Evolution of environmental concern and the dynamics of pollution

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Evolution of environmental concern and the dynamics of pollution"

Transcription

1 Evolution of environmental concern and the dynamics of pollution Emeline Bezin March 26, 2012 Abstract Although the evolution of environmental concern has exhibited a very similar pattern in industrialized and developing nations so that it has been widely demonstrated to be now as spread in both kind of countries, many pollutions have steadily increased within the former group while it was stabilizing in the latter one. To explain those facts, we develop a dynamic model within which the evolution of pollution and the formation of environmental concern are both endogenous. We first set up an overlapping generation model based on John and Pecchenino s [1994] in which environmental concern, view as a perception of pollution, can vary within the population but is still fixed in time. We find that it is not always better for the long run environment to have a lot of environmentally concerned people and that this depends upon the available technology for the pollution production process. The technological factor matters because it determines the ease of reducing pollution in terms of its opportunity cost in consumption units. Hence, we show that a sufficient number of people who care about environment is needed in order to reach a stationary state as long as the available technology is clean. However if the technology is quite polluting a steady state will exist only if the share of environmentally concerned people is low enough. In a second step, we consider the composition of the population to be endogenous while environmental concern is transmitted through a socialization process based on Bisin and Verdier [1998, 2000] in which we further assume that pollution interacts. We show that as long as pollution and the culture sphere interact in a non negligible way, a stationary state characterized by a low (but nonzero) share of environmentally concerned people does not exist anymore. The existence of a stable steady state requires a clean technology for pollution production. This steady state is always characterized by an heterogeneous composition of the population where the fraction of people concerned by the environment is relatively high. Our model points out that it is not sufficient to be environmentally concerned to achieve pollution stabilization and that a clean technology for the pollution production process is also required. Furthermore when the share of environmentally concerned agents is endogenously determined, while having both previous conditions is still sufficient, it now turns to be also necessary. Actually with a polluting technology, individuals who are concerned with pollution cannot do anything but increase their consumption so that a rise of their number makes the environment more favorable to the transmission of their own trait. It supports the empirical evidences on the two different trends which have linked the environmental concern and the evolution of pollution. keywords: Overlapping generations, pollution, environmental concern, cultural transmission. JEL Classification: Q50, D90, J11. I am grateful to Frédéric Chantreuil and Dominique Vermersch for their advices. I would also like to thank David de la Croix and Thomas Baudin as well as François Portier for very helpful comments. UMR 1302 Smart, INRA, 4 allée Bobierre-CS Rennes cedex, France. Tél. (33) emeline.bezin@inra.rennes.fr 1

2 1 Introduction Many authors have recently increase their interest toward the spread of environmental concern, a phenomenon which has begun in the early 1970 s and has never stop to intensify. An important issue is to understand the link with pollution especially because the way in which it can be involved in solving environmental problems has huge potential policy implications (mostly in terms of education). The conventional wisdom suggests that, inducing the change of agents destructive behaviour, the spread of environmental concern would consistently lead to the reduction of environmental degradations. Nevertheless some facts reveal that this relashionship does not seem so obvious. Within the developping world various kinds of pollution have risen so that many have supported the hypothesis that it was due to a lack of environmentally concerned individuals in those nations. The extansive environmental Kuznets Curve s litterature has particularly pointed in that direction and among others, McConnel [1997] for instance, explains the difference between industrialized and developping nations by a difference in environmental concern. Actually, he assumes that as income rises people are more and more concerned about the environment and this in turn lead to less environmental degradations. However number of studies which have used various measures of environmental concern have shown that the development of environemental values has not been not confined to industrialized nations but that it has been rather a worlwide phenomenon (Dunlap, Gallup and Gallup [1992], Brechin and Kempton [1994], Dunlap and Mertig [1995], Brechin [1999], Dunlap and York [2008]). In addition, simple observation of data reveals there has been two different trends linking environmental concern and the evolution of pollution. On the one hand, for a wide part of industrialized countries, the spread of environmental concern has resulted into stabilization of many kinds of pollution. On the other hand, while the same spread has occured in developping nations, most pollutions have risen. For instance, air pollutants (like PM10 and nitrogen dioxide) have exhibited upward pattern in Asia and Latin America during the last decades. As a consequence, several cities of those parts of the word range now from the highest concentration levels. Meanwhile, the same air pollutants has decreased and stabilized in Europe as well in North America (World Health Organization [2005], Baldasano and al. [2003]). In spite of those different worlwide patterns for the evolution of pollution, no statistical differences have been found between rich and poor counties, for environmental concern in general, by the studies mentionned above. It is neither the case for specific environmental issues. Precisely, concerning air pollution, 77% of mexican inhabitants and 64% of Indian were reported to be highly concerned, which is comparable with what have been reported in USA or Germany where the share is around 60 % (Kempton and Brechin [1994]). Linking those facts with what has been put forward by the EKC litterature leads us to two major observations. The first one questionned the relashonship between income and environmental concern. Indeed contrary to the EKC hypothesis, the spread of environmental concern has occured in both rich and poor nations. Hence if the incomes rise is not the engine of that change what may be at work in the evolution of environmental attitutes? Secondly, it challenges the conventional link between the evolution of environmental concern and the dynamics of pollution. What can explain that the rise of environmental concern has resulted into pollution stabilization for the industrialized world while it has been associated with an increase of many kinds of pollution in developping countries. First of all, the fact that income is not decisive for environmental concern suggests that it can not be understood in terms of monetary value. This is further emphazised by Kempton and 2

3 Brechin [1994] who argue that surveys measuring environmental values via willingness to pay cash question, already reflect a strong bias toward economic measures of worth. The conclusion that the poor lack environmental concern is generated by the measurement instrument.. On the other hand, many authors seem to agree that perception is a good measure of the degree of concern so that it has almost always been used in the extensive related litterature. In this article, therefore, we operationalize environmental concern as a perception. More precisely, we consider agents which are not able to correctly assess the actual stock of pollution because as justified in Schumacher and Zou [2008] they are naturally more able to perceive environmental stimulus than absolute levels. This is also emphazied by many authors in environmental psychology who make use of the comparison with a frog which immediately jumps out if suddenly plunged into hot water while it would never realize the danger if water would be heated gradually to the same temperature. Thereby, in our setting agents are not affected by the level of pollution but by the variation of the level of pollution. They consider the level within which they have lived as a benchmark, against which the new level is assessed. Variations in concern for the environment are captured by the relative importance of this benchmark which stands for the amount of pollution considered as neutral. Hence, we consider two types of agents which differ in the following manner: 1. People concerned about pollution are convinced of an harmful human impact on its natural environment so that the preceeding level of pollution is thought to be already high. Consequently for those agents, the reference level is relatively close to zero so that the new level of pollution is perceived as high, and they are strongly affected by it. 2. The other type of agents strongly trust in science and innovation. They think there is no limits to growth because technological progress is able to solve environmental problems. Hence in their point of view, the preceeding level could not be harmful and their reference level is high. However they cannot denie observed changes in their natural environment and are still affected by pollution when it increases compared to the benchmark. With this formalization, environmental concern relies mostly on individual beliefs and values. This is just confirmed by an exhaustive litterature which have tried to explain variations of the concern for environmental issues (among others see Van Liere and Dunlap [1980] for a wide review). In many studies demographic variables have been shown to be slightly relevant to assess the degree of concern while cognitive ones have been demonstrated to explain a large share of observed variations. As a consequence, it is likely that, as for other belief-based characteristics, a cultural transmission process is at work and drives the evolution. Hence rather than income rise, we think that social interactions are the driving force in the spread of environmental concern and we use the cultural transmission framework developed by Bisin and Verdier [1998, 2000] to describe this process. Furthermore, it is clear for many authors that rising pollution has also been a driving force in the spread of environmental concern (Inglehart [1995], Brechin [1999]). However the role played by objective environmental conditions still remains a puzzling question. As pointed out by Dunlap and Merting [1997] a simple stimulus-response model of the role of objective environmental problems is much too simplistic [...] and ignores the documented complexities of environmental perception.. Hence pollution must interact in the socialization process who drives the evolution of environmental perceptions but it could occur at different stages of the transmission mechanism. We think it is realistic to assume it interacts with parental point of view (through the desire to transmit its own attitude toward environment). This is not crucial for the consistency of our results since the same conclusion can be obtained assuming pollution interacts with children s point of view. 3

4 We use an overlapping generation framework with a pollution externality based on John and Pecchenino [1994]. Pollution, arising in a accumulative way, is increased by consumption while it can be reduced by abatement spendings. The two types of agents can either use their wage for saving in order to consume latter or for the abatement of pollution through a voluntary contribution. Since we specify environmental concern as a perception, those who are concerned about pollution are actually those significantly affected by the rise of the pollution stock. This is fundamental in a dynamic framework because the direction of the changes of the decision variables, and not their absolute level, determines the evolution of the state variables and so rules out the short run and the long run behaviour of the economy. In fact, when the pollution bequeathed by preceeding generations rises, agents with environmental concern, who heavily suffer from this rise, need to undertake largest actions to offset the rising cost of past actions. To do so they can either decrease pollution or increase consumption. However, pollution is a public good so that they cannot act directly on its level. Hence is the key feature: if they must respond more to a rise of the bequeathed pollution, it does not imply that they always act for the reduction of pollution because depollution can be constrained. It is in line with a widely developed litterature capturing the existence of barriers to pro-environmental behaviour (Kollmuss and Agyeman [2002], Stern [2000]). Within this field, authors have put forward that attitudes as perception of harmful impacts of pollution do not always lead to pro-environmental behaviour and have pointed out, among others, the role played by what they called external factors. Within those factors, they mentionned the institutions as well as the technology. In our setting, such a binding technological factor is precisely at stake to link up a perception with a type of behaviour. Actually, pollution is produced according to a given process which can be more or less binding for either type of agents depending on the relative values of the efficiency of abatement and of the consumption externality. The technology interacts with environmental attitudes to determine the ease of reducing pollution in terms of its opportunity cost in consumption units (along the transistion path if not a barrier, it determines the strengh of individual actions so that it is crucially implied in stability). Thus we show that, when the production process of pollution is clean (that is the efficiency of abatement is large enough compared to the consumption externality), a large number of environmentally concerned agents is also necessary to the stabilization or to the sustainability when it is basically defined as reaching a stationary state. In fact, within this technological context, any rise in pollution stock incit them to increase abatement contrary to their contemporaneous who prefer to rise saving to consume more. Nevertheless, when the available technology is highly polluting, a sustainable stationary state will never be reached if the share of agents concerned is large enough because of the difficulty of reducing pollution in terms of its opportunity cost in consumption units. Indeed, they cannot act efficiently against a rise in pollution while they are strongly affected, so that they must consume more to compensate. Hence, we show that within this kind of pollution technology, a stationary state can be reached only if the share of agents concerned with pollution is low enough. If the former case can be compared with the trend, which have occured in industrialized countries, the latter one does not correspond to any observed situations. This is because the distribution of environmental concern is also a dynamical variable so that considering its evolution is essential to be able to have the whole story. Thereby, in a second time, we consider the fraction of environnementally concerned people is endogeneous. We show that if the environmental concern evolves through cultural transmission and if pollution has a non negligible impact in the socialization process, then a stable stationary state exists only when technology is clean and it is characterized by 4

5 a high share of agents concerned with the environment. When technology is polluting, however, while the share of people concerned about pollution is rising up, stabilization never occurs. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section one presents and solves the model where two types of agents coexist but when the share of environmentally concerned people is fixed. In section two we endogenize the distribution of environmental concern through a cultural transmission model where pollution interacts. Section three concludes. 2 The model Let consider a perfectly competitive economy with an overlapping generation structure. Time is discrete and goes from 1 to. At each date a generation is born and lives for two periods. During the first period agents supply their labor inelastically and earn a wage which can be either saved for future consumption or spend in the abatement of pollution. Following John and Pecchenino [1994] we assume agents have preferences over consumption and the environment and can only derive utility during the second period of life (which stands for a period of retirement). Each cohort, of constant size n, consists of two types of agents who differ through their appraisal of the pollution stock. As highlighted in the introduction, agents of the first type have high perception of the pollution stock because their frame of reference is quite low. They are called environmentally concerned agents and they will be associated with the superscript G. On the other hand, the second type of agents with a relatively high frame of reference estimates pollution stock is lower than it actually is. They will be denoted by T for technologists. There are n G agents of type G and n T = n n G agents of type T. 2.1 Pollution accumulation The pollution accumulation process is described by the following equation based on John and Pecchenino [1994]: P t+1 = (1 b)p t + βn G c G t + βn T c T t γn G A G t γn T A T t, (1) where b [0, 1] is the natural rate of absorption, β > 0, is the amount of pollution per unit of consumption by agents of the old generation. Hence it stands for the intergenerational externality. On the other hand, γ > 0 is the effectivness of abatement. c i and A i, i {G, T } are respectively the type-i agents consumption of the generation born at t 1, and the type-i agents abatement of the generation born at t. 2.2 Agents behaviour Perception of pollution The formalisation of the pollution perception comes from Schumacher and Zou [2008]. In a model where agents live for two periods, the amount of pollution, an agent is affected by is H t+1 = P t+1 h i P t, where P t (resp. P t+1 ) is the pollution stock at time t (resp. t + 1). Individuals perceive a level between the stock and the flow from t to t + 1. h i [0, 1] is an individual specific parameter. For 5

6 a high h i, agent i almost considers as a benchmark the level where he has lived so far (P t is almost the neutral level). On the contrary agents who care a lot about about environmental problems consider the level where they have lived as already high (their frame of reference is thus closer to zero). The lower h i, the better the perception. Finally we assume h G < h T Economic choices During the first period agents have to choose the mix of abatement-saving which maximises their utility when old. We assume that, for all types of agent, U : R 2 ++ R, is twice continously differentiable and such that U c > 0, U cc < 0, U H < 0, U HH < 0 and lim c 0 U c =. An agent of type i, i {G, T } faces the following budget constraints : w t = s i t + A i t, (2) c i t+1 = (1 + r t+1 ) s i t, (3) where w t is the agent s wage (whatever his type) at time t, s i t is the amount of saving of a type-i individual and A i t, his abatement expenditure. r t is the interest rate at time t. An agent of type i maxmizes his utility subject to the budget constraints (??) and (??), as well as to P t+1 = (1 b)p t + βn G c G t + βn T c T t γa i t γāt where Āt is abatement spendings of all other economic agents. It leads to the following FOC (1 + r t+1 )U i c + γu i H = 0, i {G, T }. (4) Following Zhang [1999] and Schumacher and Zou [2008], for analytical convenience we restrict to simple class of utility functions so that we assume a constant elasticity of substitution between private consumption and the environment. σ = U i H Hi U i cc i > 0, i {G, T }. (5) Note that σ does not change from one type of agent to another. As highlighted in the introduction, agents do not differ through their relative valuation of the environment but only through their perception of the pollution. Using (??), let rewrite the FOC as γσs i t = P t+1 h i P t, i {G, T } (6) At the optimum, agents choose their saving such that positive level of pollution is associated with positive amount of saving. Since h G < h T, for a given stock of pollution in t + 1 type-g agents always choose to save more than type-t agents do. This is because for a given stock of pollution, type-g agents feel a higher desutility, so that all else equals, they have to consume more to offset the loss. However note that those agents are more sensitive to the intergenerational externality, 6

7 that is to a rise in the bequeathed stock of pollution P t. Hence, if pollution at time t increases, they always need to undertake largest actions. In other words, if they choose to increase abatement, they will increase it more than do type-t agents. Nevertheless, if they decide to increase saving on the other hand, they will rise it more. Later we point out the specific circumstances which determinate such a choice. 2.3 The representative firm The productive sector consists in a representative firm which is supposed to be perfectly competitive and which produces using the constant returns to scale production function Y = f (K) L. We can normalize by the labor supply so that output per worker can be written as y = f (k), where k = K/n. We assume that f meets the following properties : f > 0 and f < 0. The firm maximizes its profit equalizing each marginal productivity with its market price. Namely the marginal productivity of labour is equalized to the wage rate, whereas the marginal productivity of capital minus its depreciation rate is equalized to the interest rate. Finally total savings of the young generation form the capital at time t+1, w t = f(k t) n r t+1 = f (k t+1 ) n k t n f (k t ), (7) δ, (8) n G n sg t + (1 n G n )st t = k t+1. (9) For analytical convenience we restrict to a Cobb Douglas production function f(k t ) = kt v (Zhang [1999], Schumacher and Zou [2008]) where v [0, 1] is the capital share. We further assume full depreciation of captital, that is δ = 1. In what follows, let denote by q = n G n, the share of type-g agents. 2.4 Existence of steady state Definition 1 (Intertemporal equilibrium). Given inital conditions (k 0, P 0 ), the intertemporal equilibrium is the sequence (k t, P t ) t N which satisfies the two following equations for each t. P t+1 = (bσ + h(q) σ) P t (n σ) k t+1 = where h(q) = qh G + (1 q)h T and σ n. (1 b h(q)) P t γ(n σ) (βv + γv γ)σ kt v, (10) (n σ) (βv + γv γ) kt v, (11) γ(n σ) 7

8 2.4.1 Steady states A steady state exists if some vector (k,p) solves k t+1 = k t, P t+1 = P t for all t. There are two steady states : (0,0) and a non-trivial one, which crucially depends on q, so that it will be denoted by ( P (q), k(q)) : P (q) = σγ 1 h(q) ( (1 h(q))(βv + γv γ) γ(bσ + h(q) 1) ) 1 1 v (12) Assumption 1. Preferences ( ) 1 (1 h(q))(βv + γv γ) 1 v k(q) = γ(bσ + h(q). (13) 1) (1) We assume that 1 hg b > σ, i.e. for type-g agents the cost of an additionnal unit of pollution is higher than the gain of one more unit of consumption. (2) Conversely, we assume that 1 ht b < σ, i.e. for type-t agents the cost of an additionnal unit of pollution is lower than the gain of one more unit of consumption. Since a non-trivial steady state exists if bσ + h(q) 1 and βv + γv γ have the same sign, the following proposition can be deduced. Proposition 1. Existence of a non-trivial steady state (1) If the share of agents concerned about pollution is relatively high (q > q with q = bσ+ht 1 h T h G < 1), a non-trivial steady state exists if, and only if, the effectivness of abatement γ is high enough compared to the pollution externality β, that is, if the pollution production technology is clean (βv + γv γ < 0). (2) If the share of agents concerned about pollution is small enough (q < q), then a non-trivial steady state exists if, and only if, the effectivness of abatement is small enough compared to the pollution externality, that is if the technology is quite polluting (βv + γv γ > 0). For our purpose, it is interesting to investigate the impact of a change in the distribution of environmental concern for the long run state of the economy. Proposition 2. Impact of an increase of the share of type-g agents, on the long run capital and pollution stocks. (1) If the technology is clean, and if q > q, then a rise of q, the share of type G agents, induces a decrease of the steady state pollution and capital. (2) If the technology is polluting, and if q < q, then a rise of q induces an increase of the steady state pollution and capital. 8

9 Proof. Differentiating the functions P (q) and k(q) with respect to q we obtain, P (q) = P (h G h T ( ) ) bσ (1 v)(1 h(q)) (1 v) + (1 bσ h(q)) (14) k(q) kbσ(h G h T ) = (1 v)(1 h(q))(bσ + h(q) 1). (15) The sign of the above derivatives depends upon the sign of bσ + h(q) 1. If bσ + h(q) 1 < 0, which involves βv + γv γ < 0, then both dervatives are negative; while, if bσ + h(q) 1 > 0, which involves βv + γv γ > 0, then both derivatives are positive Interpretation The existence of a steady state is linked to the ease of reducing pollution in terms of its opportunity cost in consumption units. This cost depends upon the preferences, on the one hand, and upon the technology for pollution production, on the other hand. Actually, when pollution increases, type-g agents prefer to act for the reduction of pollution in increasing abatement, unless abatement is inefficient. Indeed, in this case only, the opportunity cost of consumption becomes too high so that they increase consumption. When pollution increases, type-t agents prefer to rise their consumption, as long as the consumption externality is relatively low compared to the efficiency of abatement. In fact, the opportunity cost of consumption iss too high for them so that they rise consumption, unless consumption be highly polluting. More precisely, first consider the case of a clean technology. Agents with a bad perception feel little affected by pollution on the one hand, little affected by consumption externality (β low) on the other hand. Consider pollution rises. To offset this rise, type-t individuals had better to save more in order to increase utility from consumption, even though this results into a further increase in pollution. In fact, the latter is felt only slightly compared to the gain provided by consumption. Therefore, if the share of technologist agents is too high, a steady state cannot exist since an increase in the long run pollution would entail further increase in pollution. Unlike type-t individuals, agents of type G care a lot about environment so that when pollution rises, they are strongly affected. Hence, since abatement is efficient, slightly increasing it induces a high utility gain without inducing a too high cost, since the decrease of consumption can be moderate. Hence when q is high enough, a steady state always exists because an increase of pollution is immediately reduced. Furthermore, the higher the share of type G, the larger the number of people who want to abat more, the lower the long run pollution. Now consider the case of a polluting technology. Any rise in pollution strongly affects environmentally concerned agents. However since abatement is not efficient, they cannot sufficiently reduce pollution without significantly reduce their consumption so that they had better to increase their consumption. On the other hand, type-t slightly suffer from an increase of pollution. Hence, even though abatement is not efficient, increasing it entails a sufficient reduction of pollution while a slight increase in saving would have resulted in a too high rise of pollution (because it is highly polluting). Hence when q is sufficiently low, a steady state always exists because any rise in pollution is immediately reduced. Finally the higher q, the lower the number who benefit from an increase in abatement, the higher the long run pollution. 9

10 Hence, an important conclusion is that a high share of agents with environmental concern is not sufficient for the existence of a steady state. A clean enough technology for the pollution production process is also required. 2.5 Stability of the non-trivial steady state Proposition 3. A necessary condition for local stability. (1) When the technology for the pollution production function is clean (βv + γv γ < 0), stability of the steady state requires that the cost of an additionnal unit of saving be relatively high (σ < n). (2) When the technology is polluting (βv + γv γ > 0), stability of the steady state requires that the cost of an additionnal unit of abatement be relatively high (σ > n). Proof. To study the local stability of the non-trivial steady state, we linearize the two-dimensional map composed of equations (??) and (??) around ( P (q), k(q)). Denote by Df 2 the jacobian matrix, we have Df 2 ( k, P ) = Its characteristic polynomial can be written as v(bσ+ h(q) 1) (1 h(q))(n σ) σvγ(bσ+ h(q) 1) (1 h(q))(n σ) P (λ) = α 0 λ 2 + α 1 λ + α 2, (1 b h(q)) γ(n σ) (bσ+ h(q) σ). (n σ) where α 0 = (n σ)(1 h(q)), α 1 = σ(b 1)( h(q) 1) + vbσ (1 h(q))(v + h(q)), and α 2 = h(q)v(bσ + h(q) 1). The steady state is locally stable if each eigenvalue of the above matrix is of magnitude less than one. We denote by λ 1 = α 1+ 2α 0 and λ 2 = α 1 2α 0 the roots of P. We want to show that, at least one of the two roots of the characteristics polynomial will be of magnitude higher than 1 if, on the one hand σ > n and βv+γv γ < 0, or if, on the other hand, σ < n and βv+γv γ > 0. (1) Let consider the case βv + γv γ < 0. The existence of a steady state implies α 2 > 0 since bσ + h(q) 1 is negative. Suppose that σ > n which implies α 0 < 0. Then α 2 1 4α 0 α 2 > α 2 1 (since 4α 0 α 2 < 0) so that > α 1. Hence λ 1 = α 1+ 2α 0 < 0. Especially, we show that we always have λ 1 < 1. λ 1 < 1 α 1 + 2α 0 > which is equivalent to > ( α 1 + 2α 0 ) 2 (since α 1 + 2α 0 > λ 2 < 1 and we are done), or also to α 1 α 2 α 0 < 0. However, after simplification, we find α 1 α 2 α 0 = (v 1)( h(q) 1)(bσ + h(q) 1) which is negative since bσ + h(q) 1 is negative. Finally, when βv + γv γ < 0 and σ > n, one of the eigenvalues, is always lower than 1 and the steady state is unstable. (2) Let consider the case βv + γv γ > 0 which implies α 2 < 0 since bσ + h(q) 1 is positive. Consider σ < n which implies α 0 > 0. Then = α 2 1 4α 0 α 2 > α 2 1 so that > α 1. Hence λ 1 = α 1+ 2α 0 is always positive, but this is not the case for λ 2, which, we will we show, is always lower than 1 as long as σ < n. This is equivalent to 2α 0 α 1 <, or > ( α 1 + 2α 0 ) 2 10

11 (since λ 1 > 0 2α 0 α 1 > ). When α 0 > 0, this is equivalent to α 1 α 2 α 0 = (v 1)( h(q) 1)(bσ + h(q) 1) > 0 which is always positive since bσ + h(q) 1 > 0. Hence, when βv + γv γ > 0 and σ < n, one of the eigenvalues is always lower than 1 and the steady state is unstable An interpretation of the necessary condition for local stability On the one hand, a high relative cost of an additional unit of saving (σ < n) have to be associated with efficient abatement (βv + γv γ < 0) along the transition path. Let suppose that the cost of past actions rises, then agents (of all types but especially of type G) want to increase abatement in order to limit the rise of pollution. Since abatement is efficient, for a slight increase of abatement spendings, they reach the desired level of pollution without decreasing saving too much. Hence pollution when old undergoes a limited increase while aggregate consumption decreases so that their is a rise of the cost of past actions for the following generation but which is rather moderate. Therefore, the new generation increases abatement spendings but less than the preceeding one such that, at each iteration, the magnitude of variations decreases and the system converges toward the non-trivial steady state. On the other hand, a high relative gain of an additional unit of saving (σ > n) have to be associated with inefficient abatement (βv + γv γ > 0) along the transition path. If they prefer to increase consumption after an increase of the cost of past actions then abatement must not affect pollution too heavily. Indeed, in this case, the increase in consumption must be of large magnitude to offset the lost generated by the rising level of pollution. The large variation of consumption and pollution would lead to an even higher variation of the cost of past actions for the next generation, which thus would have to increase consumption even more. On the contrary, if the decrease of abatement does not affect pollution too heavily, then the rise of consumption can be moderate. Hence, the rise of the cost of past actions for the next generation can be limited. Finally, the magnitude of variations decreases at each iteration, so that the system converges. 3 Model with endogeneous distribution of environmental concern In the following the distribution of environmental concern is no longer constant. We allow for a cultural transmission mechanism which relies on Bisin and Verdier s works [1998, 2001]. Children are born naive and adopt a defined kind of environmental attitude through imitation and social learning. Socialization is the result of two interacting types of transmission : transmission inside the family called direct transmission and socialization outside by peers, called oblique transmission. More precisely, each child is first exposed to his parents cultural trait (the perception of pollution for us) and adopts it with probability e i, i {G, T }. If not, which occurs with probability (1 e i ), he is socialized to the cultural trait of a role model choosen randomly in the population. Thus if direct transmission failed, probabilities to pick up trait G and T are respectively q t and 1 q t. Let P ij t be the probability for a child from a family with perception i to be socialized to trait j at time t. We have the following transistion probabilities : P GG t = e G t + (1 e G t )q t, P GT t = (1 e G t )(1 q t ), P T T t = e T t + (1 e T t )(1 q t ), and P T G t = (1 e T t )(q t ). 11

12 We can characterize the dynamic law for the share of agents with environmental concern in the population, q t+1 = q t + q t (1 q t )(e G e T ). (16) Furthermore, as Bisin and Verdier we assume socialization is an economic choice of parents which purposefully attempt at transmitting their own perception of the environment. Therefore we also consider there is cultural intolerance : the motivation to transmit comes from the fact parents feel a relatively higher gain to have a child like them. However, we will not rely on the standard Bisin and Verdier s set up. Instead, we suppose that the gain depends upon the relative advantage they judge their trait provide in given external conditions. In other words, the desire to transmit is environment-dependant and so endogeneous. As highlighted by Bisin and Verdier [2010], The preference on the part of parents for sharing their cultural trait with their children can depends on the economic and social conditions. This is because the child might feel relatively less advantaged when having his parents trait depending on its specific living conditions. In light of this reasoning, we assume the gain to be a function of perceived pollution. And so is the interpretation : for an agent of type G, the higher the perceived level of pollution, the more he thinks his child needs to be aware of what he is going to endangered in order to act accordingly, the higher the gain to have a child of his type. On the contrary, for a type-t individual, the lower the perceived pollution, the more he thinks his child does not have to worry about it because technology is reliable, the higher the gain to transmit its own perception. What is interesting with this kind of specification is that evolution of perceptions is somehow governed by Natural selection because the living environment provides the conditions in favor of one particular trait. Actually we are assuming reproductibility of each trait depends upon parental effort which is given rise by the gain to transmit, the latter being environment-dependant. We denote by V ij t the gain, for a parent of type i, to have a child of type j at time t, i {G, T }. A parent of type G faces the following welfare gain functions : Vt GG (Ht+1), G dv GG dh G > 0, with Vt GT (Ht+1), G Vt GG ( ) ( ) H G t+1 > V GT t H G t+1 dv GT dh G < 0, H G t+1 > 0. The relative gain function (which stands for cultural intolerance), V G (Ht+1) G = Vt GG ( ) ( ) H G t+1 V GT t H G t+1 is positive and increasing. Furthermore, we assume that V G (0) = 0, that is type-g parents do not demonstrate cultural intolerance toward technologists if there is no pollution. Likewise, a parent of type-t derives utility from : Vt T T (Ht+1), T dv T T dh T > 0, 12

13 with This results into V T T t Vt T G (Ht+1), T ( ) ( ) H T t+1 > V T G t H T t+1 V T (H T t+1) = V T T t dv T G dh T < 0, H T t+1 > 0. ( ) ( ) H T t+1 V T G t H T t+1 being positive but decreasing. Besides, let suppose that lim H T t+1 V T (Ht+1 T ) = 0, that is type-t parents do not demonstrate cultural intolerance toward environmentally concerned individuals if pollution is dramatically high. Finally we assume socialization is costly. The parental effort implies a welfare loss which can be understood as time spend with the child. This effort is denoted by C(e i ) with C(e i ) = e2 i 2C, where C is a positive constant. 3.1 Agents choices Agents live for three periods but are passive when child. We assume a two-stages maximisation process. During the adulthood, agents first choose their optimal combination of abatement-saving according to their concern for pollution. Then when their choices related to the economic sphere are made, they make their educational choices (to tranmsit their cultural trait). Hence, and because we assume the transmission effort enters separately in utility, we can deal with the socialization problem irrespective of the optimal saving-abatement choice. The same first order conditions hold for the economic problem. The socialization problem for each agent of type i, i {G, T }, is then to choose e i to maximize ( ) θ Pt ii Vt ii (Ht+1) i + P ij (Ht+1) i C ( e i), t V ij t leading to the following FOC for agents of type G and T respectively, θ(1 q t ) V G (H G t+1) eg t C = 0, θq t V T (H T t+1) et t C = 0. We can already see that e G and e T do not necessarily respect the cultural substitution property, as defined in Bisin and Verdier [2001]. On the one hand, direct and oblique transmission are substitutes in the socialization process. Namely, parents of type i have less incentives to socialize their child whenever the cultural trait i is more widespread in the population. Thereby, effort of type i falls to zero in the limit of a perfectly homogeneous population of type i. On the other hand, parental efforts are also sensitive to the variations of q through the variations of the perceived pollution level. Hence, depending on the direction and the magnitude of this second effect, the overall impact of q on e i can be of either sign. Calculating the derivatives, e G t t = Cθ V G (H G t+1) + Cθ(1 q t ) d V G dh G P t+1 t, e T t t = Cθ V P (H T t+1) + Cθq t d V T dh T P t+1 t. 13

14 Note, that we always have e G (0) > 0, e T (0) = 0 and e G (1) = 0, e T (1) > 0 whatever the second effect. In addition, et t t (0) = Cθ V T > 0 and eg t t (1) = Cθ V G > 0. Since Ht+1 i is a function of the variables at time t, which can be written as Hi (P t, k t, q t ), let replace Ht+1 i in the intolerance functions to have an optimal parental effort depending exclusively on the variables at t, e G (k t, P t, q t ) = Cθ(1 q t ) V G (H G (P t, k t, q t )), e T (k t, P t, q t ) = Cθq t V T (H T (P t, k t, q t )). By substituting those functions in (??), we obtain the dynamic law of the share of type-g agents. Therefore, in the system we are going to study, all variables are predeterminated. Definition 2 (Intertemporal Equilibirum). Let (k 0, P 0, q 0 ) be the vector of intial values. The intertemporal equilibrium is the sequence (k t, P t, q t ) t N which satisfies for each t, the following system of equations Steady states k t+1 = (1 b h(q t )) P t γ(n σ) P t+1 = (bσ + h(q t ) σ) P t (n σ) (βv + γv γ) kt v, (17) γ(n σ) (βv + γv γ)σ kt v, (18) (n σ) q t+1 = q t + q t (1 q t )(e G (P t, k t, q t ) e T (P t, k t, q t )). (19) Proposition 4. Existence of steady sates with cultural transmission of environmental concern. (1) If the pollution production technology is clean enough (βv + γv γ < 0), the system admits two steady states. One is characterized by a perfectly homogeneous population of environnmentally concerned people : ( P (1), k(1), 1). The other one is characterized by a heterogeneous population within which, the share of agents concerned about pollution is relatively high : ( P ( q), k( q), q) with ( q > q, with q defined as in Proposition??). (2) If the technology is polluting (βv + γv γ > 0), the system will have only one steady state characterized by a perfectly homogeneous population of technologist agents : ( P (0), k(0), 0). There will have no heterogeneous steady state unless the impact of pollution on the socialization process be negligible. Proof. Existence of steady states. A steady state of the three-dimensional system is a vector (k, P, q) which solves k t+1 = k t, P t+1 = P t, q t+1 = q t for all t. (As we have ever seen the point (0,0) solves the two first equations so that a vector (0,0,q) solves the whole system if q solves the third equation). 1 The variable q t can be rationnal as long as we restrcit to the case V i : R Q, i {G, T }. Indeed, it implies e i Q and hence q t Q. The behaviour of the dynamical system is decribed by a map G : R 2 Q R 2 Q. However, for the sake of simplicity, we study the same function G which maps R 3 into R 3. 14

15 Let S 1 = {{k(q), P (q)}, q [0, q[}, and S 2 = {{k(q), P (q)}, q ] q, 1]} be the sets of non-trivial steady states for the two-dimensional system respectively when βv + γv γ is positive or negative. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the three-dimensional system to be at steady state is thus the vector ( P, k) belongs to one either of the two sets (according to the sign of βv + γv γ) with q solving the third equation. That is q = 0, q = 1 and q solving e G t e P t = 0. Hence ( P (0), k(0), 0) is a steady state of the whole system when ( P (0), k(0)) S 1 and ( P (1), k(1), 1) is a steady state of the relevant system if ( P (1), k(1)) S 2. Furthermore the third equation admits a solution for q solving e G t e T t = 0 which is equivalent to 1 1 q = 1 + V G (Ht+1 G ) V T (Ht+1 P ). (20) As we know that the solution of the whole system ( P, k, q) must be such that ( P, k) are in either S 1 or S 2 we can fetch the solution in the restricted sets where ( P, k) are solutions of the twodimensional system. That is, in either of the two following sets : S 1 [0, q[ or S 2 ] q, 1]. The system admits a fixed point ( k, P, q) where 0 < q < 1 if the equation 1 1 q = 1 + V G (P (q)(1 h G )) V T (P (q)(1 h P )), (21) i. has at least one solution in [0, q[, when βv + γv γ > 0, ( P (q), k(q)) S 1 ; ii. has at least one solution in ] q, 1], when βv + γv γ < 0, ( P (q), k(q)) S 2. To study the existence of q let define and Ψ(q) = 1, q [0, 1] 1 q Φ 1 (q) = 1 + V G (P (q)(1 h G )) V T (P (q)(1 h P )) = 1 + V G (q) V T (q), q [0, q[, (P (q), k(q)) in S 1, Φ 2 (q) = 1 + V G (P (q)(1 h G )) V T (P (q)(1 h P )) = 1 + V G (q) V T (q), q ] q, 1], (P (q), k(q)) in S 2. We need to determine wheither Φ 1 (q) Ψ(q) = 0 admits a solution on [0, q[ on the one hand, and weither Φ 2 (q) Ψ(q) = 0 has a solution on ] q, 1] on the other hand. (1) Now let study the existence of some fixed points (different than the one where q is zero) on S 1 [0, q[. Ψ is strictly increasing on [0, q[, Ψ(0) = 1 and Ψ( q) = 1 1 q > 1. On the other hand, 15

16 q [0, q[ dφ 1 (q) dq = dp (q) dq d V G (q) dh G (1 h G ) V T (q) d V T (q) (1 h dh T T ) V G (q) ( V T (q)) 2. By assumption, d V G > 0 and d V P < 0. The second term of the product is thus positive and Φ dh G dh P 1 has the same sign as P on [0, q[. We know, from the study related to the economic sphere, that P (q) > 0 q [0, q[ (see section 2.). So that Φ 1 is strictly increasing on [0, q[. Moroever, Φ 1 (0) = 1 + V G (0) V P is strictly superior to 1 since, by assumption, the functions (0) V G and V P are striclty positive as long as for i {G, T } H i > 0, which is true, since here H i = P (0)(1 h i ) > 0. Furthermore we have, lim q q lim H G lim H P P (q) = +, V G (H G ) = δ <, V P (H P ) = 0, so that Φ( q) = lim q q Φ 1(q) = + 2. Let define the continous function g 1 (q) = Φ 1 (q) Ψ(q), we have g 1 (0) > 0, lim q q g 1 (q) =. For g 1 (q) = 0 to have solution on [0, q[, a necessary condition is g 1 to be decreasing on some interval [q 1, q 2 ], with q 1 0 and q 2 < q, or dg1 dq = dφ 1 dq dψ dq < 0 on [q 1, q 2 ]. That is, we need to find dφ 1 dq < dψ dq on the relevant interval. However, dψ dq = 1 is precisely low for low values of q, so that, the (1 q) 2 necessary condition does not hold if the derivative of Φ 1 is not small enough. More particularly, g 1 must decrease sufficiently such that it reaches the x-axis. Then for that condition to be true, dg1 dq must be negative enough, that is dφ 1 dq has to be very close to zero. Therefore, a steady state is unlikely on S 1 [0, q[. It requires that the impact of a change in pollution on the transmission process dφ 1 dq be negligible so that the effect of cultural substitution (a change in the cultural composition of the population), dψ dq, which is weak, overcomes it3. (2) Let study the existence of solutions in ] q, 1]. Ψ is strictly increasing on ] q, 1]. Ψ(1) = lim q 1 Ψ(q) = + and as we just noted Ψ( q) is a finite number which is superior to one. 2 V G (H G ) cannot be infinite, otherwise the optimal effort, which stands for the probability of direct transmission, could be higher than one as long as C, or θ, are not zero. Likewise, V T (H T ) must be finite in zero. 3 To make sure of the unlikelihood of a steady state and to confirm the conditions on its existence, we relied on a numerical exemple. This is presented in Appendix. 16

17 On the other hand, the derivative of Φ 2 on the interval ] q, 1] has the same sign as P on the same interval. From our study we know that the latter is negative on ] q, 1]. So that Φ 2 is stictly decreasing on ] q, 1]. At q=1, Φ 2 (1) = 1 + V G (P (1)(1 h G )) V P (P (1)(1 h P )) is a finite number supeior to one. Besides, lim P (q) = +, hence Φ( q) = lim Φ 1(q) = +. q q + q q + Finally, we have Φ 2 ( q) > Ψ( q) et Φ 2 (1) < Ψ(1). Φ 2 and Ψ are both continous on ] q, 1]. Moreover Ψ is strictly increasing on ] q, 1], while Φ 2 is decreasing on the same interval. According to the intermediate value theorem there is a unique q ] q, 1] such that. Ψ(q) = Φ 2 (q) Interpretation regarding existence of a steady state A steady state with a heterogeneous distribution of environmental attitudes always exists if the technology is such that abatement is quite effective compared to the strengh of consumption externality. The intuition is as follows : in that situation, as soon as pollution increases type-g agents have incentive to increase abatement (unlike type-t ). The larger the share of agents of type G, the higher the number of people who benefit more from a rise in abatement, the higher the rise in total abatement spendings. Hence, an increase in q reduces the level of pollution. Both changes, in environmental conditions on the one hand, in the composition of the population on the other hand alter cultural attitudes in the same direction. Parents of type G reduce their effort not only because transmission by peers works better but also because they feel a relatively lower gain to transmit their own trait since perceived pollution is lower. The reverse is true for individual of type-t so that q eventually decreases. When effectivness of abatement is low while consumption externality is quite high, a steady state associated with heterogeneous population is very unlikely. Actually, when the technology is polluting, as highlited in section 2., type-t agents, as opposed to type-g, have incentive to abat more and save less after a rise in pollution (because of the opportunity cost of consumption). Contrary to the case of a clean technology, an increase in q involves a rise of the pollution stock. On the one hand, the substitution effect enables a relative increase of type-t parental effort against type-g and allows a decrease of q. On the other hand, the rise in pollution alters relative parental efforts in the opposite direction and favours an increase of q. The system will admit a stationnary state if the overall effect is a decrease of q, i.e. the magnitude of the substitution effect is higher than the strengh of the impact of pollution. However when q is small, which is precisely the case when the technology is polluting (remember we are working in [0, q[), the former effect is very weak. Hence q, the fraction of type-g agents will further increases unless the effect of pollution on the socialization process is negligible. Finally, and contrary to the results we have got within our first model, when economic choices and cultural attitudes toward environment are jointly determined it is never sustainable to have a polluting technology, as long as pollution interacts in a non negligible way on the transmission of environmental concern. A clean technology and a high share of environmentally concerned people becomes the necessary and 17

18 sufficient conditions for the existence of a steady state, that is for sustainability. 3.3 Stability of steady states Stability of the steady states with homogeneous population Proposition 5. Unstability of the homogeneous stationnary population. (1) The steady state characterized by an homogeneous population of agents with environmental concern ( P (1), k(1), 1) (existing if (and only if) the technology is clean (βv + γv γ < 0)) is unstable. (2) The steady state characterized by an homogeneous population of technologist agents ( P (0), k(0), 0), (existing if (and only if) the technology is polluting (βv + γv γ > 0)) is unstable. Proof. To study the local stability of each steady state let linearize the system consisting of equations (16), (17) and (18) around ( P (0), k(0), 0) on the one hand (βv + γv γ > 0), and around ( P (1), k(1), 1), on the other hand (βv + γv γ > 0). (1) The Jacobian matrix evaluated at ( P (0), k(0), 0) is v(bσ+ h(0) 1) (1 h(0))(n σ) σγv(bσ+ h(0) 1) (1 h(0))(n σ) (1 b h(0)) γ(n σ) (bσ+ h(0) σ) (n σ) We can express its characteristic polynomial as γ(h G h P ) (n σ) (h G h P ) (n σ) P e G (0) e T (0) Q 1 (λ) = ([1 + e G (0) e T (0)] λ)(α 0 λ 2 + α 1 λ + α 2 ), where α 0, α 1 and α 2 are defined as in section 2.5. The second term of this product is precisely P (λ), the characteristic polynomial of Df 2 defined in section 2.5, evaluated at q = 0. Hence, two of the eigenvalues can be of magnitude less than one as long as the two-dimensional system of section 2 is stable. That is Df 2 has two eigenvalues of magnitude less than one (which requires especially σ > n). However, the third eignevalue is equal to 1 + e T (0) e G (0). This is always higher than one since the socialization mechanism implies e G (0) > 0 and e T (0) = 0. Hence, the system consisting of (16), (17) and (18) is never stable around ( P (0), k(0), 0). (2) The Jacobian matrix evaluated at ( P (1), k(1), 1) is P v(bσ+ h(1) 1) (1 h(1))(n σ) σγv(bσ+ h(1) 1) (1 h(1))(n σ) (1 b h(1)) γ(n σ) (bσ+ h(1) σ) (n σ) γ(h G h P ) (n σ) (h G h P ) (n σ) P e T (1) e G (1) P 18

19 Its characteristic polynomial can be express as Q 2 (λ) = ([1 + e T (1) e G (1)] λ)(α 0 λ 2 + α 1 λ + α 2 ). Again if stability holds for the two-dimensional system studied in section 2.5. (especially, σ < n), then two of the eigeinvalues are of magitude less than one. Then, the three-dimensional system is stable if and only if λ 3 = 1 + e T (1) e G (1), has absolute value less than one. However within our set up, e T (1) > 0 while e G (1) = 0, so that we always have λ 3 > 1 and the system consisting of (16), (17) and (18) is never stable around ( P (1), k(1), 1) Stability of the steady state with heterogeneous population When linearizing the system at ( P ( q), k( q), q ), we obtain the following Jacobian matrix v(bσ+ h( q) 1) (1 h( q))(n σ) σγv(bσ+ h( q) 1) (1 h( q))(n σ) G( q, P )σγv(bσ+ h( q) 1) (1 h( q))(n σ) where (1 b h( q)) γ(n σ) (bσ+ h( q) σ) (n σ) G( q, P )(bσ+ h( q) σ) (n σ) G( q, P ) = q(1 q)βc ((1 q) V G H T γ(h G h P ) (n σ) (h G h P ) (n σ) 1 + G( q, P )(h G h T ) P (n σ) + q(1 q)βc( V T V G ) P P ) V T q H T. Expressions of the eigenvalues are far more complicated so that we rely on a numerical exemple to study the local stability. Contrary to the other steady states, we find that this one could be stable for large combinations of the parameters. We also observe that σ < n is still necessary for stability Interpreting stability The steady state characterized by an homogeneous population, either in the clean technology case (q = 1) or when technology is polluting (q = 0), is always unstable whatever the interaction between the pollution generated by the economic sphere and the cultural composition of the population. Actually, what matters is the effect of economic choices on capital and pollution on the one hand, and the effect of cultural choices on the cultural composition of the population on the other hand. Hence no matter if the former effect enables the economy to converge to a stationnary state, the system will never be stable because cultural choices lead to move away from full homogeneity of the population. Actually, vertical and oblique transmission are cultural substitutes, so that, all else equal, parents have less incentives to socialize their children, the more widely dominant are their environmental values in the population. In the limit of a perfectly homogeneous population of type G or T, parents of type G or T, respectively, do not directly socialize their child. The cultural substitution property makes homogeneous distributions of environmental concern unstable. Conversely, the stability of the steady state characterized by an heterogeneous population crucially depends upon the interaction between the economic sphere, and the cultural sphere which is linked to the value of σ. First, as long as σ < n, economic as well as cultural choices enable the convergence of capital and pollution stocks. Actually, the cultural composition of the population affects the economic sphere in strengthening the effect of economic choices on the stocks of capital and pollution. On the one hand, as more detailed in section 2, as long as σ < n a rise in the, 19

20 bequeathed stock of pollution encourages agents to increase abatement and enables convergence toward a stationnary state (since abatement is efficient). On the other hand, agents of type G are precisely those who increase more abatement since they are sensitive to pollution. Hence an increase of the share of type-g agents allows for stability because it lowers the increase of capital and pollution in strenghtening the stabilizing effect of aggregated economic actions. Secondly, the cultural choices enable the convergence toward the heterogeneous composition of the population. Importantly, when σ < n the cultural substitution property holds, that is parental effort of type-i decreases with the fraction of type-i. On the one hand, the technology of direct socialization allows for cultural substitution property : parents have less incentives to socialize their children whenever their cultural trait is more widely dominant because direct and oblique transmission act as substitutes. Nevertheless a sufficient condition for cultural substitution to hold, involves the impact of the distribution of environmental concern, at some t, on the next pollution stock. In fact, since pollution favours the transmission of environmental concern (through the intolerance functions), an increase of the fraction of environmentally concerned have to imply the reduction of pollution in order to reduce the desire to transmit. As we just point out in the first paragraph, it is precisely the case when σ < n. Hence the system can converge to an heterogeneous steady state but σ < n is a necessary condition. 20

Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation.

Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation. Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation. 1 Without any doubts human capital is a key factor of economic growth because

More information

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model 21.1: Introduction This is an important chapter in that it introduces, and explores the implications of, an empirically relevant utility function representing intertemporal

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth Michael Bräuninger October 2002 Abstract This paper analyzes the effects of public debt on endogenous growth in an overlapping generations model. The

More information

Why do merchants accept payment cards?

Why do merchants accept payment cards? Why do merchants accept payment cards? Julian Wright National University of Singapore Abstract This note explains why merchants accept expensive payment cards when merchants are Cournot competitors. The

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine 1 The Standard Schumpeterian Competition Monopolistic Competition innovation modeled as endogenous rate of movement

More information

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey SIMULATING THE TURKISH TAX SYSTEM ADEM İLERİ Middle East Technical University Department of Economics aileri@metu.edu.tr PINAR DERİN-GÜRE Middle East Technical University Department of Economics pderin@metu.edu.tr

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 10, 2013 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 10, 2013 1 / 44 Growth

More information

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality ROBERTO ROSON Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Venice, Italy. Abstract I review two papers, addressing the issue of

More information

The Real Business Cycle model

The Real Business Cycle model The Real Business Cycle model Spring 2013 1 Historical introduction Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynesian

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Daniel McFadden Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley April 8, 2002 I. This note is concerned with the economics of

More information

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction One of the most important long-run issues in macroeconomics is understanding growth. Why do economies grow and what determines

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Updated for the 9th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement

More information

2007/8. The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production of physical capital. Agustin Pérez-Barahona

2007/8. The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production of physical capital. Agustin Pérez-Barahona 2007/8 The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production of physical capital Agustin Pérez-Barahona CORE DISCUSSION PAPER 2007/8 The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production

More information

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT ECONOMICS OF GROWTH AND INNOVATION Lecture 1, January 23, 2004 Theories of Economic Growth 1. Introduction 2. Exogenous Growth The Solow Model Mandatory

More information

Adverse selection in health insurance: are first best. contracts impossible?

Adverse selection in health insurance: are first best. contracts impossible? Adverse selection in health insurance: are first best contracts impossible? David Alary CERPEM-SDF, University Paris Dauphine Franck Bien EuRISCO LEGOS, University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note,

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan

Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan 1. Introduction The paper looks at an economic environment where borrowers have some

More information

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary John Creedy The University of Melbourne Abstract This paper provides a non-technical summary of the concept of the elasticity of taxable income,

More information

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models Discussion Paper No. 06-078 Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models Rainer Klump and Marianne Saam Discussion Paper No. 06-078 Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions

More information

Money and Public Finance

Money and Public Finance Money and Public Finance By Mr. Letlet August 1 In this anxious market environment, people lose their rationality with some even spreading false information to create trading opportunities. The tales about

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION March 1, 2005 JCX-4-05 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract Interconnection Agreement between Internet Service Providers and the Optimal Policy Intervention: The Case of Cournot-type Competition under Network Externalities Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Money and Capital in an OLG Model

Money and Capital in an OLG Model Money and Capital in an OLG Model D. Andolfatto June 2011 Environment Time is discrete and the horizon is infinite ( =1 2 ) At the beginning of time, there is an initial old population that lives (participates)

More information

Online Supplementary Material

Online Supplementary Material Online Supplementary Material The Supplementary Material includes 1. An alternative investment goal for fiscal capacity. 2. The relaxation of the monopoly assumption in favor of an oligopoly market. 3.

More information

Earnings in private jobs after participation to post-doctoral programs : an assessment using a treatment effect model. Isabelle Recotillet

Earnings in private jobs after participation to post-doctoral programs : an assessment using a treatment effect model. Isabelle Recotillet Earnings in private obs after participation to post-doctoral programs : an assessment using a treatment effect model Isabelle Recotillet Institute of Labor Economics and Industrial Sociology, UMR 6123,

More information

HANDOUTS Property Taxation Review Committee

HANDOUTS Property Taxation Review Committee HANDOUTS Property Taxation Review Committee Legislative Services Agency September 1, 2004 Criteria For Good Proposals for Property Tax Reform Dr. Thomas Pogue, University of Iowa DISCLAIMER The Iowa General

More information

Determinants of Social Discount Rate, general case

Determinants of Social Discount Rate, general case Determinants of Social Discount Rate, general case The resulting equation r = ρ + θ g is known as the Ramsey equation after Frank Ramsey (928) The equation states tt that t in an optimal intertemporal

More information

Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling

Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling Daron Acemoglu MIT November 3, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Education, Selection, and Signaling November 3, 2011. 1 / 31 Introduction

More information

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful?

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? Economics Letters 87 (2005) 313 317 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? David Bardey a, T, Romain Lesur b a GREMAQ UMR CNRS 5604-Manufacture des

More information

Stochastic Inventory Control

Stochastic Inventory Control Chapter 3 Stochastic Inventory Control 1 In this chapter, we consider in much greater details certain dynamic inventory control problems of the type already encountered in section 1.3. In addition to the

More information

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle (RBC) Theory is the other dominant strand of thought in modern macroeconomics. For the most part, RBC theory has held much less sway amongst policy-makers

More information

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Cécile Aubert Abstract Two agents sequentially contracts with different principals under moral

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

Electronics for Analog Signal Processing - II Prof. K. Radhakrishna Rao Department of Electrical Engineering Indian Institute of Technology Madras

Electronics for Analog Signal Processing - II Prof. K. Radhakrishna Rao Department of Electrical Engineering Indian Institute of Technology Madras Electronics for Analog Signal Processing - II Prof. K. Radhakrishna Rao Department of Electrical Engineering Indian Institute of Technology Madras Lecture - 18 Wideband (Video) Amplifiers In the last class,

More information

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis.

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis. Revenue :The income receipt by way of sale proceeds is the revenue of the firm. As with costs, we need to study concepts of total, average and marginal revenues. Each unit of output sold in the market

More information

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS Gustavo A. Marrero Alfonso Novales y July 13, 2011 ABSTRACT: In a Barro-type economy with exogenous consumption aspirations, raising income taxes favors

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

ELASTICITY OF LONG DISTANCE TRAVELLING

ELASTICITY OF LONG DISTANCE TRAVELLING Mette Aagaard Knudsen, DTU Transport, mak@transport.dtu.dk ELASTICITY OF LONG DISTANCE TRAVELLING ABSTRACT With data from the Danish expenditure survey for 12 years 1996 through 2007, this study analyses

More information

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains?

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains? The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains? Wilfred J. Ethier Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania First version: 30 November 2007 This printing: 21 April 2009 The Greater the Differences,

More information

Credit card interchange fees

Credit card interchange fees Credit card interchange fees Jean-Charles Rochet Julian Wright January 23, 2009 Abstract We build a model of credit card pricing that explicitly takes into account credit functionality. We show that a

More information

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies Thomas Aronsson and Linda Thunström Department of Economics, Umeå University SE - 901 87 Umeå, Sweden April 2005 Abstract The starting point for this

More information

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing) Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing) EC 105. Industrial Organization. Fall 2011 Matt Shum HSS, California Institute of Technology November 14, 2012 EC 105. Industrial Organization. Fall

More information

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers Sam C.M. Lee John C.S. Lui + Abstract The current Internet architecture comprises of different privately owned Internet service providers

More information

Introduction to time series analysis

Introduction to time series analysis Introduction to time series analysis Margherita Gerolimetto November 3, 2010 1 What is a time series? A time series is a collection of observations ordered following a parameter that for us is time. Examples

More information

Nº 252 Diciembre 2003

Nº 252 Diciembre 2003 Nº 252 Diciembre 2003 Documento de Trabajo ISSN (edición impresa) 0716-7334 ISSN (edición electrónica) 0717-7593 Social Security Financial Crises Rodrigo Cerda www.economia.puc.cl Versión impresa ISSN:

More information

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 3 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Key Concepts Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans In the very short run, firms do not change their prices and they sell the amount that is demanded.

More information

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) 1 CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) This model is the main tool in the suite of models employed by the staff and the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) in the construction

More information

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction Benjamin Edelman Hoan Soo Lee Working Paper 09-074 Copyright 2008 by Benjamin Edelman and Hoan Soo Lee Working papers are in draft form. This working paper

More information

Entrepreneurs Heterogeneity and New Ventures Financing. Eli Berkovitch Interdisciplinary Center, Hertzliya e-mail: elib@idc.ac.il

Entrepreneurs Heterogeneity and New Ventures Financing. Eli Berkovitch Interdisciplinary Center, Hertzliya e-mail: elib@idc.ac.il Work in Progress. Please don't quote or circulate. Entrepreneurs Heterogeneity and New Ventures Financing Eli Berkovitch Interdisciplinary Center, Hertzliya e-mail: elib@idc.ac.il Yaniv Grinstein Cornell

More information

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Willemien Kets Northwestern University w-kets@kellogg.northwestern.edu David M. Pennock Microsoft Research New York City dpennock@microsoft.com

More information

Sample Midterm Solutions

Sample Midterm Solutions Sample Midterm Solutions Instructions: Please answer both questions. You should show your working and calculations for each applicable problem. Correct answers without working will get you relatively few

More information

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 13 2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Introduction Simplistic RBC Model Simple stochastic growth model Baseline RBC model Introduction

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

)LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\

)LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\ )LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\ ([HFXWLYH6XPPDU\ %\ 3URI'U0LFKDHO*)DXUH//0 DQG 0U'DYLG*ULPHDXG Maastricht University and European Centre for Tort and Insurance Law (ECTIL) Final version

More information

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE I. Alternatives to Comparative Advantage Economies of Scale The fact that the largest share of world trade consists of the exchange of similar (manufactured) goods between

More information

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets Chapter 6 Competitive Markets After reading Chapter 6, COMPETITIVE MARKETS, you should be able to: List and explain the characteristics of Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition Explain why a

More information

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory In this lecture we go on considering a general equilibrium model of a private ownership economy. In contrast to the Notes IV, we focus on positive issues such

More information

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty 1. Introduction In this lecture we examine the theory of decision-making under uncertainty and its application to the demand for insurance. The undergraduate

More information

Economic Development and Gains from Trade

Economic Development and Gains from Trade Economics Education and Research Consortium Working Paper Series Economic Development and Gains from Trade Georgi Trofimov Working Paper No 98/06 This project (No 96-161) was supported by the Economics

More information

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich. Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459. Working Paper No. 229

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich. Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459. Working Paper No. 229 Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459 Working Paper No. 229 On the Notion of the First Best in Standard Hidden Action Problems Christian

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 11 FISCAL POLICY* Key Concepts The Federal Budget The federal budget is an annual statement of the government s expenditures and tax revenues. Using the federal budget to achieve macroeconomic

More information

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 How Not to Win a Million Dollars: A Counterexample to a Conjecture of L. Breiman Thomas P. Hayes arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 Abstract Consider a gambling game in which we are allowed to repeatedly

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Why payment card fees are biased against merchants

Why payment card fees are biased against merchants Why payment card fees are biased against merchants Julian Wright November 2010 Abstract I formalize the popular argument that payment card networks such as MasterCard and Visa charge merchants too much

More information

The Trip Scheduling Problem

The Trip Scheduling Problem The Trip Scheduling Problem Claudia Archetti Department of Quantitative Methods, University of Brescia Contrada Santa Chiara 50, 25122 Brescia, Italy Martin Savelsbergh School of Industrial and Systems

More information

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation Louis Kaplow * Abstract In a recent article, I demonstrated that, under standard simplifying assumptions, it is possible

More information

Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Ù

Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Ù Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Page 1 Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Ù Introduction 1 Discounting the future 2 Interpreting the discount factor 3 The average discounted payoff 4

More information

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect?

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect? Name: Number: Nova School of Business and Economics Macroeconomics, 1103-1st Semester 2013-2014 Prof. André C. Silva TAs: João Vaz, Paulo Fagandini, and Pedro Freitas Final Maximum points: 20. Time: 2h.

More information

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Optimality Conditions Euler equation under uncertainty: u C (C t, 1 N t) = βe t [u C (C t+1, 1 N t+1)

More information

(Refer Slide Time: 01:11-01:27)

(Refer Slide Time: 01:11-01:27) Digital Signal Processing Prof. S. C. Dutta Roy Department of Electrical Engineering Indian Institute of Technology, Delhi Lecture - 6 Digital systems (contd.); inverse systems, stability, FIR and IIR,

More information

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg-Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni-essen.de 14th March 2005 Abstract

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 18 August 2009 Lecture plan and web pages for this course The lecture plan is at http://folk.uio.no/rnymoen/econ3410_h08_index.html,

More information

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Challenges for defined contribution plans While Eastern Europe is a prominent example of the importance of defined

More information

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself

More information

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 12 Number 1 Spring 1999 AN ANALYSIS OF VARIATIONS IN CAPITAL ASSET UTILIZATION

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 12 Number 1 Spring 1999 AN ANALYSIS OF VARIATIONS IN CAPITAL ASSET UTILIZATION Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 2 Number Spring 999 AN ANALYSIS OF VARIATIONS IN CAPITAL ASSET UTILIZATION Kwang S. Lee *, Robert J. Hartl ** and Jong C. Rhim ** Abstract This paper

More information

No-Betting Pareto Dominance

No-Betting Pareto Dominance No-Betting Pareto Dominance Itzhak Gilboa, Larry Samuelson and David Schmeidler HEC Paris/Tel Aviv Yale Interdisciplinary Center Herzlyia/Tel Aviv/Ohio State May, 2014 I. Introduction I.1 Trade Suppose

More information

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}. Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 5, September 16 Outline 1 Walrasian Demand 2 Properties of Walrasian Demand 3 An Optimization Recipe 4 First and Second Order Conditions Definition Walrasian

More information

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade Michele Connolly Duke University and Diego Valderrama Federal Reserve

More information

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC MARKET STRUCTURE AND INSIDER TRADING WASSIM DAHER AND LEONARD J. MIRMAN Abstract. In this paper we examine the real and financial effects of two insiders trading in a static Jain Mirman model (Henceforth

More information

Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly?

Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly? Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly? David Barker April 26, 2009 Summary: After a long period of stability which ended in the early 1990s, U.S. house prices rose for more than a decade, then suddenly

More information

Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do?

Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do? Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do? Allan H. Meltzer The title of Ball and Mankiw s paper asks: What Do Budget Deficits Do? One answer to that question is a restatement on the pure theory of debt-financed

More information

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas Price Discrimination: Part 2 Sotiris Georganas 1 More pricing techniques We will look at some further pricing techniques... 1. Non-linear pricing (2nd degree price discrimination) 2. Bundling 2 Non-linear

More information

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk 1 This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. 1 Jonathan B. Berk Haas School

More information

Thomas Piketty Academic year 2014-2015

Thomas Piketty Academic year 2014-2015 Public Economics: Tax & Transfer Policies (Master PPD & APE, Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty Academic year 2014-2015 Lecture 3: Externalities & corrective taxation: illustration with global warming

More information

EFFECT OF ENVIRONMENTAL CONCERN & SOCIAL NORMS ON ENVIRONMENTAL FRIENDLY BEHAVIORAL INTENTIONS

EFFECT OF ENVIRONMENTAL CONCERN & SOCIAL NORMS ON ENVIRONMENTAL FRIENDLY BEHAVIORAL INTENTIONS 169 EFFECT OF ENVIRONMENTAL CONCERN & SOCIAL NORMS ON ENVIRONMENTAL FRIENDLY BEHAVIORAL INTENTIONS Joshi Pradeep Assistant Professor, Quantum School of Business, Roorkee, Uttarakhand, India joshipradeep_2004@yahoo.com

More information

LONGEVITY AND ANNUITIES: AN INTRODUCTION

LONGEVITY AND ANNUITIES: AN INTRODUCTION LONGEVITY AND ANNUITIES: AN INTRODUCTION HELMUTH CREMER Toulouse School of Economics (GREMAQ, IDEI, and Institut Universitaire de France) PIERRE PESTIEAU Université deliège and CORE For decades the debate

More information