economy. The impulse responses identi ed for the two covariates are nevertheless very similar. 4

5 Figure 1 shows impulse responses to demand from output, consumption, investment, and hours respectively. They all exhibit the familiar hump-shaped, trend-reverting dynamics. These dynamics are very similar to those identi ed by Blanchard and Quah (1989), and the responses of di erent variables move very closely together. To further ensure that the responses so identi ed re ect responses to demand disturbances, we also use the government expenditure to GDP ratio as the covariate in carrying out the Blanchard-Quah decomposition. The identi ed responses to innovations in the government expenditure to GDP ratio are very similar to those identi ed using the investment to output ratio. 9 Figure 2 shows the implied autocorrelation functions (ACF) for growth rates. The transitory components of all four variables exhibit positive serial correlation in growth rates for lags of the rst two quarters, and show negative serial correlation in growth rates for lags beyond three to four quarters. This is consistent with the empirical ndings of Cogley and Nason (1995). As is pointed out by Cogley and Nason, a central weakness of the real-businesscycle paradigm as a convincing explanation of the business cycle is its failure to account for the above stylized business cycle dynamics. Under transitory demand shocks, standard RBC models generate monotonic impulse responses for output, negative serial autocorrelation for output growth, and negative cross correlation of consumption and investment. In other words, contrary to conventional wisdom and postwar US data, demand shocks do not seem to have fully expansionary multiplier e ects in RBC models. This is illustrated in gure The data used are log quarterly US real xed investment, consumption expenditure on nondurables and services, and total government expenditure. All data series are from CITIBASE (1960:1-1994:4). Output is de ned as the sum of consumption, investment, and government expenditure. 2 lags are used in the VAR estimation. Both the investment to output ratio and the government spending to GDP ratio have a weak time trend. We used two di erent detrending methods in the VAR estimation to render stationarity for the covariate. One uses a linear time trend and the other uses the Hodrick-Prescott trend (i.e., the HP ltered investment to output ratio was used as the covariate in bivariate VAR analyses). The results are very similar for both typesoftrend.thehp-trendcasesarereportedinfigure1. 10 Figure 3 shows the impulse responses of output and investment in the King-Plosser-Rebelo (1988) model to a consumption demand shock. The responses of the model to a government spending shock are very similar. The consumption demand shock follows an AR(1) process and is modeled as a disturbance to the subsistence level in the utility function, as in Baxter and King (1992). For more detailed description about shocks to consumption demand and government expenditure, see Section 3. 5

6 3. Searching for the Propagation Mechanism In this section, we show how to bring the real business cycle paradigm into closer conformity with the data. In particular, we show that indeterminacy arising from variable capacity utilization and mild externalities enables demand shocks to play an essential role in replicating the actual business cycle uctuations The Model This is the one-sector RBC model with variable capacity utilization studied by Wen (1998), based on Greenwood et al. (1989), Burnside and Eichenbaum (1996), Baxter and King (1992), Benhabib and Farmer (1994), and Farmer and Guo (1994). A representative agent in the model chooses sequences of consumption, hours, capacity utilization, and capital accumulation to solve 1! X max E 0 t Ãlog(c t t ) a n1+ t 1+ t=0 subject to c t + i t + g t = t (e t k t ) n (1 ) t ; (3.1) k t+1 = i t +(1 ± t )k t ; where is a random shock to the subsistence level of consumption, which can generate the urge to consume (Baxter and King, 1992); g is government spending and is modeled as an exogenous stochastic process representing a pure resource drain on the economy (Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992); e 2 [0; 1] denotes capital utilization rate, and is a measure of production externalities and is de ned as a function of average aggregate output which individuals take as parametric: = h (ek) n 1 i ; 0: (3.2) When the externality parameter is zero, the model is reduced to a standard RBC model studied by Greenwood et al (1988). To have an interior solution for e in the steady state, we follow Greenwood et al. by assuming that the capital stock depreciates faster if it is used more intensively: ± t = e µ t ; µ > 1; (3.3) which imposes a convex cost structure on capital utilization. 6

7 As pointed out by Benhabib and Farmer (1994), the externality model can also be cast in form of a monopolistic competition model with increasing returns to scale at the individual rm level that produces intermediate goods. If the nal output sector's production technology is de ned as Z Y = 1 y(i) di ; and the technology for producing an intermediate commodity y(i) is given by y(i) =[e(i)k(i)] a n(i) b ; then the aggregate production function in the model has the reduced form in a symmetric equilibrium: y =(ek) a n b : If markup is de ned as the logarithm of price-marginal cost ratio, then it can be shown that the markup in the model is given by ¹ =ln 1 1+( 1) ; where ( 1) is the inverse of the price elasticity of demand facing an intermediate goods producing rm. For the monopolistic competition model to be exactly equivalent to the externality model, we simply set a = ; b =1 ; and a + b =1+ : 11 This implies that = 1 = 1 a+b 1+ : The markup is therefore given by ¹ ' : To facilitate comparison with the existing literature, we assume that all shocks to fundamentals follow univariate AR(1) processes in log: " log( t ) log(g t ) # = " 1 ½ ½ g #" ¹ ¹ g # + " ½ 0 0 ½ g #" log( t 1 ) log(g t 1 ) # + " " t " gt # ; where var à " t " gt! " ¾ 2 = 0 0 ¾g 2 # : 11 See Benhabib and Farmer (1994). 7

8 Notice that innovations in the fundamental shocks are assumed to be orthogonal. To solve the model, we log-linearize the rst order conditions around the steady state as in King et al. (1988). To allow for the study of investors' animal spirits as a possible source of aggregate demand uncertainty, we arrange the system of linearized equations in a way such that investment rather than the Lagrangian multiplier appears in the state vector. Denoting S as the state vector, and Z as the vector of control variables, the model can be reduced to the following system of linear di erence equations (the hat variables denote percentage deviations from their steady state values): S t+1 = WS t + R t+1 ; Z t = HS t ; where S t = h ^kt ^{ t ^ t ^g t i 0 ; Zt = h ^c t ^n t ^e t i 0 and t+1 is a vector of one-step ahead forecasting errors that satisfy and t+1 = S t+1 E t S t+1 ; E t t+1 =0: Notice that the rst element in t+1 = k t+1 E t k t+1 =0; since k t+1 is known at the beginning of time t; the last two elements in t+1 =[" +1 " gt+1 ] 0 ; and the second element in t+1 = i t+1 E t i t+1. Thus the law of motion for the model's state vector can be written as: ^k t+1! 11! 12! 13! 14 ^k ^{ t ^ =! 21! 22! 23! t ^{ t t ½ ^ + r 1 r 2 r " t " t gt+1 5 (3.4) v ^g t ½ g ^g t st+1 where v st+1 ^{ t+1 E t^{ t+1 : When the equilibrium is unique, one of the eigenvalues of W should lie outside the unit circle, so that investment i t can be determined uniquely by solving forward the system under the expectation operator E t to obtain a decision rule for i(t) that depends only on current capital stock k t and time t realizations to the fundamentals f t ;g t g : If both eigenvalues of W lie inside the unit circle, however, the steady state is stable. In that case, the model 8

9 is indeterminate and has multiple equilibria. Hence, the state space of the model includes not only the capital stock and the realizations of the exogenous state variables, f t ;g t g ; but also the time t investment i t. Notice that under indeterminacy the decision rule for the initial investment at time t (starting from the steady state) takes the special form: ^{ t = r 1 " t + r 2 " gt + r 3 v st : Under rational expectations, the forecasting error, v st = i t E t 1 i t ; follows i:i:d processes, implying that rational agents do not make systematic errors in forecasting the future. Since v st can either re ect innovations in fundamentals or be purely extraneous, it can be called sunspots or animal spirits, and can be interpreted as shocks to autonomous investment. We de ne the vector V t =(" t ;" gt ;v st ) 0 ; where v st denotes sunspots. 12 There are potentially three types of aggregate demand disturbances in the model: innovations to government spending " g, innovations to consumption demand " ; and innovations to autonomous investment v s. Hence, sunspots can act as an equilibrium selection device. The covariance matrix for V is given by: = ¾ 2 0 ¾ s 0 ¾ 2 g ¾ gs ¾ s ¾ gs ¾ 2 s where the correlations between sunspots and innovations in the fundamentals can take values in the interval [ 1; 1] : Since the linear version of the model imposes no restrictions on the variance and covariance of sunspots, they need to be speci ed exogenously. Notice that in the decision rule for ^{ t ; the rst two terms including r 1 and r 2 are completely determined by preferences and technologies of the model, but the third term is arbitrary, depending on the variance of sunspots. We can therefore take the normalization r 3 =1: To see how the model responds to shocks under indeterminacy, take the simpler case where the shocks are all i:i:d (½ = ½ g =0): Starting from the steady state at time t, wehave: ³^kt 1 ;^{ t 1 ; ^ t 1 ; ^g t 1 =0: In addition, we have ^kt =0: Time t innovations (" t ;" gt ;v st ) thus a ect the control vector Z t through their impact on (i t ; t ;g t ) : Therefore, autonomous investment is clearly important in determining 12 When v s contains innovations to the fundamental shocks, it implies that the sunspots are correlated with fundamental shocks ; 9

10 the initial responses of the model. However, how the initial impact of shocks gets propagated through time does not depend so much on autonomous investment. Rather, it depends crucially on the eigenvalues of the matrix, " #!11! = 12 :! 21! 22 This is so because impulse responses j periods ahead are determined by the autoregressive equation: " ^kt+j ^{ t+j # = j " ^kt ^{ t # ; j =1; 2; 3; :::; 1: The eigenvalues of therefore govern the patterns of propagation. If the eigenvalues are complex, for example, the model economy will oscillate around the steady state after an initial disturbance, showing profoundly di erent propagation mechanism from the cases where the eigenvalues are real valued. If the model is determinate, however, it has only monotonic transitional dynamics (in the standard RBC case where!>0) because the law of motion for the state vector reduces to ^k t+1 =!^k t : This illustrates why indeterminacy can profoundly change the propagation mechanism of a RBC model. To quantify the model's eigenvalues, we calibrate the structural parameters of the model as follows. We set the capital share to 0:3; the time discount factor to 0:99; the inverse elasticity of labor supply to 0; and choose µ such that the rate of capital depreciation in the steady state is 10 percent a year. The externality parameter is most crucial in the model and is left free for experiments. Table 1 reports the model's eigenvalues when the externality takes on different values. The rst column lists the values of ; the second column lists the corresponding eigenvalues, and the third column lists the modulus of the complex eigenvalues, which indicate indeterminacy if the modulus is less than one. 10

11 Table 1. Ext. ( ) Eigenvalues Modulus , , , , , :377i :375i :351i :327i :289i :085i :060i :049i It is seen from Table 1 that indeterminacy and complex roots emerge under mild externalities. The minimum degree of the externality required for indeterminacy is 0:104, 13 and that for complex roots is 0:105, implying a markup around 0:1 or a degree of aggregate returns to scale around 1:10 1:11, which is very plausible even when judged by more recent empirical studies (e.g., Basu and Fernald, 1997; and Burnside et al., 1995). 14 Notice that the aggregate labor demand curve is downward sloping as in Benhabib and Farmer (1996) when indeterminacy arises in the model, which is in sharp contrast to the earlier model of Benhabib and Farmer (1994) Impulse responses to demand shocks As a benchmark, we assume that is diagonal. The parameters associated with exogenous variables are chosen as follows. We set the persistence parameter for g 13 One of the eigenvalues changes sign from +1 to 1 between =0:1029 and =0:1030: 14 The degree of markup or externality required for indeterminacy can be reduced even further if the time discount factor is larger or if the steady-state depreciation rate is higher. For example, when = 0:995; the minimum value of for indeterminacy reduces to 0:057. Complex eigenvalues arise for = 0:058: 15 The slope of the aggregate labor demand curve (in logs) is given by (1 )(1 + ) 1: For example, when =0:108; the slope is 0:22: 11

12 as ½ g =0:9 (a magnitude similar to that estimated by Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992), and the persistence parameter for as ½ =0:9 (a magnitude similar to that estimated by Baxter and King, 1992). In order to highlight the dramatic e ect of indeterminacy, two di erent values of are used in generating impulse responses of the model. Figure 4 corresponds to the case of =0:1 where the steady state is a saddle and the equilibrium is unique. It shows the impulse responses of output, consumption, investment and hours to one standard deviation increases in " (solid lines) and " g (dashed lines) respectively. Figure 5 corresponds to the case of = 0:108 where the steady state is a sink and the equilibrium is indeterminate. It shows impulse responses of income, consumption, investment and hours to a one standard deviation increase in " (solid lines), in " g (long dashed lines), and in " s (short dashed lines) respectively. Several features of the model that generate Figure 4 deserve mention. First, capacity utilization and a mild externality can generate positive comovements in the model under shocks to demand. This is in stark contrast with the standard RBC model examined by Baxter and King (1992), where an extremely high externality is necessary to generate positive comovements. Second, the impulse responses of all variables to demand shocks are still monotonic, as opposed to hump-shaped, when the steady state is a saddle, despite the presence of capacity utilization and increasing returns. Figure 5 shows a completely di erent picture when the externality is slightly increased to a level such that the \capacity-utilization augmented" short-run returns to labor are greater than one and indeterminacy is present. 16 The impulse response of output to fundamental demand shocks becomes hump-shaped, revealing a signi cant change in the model's dynamic structure. The output response to sunspots (long dashed lines), although continuing to show positive comovements with other variables, nevertheless fails to exhibit the initial hump. This observa- 16 The social returns to labor is only 1:108(1 ) =0:7756: Variable capacity utilization makes the model behave as if the short-run output elasticity of labor is greater than one. According to Wen (1998), the "capacity utilization augmented" short-run elasticity of labor is µ (1 )(1 + ) µ (1 + ) =1:016: See Wen (1998c) for detailed analyses on the dynamic e ect of capacity utilization on returns to labor. 12

13 tion, that sunspots cannot generate hump-shaped impulse responses for output, has been discussed by Schmitt-Grohe (2000). 17 So far we have not allowed the model to respond simultaneously to both fundamental shocks and sunspots. Figure 5 suggests that mixing fundamental shocks and sunspots shocks should not destroy the hump-shaped impulse response patterns of the model as long as the variance of sunspots is not extremely large relative to that of fundamental shocks. Figure 6 compares several possible response functions of output to a fundamental shock (" ) and sunspots (" s ) when the correlation between " and " s takes ve possible values: ¾ s = f1; 0:5; 0; 0:5; 1g : We choose the standard deviation of " to be one, and that of the sunspots to be 0:5. 18 It is seen in gure 6 that regardless the correlations between sunspots and fundamentals, the impulse response functions of output are always hump-shaped. As a matter of fact, if the relative standard deviation of sunspots is allowed to vary instead of being xed at 0:5, the model can generate any one of those impulse response functions shown in gure 6 for any given ¾ s : This means that adding sunspots will certainly improves the model's empirical t since the model tends to generate too much hump under fundamental shocks alone (Figure 5). 19 The hump-shaped propagation mechanism that arises under indeterminacy can be understood as follows. In a standard RBC model without indeterminacy, the only channel of propagation is capital accumulation. This, however, is an extremely weak channel for transmitting the impact of shocks, because capital is a stock while investment is a ow. Given that the steady-state investment to capital ratio is small, even a large change in the current investment ow induced by a technology shock would have little impact on the next period capital stock. In addition, since higher consumption in the next period is accompanied by higher leisure, labor supply would immediately fall after the impact period, which would 17 It is worth emphasizing that the hump-shaped impulse responses of output to the fundamental demand shocks do not depend on the persistence of these shocks. Even when they are i:i:d processes, the impulse responses are still hump-shaped, except that the humps are too sharp and are less smooth than the data. 18 To compute the impulse responses of output to multiple shocks, we draw two i:i:d processes from standard normal distributions (taking the rst process as " t ), and mix them in various degrees to form the sunspots variable " st so that the correlation between sunspots and the rst series equal exactly to the pre-speci ed values. We then generate arti cial time series of output by simulating the model. The impulse response functions of output for each possible case in gure 6 are estimated using the corresponding arti cial data sample. 19 Sunspots help here because they change the magnitude of initial responses of the model, so as to make them less hump-shaped. 13

14 e ectively terminate the possibility of continuous increases in output. For the same reason, a demand shock can only generate a negative comovement between and consumption and investment. Therefore, in the standard RBC model, output dynamics mirrors the dynamics of technology shocks (for more detailed analyses of the propagation mechanism of standard RBC models, see Wen, 1995). By contrast, in our model, variable capacity utilization o ers an additional channel of propagation that can propagate not only supply shocks but also demand shocks in a manner that better conforms to the data. Variable capacity utilization coupled with a mild externality on labor mimics increasing returns to labor, inducing consumption and labor to comove in response to a demand shock. Therefore, even in response to a demand shock, output can rise su±ciently to permit positive investment and a higher capital stock in the next period. Since consumption follows permanent income, a higher future capital stock, coupled with the persistence of demand shocks, leads to higher future consumption, and therefore to higher future labor supply and higher future output. Continuous output expansion is thus sustainable by aggregate demand. In other words, the propagation mechanism in our model is powerful not because more capital stock leads to more output, but because more capital stock leads to more consumption demand (the permanent-income or wealth e ect), which in turn leads to higher capacity utilization, more employment and more output (the returns-to-scale effect) in subsequent periods. This is a cumulative process of expansion, similar to a classic multiplier-accelerator mechanism. As the expansion continues, the rising marginal cost of capacity utilization, and the diminishing marginal product of capital dictate a tapering o in the increases of output and a decline in the growth rate of the capital stock. The result is that sooner or later, the capital stock and output must stop growing, and hence consumption must begin to fall. A reduction in consumption demand then triggers a contraction in labor supply and in output. As the contraction begins, the propagation mechanism reverses direction, leading to a cumulative process of contraction. When the capital stock falls, however, its marginal product starts to rise, and a new round of expansion eventually follows. The non-monotonic and cumulative dynamics of output growth therefore depends crucially on the richer two-dimensional dynamics of indeterminacy that allows these oscillatory hump-shaped impulse responses. 14

15 4. An Econometric Test Cogley and Nason demonstrate that standard RBC models cannot explain two stylized facts about US GDP: positive serial correlation of GDP growth and a hump-shaped, trend reverting impulse response function to innovations in the temporary component. Accordingly, this section employs the same econometric procedure proposed by Cogley and Nason to test whether indeterminacy has the potential to account for the aspects of actual uctuations which the standard realbusiness-cycle paradigm cannot explain. Speci cally, we calibrate and estimate the model's parameters and ask how likely it is that the actual US sample time series are generated from a world that is equivalent to our model. We calibrate most of the parameters following the existing literature. Specifically, we set the capital share to 0:3; thetimediscountfactor to 0:99; the steady-state rate of capital depreciation ± to 0:025, the inverse labor supply elasticity to 0 (Hansen, 1985), the persistence parameter for government spending ½ g to 0:96 (estimated by Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992), the persistence parameter for consumption shock ½ to 0:97 (estimated by Baxter and King, 1992), and the externality parameter to 0:108 (consistent with indeterminacy). We arbitrarily set the standard deviation of sunspots, ¾ s =0:01; and choose parameters, f¾ ;¾ g g ; so that each of them acting alone with the sunspots can generate autocorrelation functions of output growth that matches the data as closely as possible. 20 To show the robustness of our empirical results, we let the correlation between sunspots and fundamental shocks take di erent values between 1 and 1; so as to show that the model's successes do not depend on whether and how sunspots are correlated with fundamentals. These parameterizations are reported in Table 2 (the pre-speci ed values for cross correlation between sunspots and fundamentals are listed on the last two columns). 20 This is equivalent to an informal estimation procedure called methods of moments widely adopted in the RBC literature. Notice in table 2 that as the correlation parameter changes, ¾ changes accordingly but ¾ g barely changes at all. 15

16 Table 2. Calibration ¾ ¾ g ¾ s ¾ s ¾ gs Model 0:01 Model A 1 0:009 0:01 1 Model A 2 0:012 0:01 0:5 Model A 3 0:015 0:01 0 Model A 4 0:022 0:01 0:5 Model A 5 0:022 0:01 1 Model B 1 0:0042 0:01 1 Model B 2 0:0042 0:01 0:5 Model B 3 0:0042 0:01 0 Model B 4 0:0042 0:01 0:5 Model B 5 0:0042 0:01 1 Model is our benchmark that has sunspots shocks only. Then we add consumption demand shocks (models A 1 A 5 ) and government shocks (models B 1 B 5 ) respectively into the environment. We test each of these versions of the model with respect to impulse response functions and autocorrelation functions by computing the generalized Q test statistics, which are de ned as follows: Q =(^c c) 0 ^V 1 c (^c c) : The vector ^c is the sample impulse response function or autocorrelation function, and c is the mean of N (= 500) simulated impulse response functions or autocorrelation functions computed from simulated time series of the same length as the actual data, namely, 140 quarters. 21 That is, c = 1 N P Ni=1 c i. The covariance matrix, ^V c ; is estimated by ^V c = 1 N NX (c i c)(c i c) 0 : i=1 The test statistic Q has approximate  2 distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number of elements in c. Following Cogley and Nason, the number of lags 21 Since all shocks in the model are transitory demand shocks (there are no permanent demand shocks), we do not use the Blanchard-Quah decomposition to estimate conditional impulse response functions. Instead, a univariate VAR is su±cient to obtain the conditional impulse response functions for each variable. We use a lag length of four in the univariate VARs. The autocorrelatiion functions are simply computed by their formula. 16

17 chosen is 8, which gives a critical value of 20:1 at the 1% signi cance level and a critical value of 15:5 at the 5% signi cance level. The test results for autocorrelation function of growth are reported in table 3. The benchmark model driven by sunspots only perform poorly in matching the data, consistent with the ndings of Schmitt-Grohe (2000). The various versions of the model (A 1 B 5 ) driven by a combination of one of the fundamental demand shocks and sunspots, however, perform extremely well with respect to all variables except consumption growth. The results indicate that the covariance between sunspots and fundamental shocks do not matter, as long as both types of shocks arepresent. Wehavealsoaddedintable3(lastrow)theversion(ModelC)in which all three types of shocks are present, so as to see whether it can improve the match on consumption growth. Figure 5 suggests that the 3 types of shocks have very di erent e ect on consumption, suggesting that a mixture of them can generate a hump-shaped consumption response function similar to the data. The last row in table 3 con rms this conjecture. Table 3. Q Statistics Q acf y i n c Model 120:9 113:3 156:2 1:9 A A A A A B B B B B Model C 2:1 5:6 12:2 11:9 The test statistics for the output impulse response function show similar results. Namely, the models driven by fundamental shocks (either " or " g )along with sunspots perform much better than the models driven by sunspot shocks alone. To see this graphically, gures 7, 8, and 9 show the output impulse response functions of three di erent versions of the model respectively. Figure 7 corresponds to model ; gure 8 corresponds to model A (version 3); and gure 8 17

18 corresponds to model B (version 3): 22 It is seen that allowing for demand shocks to preferences or government expenditure in the model produces very good matches to the data with regard to output dynamics (the Q test statistics are 4:1 and 2:5 respectively), while the benchmark model (driven by sunspots only) fails to generate the initial hump in the response function of output, resulting in an autocorrelation function of output growth that falls short in matching the data. Hence, persistent AR(1) demand shocks to fundamentals are essential for explaining the US business cycles. 23 The impulse response functions for investment and hours, even though they have very similar shapes to those of the data (see Figure 10), fail the Q test. This is so because our model does not generate the exact relative volatilities for investment and hours. 24 The Q test statistics are very sensitive to even such small level di erentials and therefore tend to magnify the di erence between model and data. Hence, despite the very close matches for the impulse response functions between our model and the data, our model fails the Q test with respect to investment and hours. Finally, we check whether the model is able to explain aspects of actual uctuations that standard RBC models predict fairly well, with respect to the small number of second moments stressed by Kydland and Prescott (1982). Table 4 shows that our model is comparable to the standard model of King, Plosser and Rebelo (1988) It makes little di erence which version of type A or type B to use. 23 Notice that persistent AR(1) shocks do not generate hump-shaped impulse responses in standard RBC models (see gure 3 and Cogley and Nason, 1995). 24 The variance of the shocks in our model are adjusted to match the response of output to theimpulseattheperiodofimpact. Analternativestrategymaybetochoosethevarianceof the shocks to match a weighted sum of the initial responses of these key variables to the impulse so as to further improve their Q statistics. 25 The common parameters of the models are the same. Notice that, as expected, consumption is too smooth under the government and sunspot demand shocks, but not under the preference shock. A combination of the three demand shocks and the technology shock, properly weighted, can be used to further improve the match between the data and the model. 18

19 Table 4. Selective Moments ¾ c =¾ y ¾ i =¾ y ¾ n =¾ y corr(c; y) corr(i; y) corr(n; y) US Economy (1960:4-1994:4) 26 0:65 4:16 1:07 0:91 0:89 0:85 RBC Model: Technology Shock 27 0:61 3:60 0:67 0:75 0:95 0:74 EBC Model: Consumption Shock 28 0:65 3:79 0:96 0:64 0:93 0:998 EBC Model: Government Shock 0:06 3:90 0:97 0:54 0:95 0:998 EBC Model: Sunspot Shock 0:03 4:65 0:99 0:36 0:999 0:999 EBC Model: Consumption + Sunspot 0:57 4:02 0:97 0:56 0:95 0:998 EBC Model: Government + Sunspot 0:05 4:09 0:97 0:49 0:96 0: Comovements of Output, Hours, and Consumption Rotemberg and Woodford (1996) highlight another characteristic of economic uctuations that is di±cult for the real-business-cycle paradigm to explain. They show that, in US data, forecastable changes in output, hours, investment and consumption are positively correlated, whereas standard RBC models imply that hours and consumption move in opposite directions in approaching the steady state after the impact period of a permanent technology shock. They also show that the problem can be solved within the standard RBC framework if the preferences are such that the degree of intertemporal substitution and the elasticity of labor supply are both substantially reduced. These modi cations however signi cantly worsen the model's ability to explain the moments of the data along other dimensions. Speci cally, the volatility of hours becomes too low and that of consumption becomes too high in comparison with the data. Our model addresses the co-movement problem by mimicking short-run increasing returns to labor, which induce hours and consumption to move together 26 The data are detrended by the HP lter. 27 The AR(1) autocoe±cient is 0:9. 28 EBC stands for our endogenous business cycle model. 19

20 along the model's transition path towards the steady state. The whole issue can be illustrated using the labor market equilibrium condition given by u n (1 n) =u c w where the left-hand side is the marginal cost of labor supply measured in utility terms and the right-hand side is the marginal bene t of labor supply measured in utility terms. In a standard RBC model capital moves little in the short run. As hours go up, the real wage, w, goes down, so the right-hand side of the equation decreases. On the other hand, since leisure goes down, the marginal utility of leisure goes up. So the left-hand side increases. To balance the equation, consumption has to decrease in order to increase the marginal utility u c : RBC models solve the co-movement problem by introducing technology shocks that increase the real wage. However, as is noted by Rotemberg and Woodford, this solves the problem at the impact period, but at least with permanent shocks, negative comovements are likely during the periods of transition towards the steady state. In the reduced form of our model the real wage is an increasing function of hours due to the combination of variable capacity utilization and external e ects, and therefore the labor market equation above implies a positive co-movement between consumption and hours. 5. Conclusion In this paper we have demonstrated that an equilibrium real business cycle model incorporating variable capacity utilization, persistent demand shocks and indeterminacy is capable of explaining aggregate uctuations. In such a model demand shocks can generate not only positive comovements among consumption, investment, hours and output, but also the trend reverting hump-shaped time series exhibited by these macroeconomic variables. It should be possible to further enrich the model by combining it with equilibrium models that introduce a role for money. 20

21 References [1] D. Andolfatto, 1996, Business cycles and labor-market search, American Economic Review 86 (March), [2] S. Basu and J. Fernald, 1997, Returns to scale in US production: estimates and implications, Journal of Political Economy 105 (April), [3] M. Baxter and R. King, 1992, Productive externality and cyclical volatility. Working paper 245, University of Rochester. [4] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, Indeterminacy and increasing returns, Journal of Economic Theory 63 (1994), [5] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, 1996, Indeterminacy and sector-speci c externalities, Journal of Monetary Economics 37, [6] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, 1999, Indeterminacy and sunspots in macroeconomics, Handbook for Macroeconomics, eds. John Taylor and Michael Woodford, North-Holland, New York, volume 1A, [7] B. S. Bernanke, M. Gertler and S. Gilchrist, 1999, The nancial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework, in Handbook of Macroeconomics, eds. J. Taylor and M. Woodford, Elsevier, volume 1C, [8] O. Blanchard, 1993, Consumption and the recession of , American Economic Review 93 (May), [9] O. Blanchard and D. Quah, 1989, The dynamic e ects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances, American Economic Review 79, [10] C. Burnside and M. Eichenbaum, 1996, Factor hoarding and the propagation of business cycle shocks, American Economic Review 86 (December), [11] C. Burnside, M. Eichenbaum and S. Rebelo, 1993, Labor hoarding and the business cycle, Journal of Political Economy 101, [12] C. Carlstrom and T. Fuerst, 1997, Agency costs, net worth, and business uctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis, American Economic Review 87 (December),

22 [13] D. Cass and K. Shell, 1983, Do sunspots matter? Journal of Political Economy 91, [14] L. Christiano and M. Eichenbaum, 1992, Current real-business-cycle theories and aggregate labor-market uctuations, American Economic Review 82, [15] J. Cochrane, 1994, Shocks, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 41, [16] T. Cogley and J. Nason, 1995, Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models, American Economic Review 85, [17] C. Evans, 1992, Productivity shocks and real business cycles, Journal of Monetary Economics 29, [18] R. Farmer and J. T. Guo, 1994, Real business Cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis, Journal of Economic Theory 63, [19] R. Gordon, 1993, Are procyclical productivity uctuations a gment of measurement error? Manuscript, Northwestern University. [20] J. Greenwood, Z. Hercowitz and G. Hu man, 1988, Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle, American Economic Review 78, [21] G. Hansen, 1985, Indivisible labor and the business cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics 16, [22] King, R., C. Plosser and S. Rebelo, 1988, Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model, Journal of Monetary Economics 21, [23] G. Mankiw, 1989, Real business cycles: A new Keynesian perspective, Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, [24] R. Perli, 1998, Indeterminacy, home production, and the business cycle: A calibrated analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics

23 [25] J. Rotemberg and M. Woodford (1996), Real-business-cycle models and the forecastable movements in output, hours, and consumption, American Economic Review 86 (March), [26] S. Schmitt-Grohe, 1997, Comparing four models of aggregate uctuations due to self-ful lling expectations, Journal of Economic Theory 72, [27] S. Schmitt-Grohe, 2000, Endogenous business cycles and the dynamics of output, hours, and consumption, American Economic Review, forthcoming. [28] K. Shell, 1977, Monnaie et allocation intertemporelle, Mimeo, Seminaire d'econometrie Roy-Malinvaud, Centre National de la Recherche Scienti que, Paris. [29] L. Summers, 1986, Some skeptical observations on real business cycle theory, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Fall, [30] M. Watson, 1993, Measures of t for calibrated models, Journal of Political Economy 101, no.6, [31] Y. Wen, 1995, Where's the beef? The trivial dynamics of real business cycle models, Manuscript, The University of Iowa. [32] Y. Wen, 1998, Capacity utilization under increasing returns to scale, Journal of Economic Theory 81,

24 Fig. 1. Responses to Demand Shocks (US 1960:1-1994:4) 24

25 Fig. 2. Autocorrelation Function of Growth Rates (US 1960:1-1994:4) 25

26 Fig. 3. Predictions of a Standard RBC model (Solic Symbols). First row: Impulse responses to demand shocks. Second row: ACF of growth rates. 26

27 Fig. 4. Impulse Responses ( = 0:1). Solid lines: responses to a consumption shock. Dashed lines: responses to a government shock. 27

28 Fig. 5. Impulse Responses ( = 0:108). Solid lines: responses to consumption shock. Long dashed lines: responses to government shock. Short dashed lines: responses to sunspots. 28

29 Fig. 6. Impulse Responses of Output when the covariances between sunspots and fundamental shocks take di erent values. 29

30 Fig. 7. Predictions of Model (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 30

31 Fig. 8. Predictions of Model A (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 31

32 Fig. 9. Predictions of Model B (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 32

33 Fig. 10. Impulse responses of model (solid lines) and data (dashed lines). 33

Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle

Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle Jess Benhabib Department of Economics New York University jess.benhabib@nyu.edu Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Yw57@cornell.edu

More information

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University, Ithaca, N.Y. yw57@cornell.edu Abstract Consumption in the US leads output at the business cycle frequency.

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Real Business Cycle Models Lecture 2 Nicola Viegi April 2015 Basic RBC Model Claim: Stochastic General Equlibrium Model Is Enough to Explain The Business cycle Behaviour of the Economy Money is of little

More information

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370 February 2006 Real Business Cycles Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota Abstract:

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Real Business Cycle Theory Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Introduction to DSGE models Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models have become the main tool for

More information

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles: Chapter 5 Real business cycles 5.1 Real business cycles The most well known paper in the Real Business Cycles (RBC) literature is Kydland and Prescott (1982). That paper introduces both a specific theory

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle Theory Guido Ascari University of Pavia () Real Business Cycle Theory 1 / 50 Outline Introduction: Lucas methodological proposal The application to the analysis of business cycle uctuations:

More information

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Yulei Luo SEF of HKU October 1, 2015 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory October 1, 2015 1 / 45 Lag Operators The lag operator (L) is de ned as Similar

More information

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 13 2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Introduction Simplistic RBC Model Simple stochastic growth model Baseline RBC model Introduction

More information

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Robert J. Rossana Department of Economics, 04 F/AB, Wayne State University, Detroit MI 480 E-Mail: r.j.rossana@wayne.edu

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomics I Introduction to Real Business Cycle Theory

Dynamic Macroeconomics I Introduction to Real Business Cycle Theory Dynamic Macroeconomics I Introduction to Real Business Cycle Theory Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia these slides are based on my Course of Advanced Macroeconomics II held at UPF and bene t of the work

More information

Estimating baseline real business cycle models of the Australian economy

Estimating baseline real business cycle models of the Australian economy Estimating baseline real business cycle models of the Australian economy Don Harding and Siwage Negara y University of Melbourne February 26, 2008 1 Introduction This paper is concerned with the issues

More information

Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets

Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets CENTRAL BANK OF THE REPUBLIC OF TURKEY WORKING PAPER NO: 0/08 Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets May 200 S. Tolga TİRYAKİ Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey 200 Address: Central

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

Reexamination of Real Business Cycles in A Small Open Economy

Reexamination of Real Business Cycles in A Small Open Economy Reexamination of Real Business Cycles in A Small Open Economy Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside y Zuzana Janko z University of Calgary January 29, 2008 Abstract Standard dynamic small open

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Exam: ECON4310 Intertemporal macroeconomics Date of exam: Thursday, November 27, 2008 Grades are given: December 19, 2008 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Understanding the Large Negative Impact of Oil Shocks Luís Aguiar-Conraria and Yi Wen Working Paper 2005-042B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2005/2005-042.pdf

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics (2)

Advanced Macroeconomics (2) Advanced Macroeconomics (2) Real-Business-Cycle Theory Alessio Moneta Institute of Economics Scuola Superiore Sant Anna, Pisa amoneta@sssup.it March-April 2015 LM in Economics Scuola Superiore Sant Anna

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2015 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle Theory Barbara Annicchiarico Università degli Studi di Roma "Tor Vergata" April 202 General Features I Theory of uctuations (persistence, output does not show a strong tendency to return

More information

E ects of oil price shocks on German business cycles

E ects of oil price shocks on German business cycles E ects of oil price shocks on German business cycles Torsten Schmidt and Tobias Zimmermann y Abstract In this paper we analyse to what extent movements in oil prices can help to explain business cycle

More information

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory By Student E XXXXXXX Abstract: The following paper reviews five articles concerning Real Business Cycle theory. First, the review compares the various

More information

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS Jakub Gazda 42 Jakub Gazda, Real Business Cycle Theory Methodology and Tools, Economics & Sociology, Vol. 3, No 1, 2010, pp. 42-48. Jakub Gazda Department of Microeconomics Poznan University of Economics

More information

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land). Chapter 3 Credit and Business Cycles Here I present a model of the interaction between credit and business cycles. In representative agent models, remember, no lending takes place! The literature on the

More information

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP?

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Raffaella Basile, Ministry of Economy and Finance, Dept. of Treasury Bruno Chiarini, University of Naples Parthenope,

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Phd Macro, 2007 (Karl Whelan) 1 Real Business Cycle Models The Real Business Cycle (RBC) model introduced in a famous 1982 paper by Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott is the original DSGE model. 1 The early

More information

In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model

In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model George T. McCandless March 3, 006 Abstract This paper studies the nature of monetary policy with nancial intermediaries that

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

On the Cyclicality of Credit

On the Cyclicality of Credit On the Cyclicality of Credit Ufuk Devrim Demirel y University of Colorado at Boulder Abstract This study documents the cyclical properties of business credit in the U.S. and in the Euro area and constructs

More information

Credit Decomposition and Business Cycles in Emerging Market Economies

Credit Decomposition and Business Cycles in Emerging Market Economies Credit Decomposition and Business Cycles in Emerging Market Economies Berrak Bahadir y University of Georgia Inci Gumus z Sabanci University July 24, 214 Abstract This paper analyzes di erent types of

More information

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Stefano Eusepi, Marc Giannoni and Bruce Preston The views expressed are those of the authors and are not necessarily re

More information

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle Chapter 11 Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle Goal of This Chapter In this chapter, we study three models of business cycle, which were each developed as explicit equilibrium (market-clearing)

More information

Real-Business-Cycle Models and the Forecastable Movements in Output, Hours, and Consumption

Real-Business-Cycle Models and the Forecastable Movements in Output, Hours, and Consumption Real-Business-Cycle Models and the Forecastable Movements in Output, Hours, and Consumption Julio J. Rotemberg; Michael Woodford The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 1. (Mar., 1996), pp. 71-89. http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199603%2986%3a1%3c71%3armatfm%3e2.0.co%3b2-y

More information

Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics. 1. Unemployment and Vacancies over the Business Cycle

Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics. 1. Unemployment and Vacancies over the Business Cycle 14.461: Advanced Macroeconomics I Suman S. Basu, MIT Recitation 9: Empirical Evidence on Labor Market Dynamics Part II of 14.461 covers topics in the macroeconomic analysis of labor markets. The purpose

More information

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Optimality Conditions Euler equation under uncertainty: u C (C t, 1 N t) = βe t [u C (C t+1, 1 N t+1)

More information

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions Franck Portier TSE Macro II 29-21 Chapter 3 Real Business Cycles 36 3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model Perfectly competitive economy Optimal growth model + Labor decisions 2 types of agents

More information

The Real Business Cycle model

The Real Business Cycle model The Real Business Cycle model Spring 2013 1 Historical introduction Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynesian

More information

Total Factor Productivity

Total Factor Productivity Total Factor Productivity Diego Comin NewYorkUniversityandNBER August 2006 Abstract Total Factor Productivity (TFP) is the portion of output not explained by the amount of inputs used in production. The

More information

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Karl Walentin Sveriges Riksbank 1. Background This paper is part of the large literature that takes as its starting point the

More information

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it. Douglas Hibbs L, L3: AAU Macro Theory 0-0-9/4 Optimal Investment Why Care About Investment? Investment drives capital formation, and the stock of capital is a key determinant of output and consequently

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 1 Introduction Having developed an operational model of the economy, we want to ask ourselves the

More information

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction Kevin E. Beaubrun-Diant and Fabien Tripier y June 8, 00 Abstract We herein advance a contribution to the theoretical literature on nancial frictions and show

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES

DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES EMI NAKAMURA* The empirical success of Real Business Cycle (RBC) models is often judged by their ability to explain the behavior of a multitude of real

More information

The Real Business Cycle School

The Real Business Cycle School Major Currents in Contemporary Economics The Real Business Cycle School Mariusz Próchniak Department of Economics II Warsaw School of Economics 1 Background During 1972-82,the dominant new classical theory

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model for Lesotho

The Real Business Cycle Model for Lesotho The Real Business Cycle Model for Lesotho Tanka Tlelima University of Cape Town, South Africa October 27, 29 Abstract This paper modi es Hansen s model of indivisible labour, to include labour exports,

More information

Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning

Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning John Duffy Department of Economics University of Pittsburgh 230 S. Bouquet Street Pittsburgh, PA 15260 USA E mail:

More information

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models 1 Contents: Lehrstuhl für Department Empirische of Wirtschaftsforschung Empirical Research and und Econometrics Ökonometrie IV.1 Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR)...

More information

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models Lecture 9: Keynesian Models Professor Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2009 Sims (Notre Dame) Keynesian Fall 2009 1 / 23 Keynesian Models The de ning features of RBC models are: Markets clear Money

More information

CDMA07/04 Investment Frictions and the Relative Price of Investment Goods in an Open Economy Model * OCTOBER 2008

CDMA07/04 Investment Frictions and the Relative Price of Investment Goods in an Open Economy Model * OCTOBER 2008 CENTRE FOR DYNAMIC MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS WORKING PAPER SERIES CDMA07/04 Investment Frictions and the Relative Price of Investment Goods in an Open Economy Model * Parantap Basu University of Durham OCTOBER

More information

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 1 Consumption with many periods 1.1 Finite horizon of T Optimization problem maximize U t = u (c t ) + β (c t+1 ) + β 2 u (c t+2 ) +...

More information

A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models

A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol. 18, No. 4, Fall 1994 A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models Ellen R. McGrattan* Economist Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Employment Protection and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies

Employment Protection and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies Employment Protection and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies Ruy Lama IMF Carlos Urrutia ITAM August, 2011 Lama and Urrutia () Employment Protection August, 2011 1 / 38 Motivation Business cycles in

More information

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53 What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 *University of Modena and Reggio Emilia RECent (Center for Economic Research) Address:

More information

Business Cycle Models - A Review of the Published Works Paper, Part 1

Business Cycle Models - A Review of the Published Works Paper, Part 1 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES 2008-02 McMASTER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Kenneth Taylor Hall 426 1280 Main Street West Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4M4 http://www.mcmaster.ca/economics/

More information

The Global Impact of Chinese Growth

The Global Impact of Chinese Growth The Global Impact of Chinese Growth by Ippei Fujiwara, Keisuke Otsu, and Masashi Saito 2008 International Conference: Frontiers in Monetary Theory and Policy Discussion by Selo Imrohoro¼glu USC Marshall

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Deficits, Public Debt Dynamics, and Tax and Spending Multipliers

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Deficits, Public Debt Dynamics, and Tax and Spending Multipliers Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Deficits, Public Debt Dynamics, and Tax and Spending Multipliers Matthew Denes Gauti B. Eggertsson Sophia Gilbukh Staff Report No. 551 February 2012 Revised

More information

Asset Prices in a News Driven Real Business Cycle Model

Asset Prices in a News Driven Real Business Cycle Model Asset Prices in a News Driven Real Business Cycle Model Aytek Malkhozov y Maral Shamloo z March 200 Abstract We examine the implications of introducing anticipated productivity shocks for the ability of

More information

Has Monetary Policy Become Less Powerful?

Has Monetary Policy Become Less Powerful? Has Monetary Policy Become Less Powerful? Jean Boivin y Columbia University Marc Giannoni z Federal Reserve Bank First Draft: March 2001 This Version: January 2002 of New York JEL Classi cation: E52, E3,

More information

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1 Homework #1 1. In 1900 GDP per capita in Japan (measured in 2000 dollars) was $1,433. In 2000 it was $26,375. (a) Calculate the growth rate of income per capita in Japan over this century. (b) Now suppose

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Australia: an SVAR Model

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Australia: an SVAR Model Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Australia: an SVAR Model Mardi Dungey and Renée Fry University of Tasmania, CFAP University of Cambridge, CAMA Australian National University September 21 ungey and Fry (University

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints WORING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 448 Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond and Måns Söderbom May 2010 ISSN 1403-2473 (print) ISSN 1403-2465 (online) Department

More information

Real Business Cycle Models: Past, Present and Future

Real Business Cycle Models: Past, Present and Future Scand. J. of Economics 107(2), 217 238, 2005 DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9442.2005.00405.x Real Business Cycle Models: Past, Present and Future Sergio Rebelo* Northwestern University, Evanston, IL 60208-2001,

More information

Bank Loan Portfolios and the Canadian Monetary Transmission Mechanism

Bank Loan Portfolios and the Canadian Monetary Transmission Mechanism Bank Loan Portfolios and the Canadian Monetary Transmission Mechanism Wouter J. DEN HAAN, y Steven W. SUMNER, z Guy M. YAMASHIRO x May 29, 2008 Abstract Following a monetary tightening, bank loans to consumers

More information

Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited

Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited by Neville Francis Lehigh University and Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and

More information

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler *

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * In recent decades, asset booms and busts have been important factors in macroeconomic fluctuations in both

More information

Macroeconomic (In)stability under Real Interest Rate Targeting

Macroeconomic (In)stability under Real Interest Rate Targeting Macroeconomic (In)stability under Real Interest Rate Targeting Chi-Ting Chin y Academia Sinica Jang-Ting Guo z University of California, Riverside Ching-Chong Lai x Academia Sinica August 22, 2007 Abstract

More information

Discussion of Faia "Optimal Monetary Policy with Credit Augmented Liquidity Cycles"

Discussion of Faia Optimal Monetary Policy with Credit Augmented Liquidity Cycles Discussion of Faia "Optimal Monetary Policy with Credit Augmented Liquidity Cycles" Ander Perez (U Pompeu Fabra) November 2008 Ander Perez (U Pompeu Fabra) () Discussion: Faia November 2008 1 / 11 (Related)

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Chapter 4 Real Business Cycle Theory This section of the textbook focuses on explaining the behavior of the business cycle. The terms business cycle, short-run macroeconomics, and economic fluctuations

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 1 Introduction This note describes the canonical real business cycle model. A couple of classic references

More information

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. International Finance Discussion Papers. Number 990. January 2010

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. International Finance Discussion Papers. Number 990. January 2010 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers Number 99 January 21 Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities, and the Business Cycle David E. Altig Lawrence J.

More information

THE 1970S saw a distinctive shift in

THE 1970S saw a distinctive shift in Journal of Economics Literatute Vol. XXXII (December 1994), pp. 1750 1783 Real Business Cycles Stadler: Real Business Cycles By GEORGE W. STADLER University of Newcastle upon Tyne I have received numerous

More information

Credit Constraints and Self-Fulfulling Business Cycles

Credit Constraints and Self-Fulfulling Business Cycles FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Credit Constraints and Self-Fulfulling Business Cycles Zheng Liu Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Pengfei Wang Hong Kong University of Science

More information

Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality?

Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality? Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality? Johannes Ludwig Ruhr Graduate School in Economics & Ruhr-Universität Bochum Abstract Contrary to the implications of

More information

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development Edgar A. Ghossoub University of Texas at San Antonio Robert R. Reed University of Alabama July, 20 Abstract In this paper, we examine the impact

More information

Economic Growth. Chapter 11

Economic Growth. Chapter 11 Chapter 11 Economic Growth This chapter examines the determinants of economic growth. A startling fact about economic growth is the large variation in the growth experience of different countries in recent

More information

Factor demand linkages and the business cycle: interpreting aggregate fluctuations as sectoral fluctuations

Factor demand linkages and the business cycle: interpreting aggregate fluctuations as sectoral fluctuations CENTRE FOR DYNAMIC MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS CONFERENCE PAPERS 28 CDMC8/9 Factor demand linkages and the business cycle: interpreting aggregate fluctuations as sectoral fluctuations Sean Holly * JULY 3, 28

More information

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 18 August 2009 Lecture plan and web pages for this course The lecture plan is at http://folk.uio.no/rnymoen/econ3410_h08_index.html,

More information

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION Emanuel R. Leão Pedro R. Leão Junho 2008 WP nº 2008/63 DOCUMENTO DE TRABALHO WORKING PAPER General Equilibrium with Banks and the Factor-Intensity

More information

Factor Demand Linkages, Technology Shocks and the Business Cycle

Factor Demand Linkages, Technology Shocks and the Business Cycle Factor Demand Linkages, Technology Shocks and the Business Cycle Sean Holly y University of Cambridge and CIMF Ivan Petrella z Catholic University of Leuven and CIMF Cambridge October 5, 21 Abstract This

More information

Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications

Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications Seminar Presentation Country of interest France Jan Krzyzanowski June 9, 2012 Table of Contents Business Cycle Analysis Data Quantitative Analysis Stochastic

More information

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS Gustavo A. Marrero Alfonso Novales y July 13, 2011 ABSTRACT: In a Barro-type economy with exogenous consumption aspirations, raising income taxes favors

More information

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY)

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY) The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY) Comments by: Brent Neiman University of Chicago Prepared for: Brookings

More information

Investment and Financial Constraints: Empirical Evidence for Firms in Brazil and China

Investment and Financial Constraints: Empirical Evidence for Firms in Brazil and China Investment and Financial Constraints: Empirical Evidence for Firms in Brazil and China Stephen R. Bond Nu eld College and Department of Economics, University of Oxford and Institute for Fiscal Studies

More information

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need Economic Quarterly Volume 100, Number 1 First Quarter 2014 Pages 51 85 A Business Cycle Analysis of Debt and Equity Financing Marios Karabarbounis, Patrick Macnamara, and Roisin McCord The recent turmoil

More information

Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning

Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning John Duffy Department of Economics University of Pittsburgh 230 S. Bouquet Street Pittsburgh, PA 15260 USA E mail:

More information

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Daniele Coen-Pirani Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890, USA Abstract This paper studies

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION March 1, 2005 JCX-4-05 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? Greg Kaplan New York University gregkaplan@nyu.edu Giovanni L. Violante New York University, CEPR, and NBER glv2@nyu.edu This Draft: February 2008 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE

More information

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics Topics Volume 1, Issue 1 21 Article 25 Financial Market Shocks during the Great Depression Alycia Chin Missaka Warusawitharana Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

More information

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Dennis Leech Economics Department and Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy University of Warwick d.leech@warwick.ac.uk Published

More information

A Critique of Structural VARs Using Business Cycle Theory

A Critique of Structural VARs Using Business Cycle Theory Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Critique of Structural VARs Using Business Cycle Theory V. V. Chari, Patrick J. Kehoe, Ellen R. McGrattan Working Paper 631 Revised May 2005 ABSTRACT

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Economics Letters 82 (2004) 167 172 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Ashoka Mody a,1, Mark P. Taylor b,c, * a Research Department,

More information

During the Great Recession, the unemployment rate increased

During the Great Recession, the unemployment rate increased Economic Quarterly Volume 99, Number 1 First Quarter 2013 Pages 1 23 Why Labor Force Participation (Usually) Increases when Unemployment Declines Andreas Hornstein During the Great Recession, the unemployment

More information

Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle

Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle Tsu-ting Tim Lin Gettysburg College July, 3 Abstract Shimer (5) argues that a search-and-matching model of the labor market in which wage

More information

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L)

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L) A CLOSED ECONOMY IN THE LONG (MEDIUM) RUN For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = C(Y T ) + I(r) + G the left hand side of the equation is the total supply of goods and services

More information