CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich"

Transcription

1 CER-ETH - Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich Economics Working Paper Series Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule Zürich Swiss Federal Institute of Technology Zurich

2 On the Design of Basic-Research Policy Hans Gersbach CER-ETH Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich and CEPR 8092 Zurich, Switzerland Maik T. Schneider CER-ETH Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich 8092 Zurich, Switzerland Olivier Schneller CER-ETH Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich 8092 Zurich, Switzerland First Version: May 2007 This Version: January 2008 Abstract We augment a Schumpeterian growth model with a public basic-research sector to examine how much a country should invest in basic research. We find that the closer the country is to the world s technological frontier the more the government should invest in basic research. Basic-research expenditures are increasing with a country s degree of openness as long as innovation sizes are small. We provide possible explanations for the empirical evidence available on basic-research expenditures across countries. Keywords: basic research, openness, distance to frontier, economic growth. JEL: O31, O38 We would like to thank Philippe Aghion and the participants of the Conference on the Economics of Technology Policy, 2007, at Monte Verita for valuable comments. All errors remain our own.

3 1 Introduction It is widely recognized in economic literature that basic research 1 plays a significant role in economic growth (e.g. Narin et al. 1997, Mansfield 1998, Martin 1998) 2. However, large inequalities are observable across countries with respect to basic-research expenditures (e.g., Cole and Phelan 1999 and Schofer 2004). The majority of basic research is performed by a small number of highly industrialized countries. For example, the US and Japan together account for almost half of the global basic-research expenditures. By contrast, technologically backward countries such as China and Argentina invest very little in basic research (OECD 2006). Basic research is usually provided publicly by the government (see OECD 2004). In this paper we build on Aghion et al. (2006) and incorporate publicly financed basic research into a Schumpeterian growth framework. We ask how much a country should invest in basic research depending on its degree of openness and its distance from the world s technological frontier. We assume that basic research increases the innovation probability of private intermediate firms within a country. 3 Intermediate sectors differ with regard to the distance from the world s technological frontier. The country s degree of openness is reflected by the probability of market entry by a foreign firm. The country is exposed to the technological frontier, i.e. foreign firms always enter at the world s most advanced technological level and consequently drive domestic firms operating at a lower technological level out of the market. Only those domestic firms that are close to the technological frontier and have been successful with innovation are internationally competitive and can hence prevent a potential foreign entrant from encroaching on the domestic market. We allow the government to allocate a share of labor to basic research. The workers in this sector have to be paid competitive wages. The government s decision on basic research is then characterized by the following considerations: First, by increasing 1 A standard definition of basic research is given by the OECD: Basic research is experimental or theoretical work undertaken primarily to acquire new knowledge of the underlying foundation of phenomena and observable facts, without any particular application or use in view (OECD, 2002, p. 30). 2 See Salter and Martin (2001) for an extensive review of this literature. 3 Several empirical studies (e.g. Jaffe 1989, Katz 1994, Narin et al. 1997, Zellner 2003; see Salter and Martin (2001) for a detailed review of this literature.) support our assumption by indicating that basic research has a strong tendency to produce local effects. They suggest, for instance, that basic research increases the innovation chances of domestic firms by the education of problem-solvers and local informal face-to-face interactions. 1

4 the innovation probability, basic research helps to escape entry of foreign firms to technologically advanced sectors. Second, basic research helps to sustain the monopoly of backward firms, as the competitive fringe catches up with such a firm when it is not innovating. Third, basic research is a costly way of fostering technological progress in comparison with the free import of foreign high technology. We solve the government s problem for polar cases - technologically advanced and backward countries - and we derive additional results by numerical simulations for intermediate cases. For large sets of parameter values, we find that the higher the share of high-technology sectors is the more a government should invest in basic research. The effect of openness on the optimal amount of basic research is ambiguous. With a small innovation size, the free productivity boost linked to the entry of foreign hightechnology firms is small. Accordingly, the government will prefer to prevent foreign entry and keep the domestic intermediates profits in the country. For this reason, optimal basic research increases with the country s openness. However, with a high innovation size, the opposite investment behavior is optimal. The entry of foreign firms is welcome as they import leading technology and effect large productivity increases in the domestic country. In other words, to achieve a higher level of technology, it is cheaper to allow the entry of foreign firms and to forgo intermediate profits than to draw labor from production for basic research. As we will elaborate in detail in section 6.1, our theoretical results may provide possible explanations for two empirical patterns. First, basic-research expenditures and technology levels are positively correlated. Second, there is an ambiguous relationship between basic research and the degree of openness. Our paper is organized as follows: In the next section we relate our work to the literature on economic growth. The model is presented in section 3. Section 4 contains a discussion of the effects of basic research in our model, followed by a comparative statics analysis in section 5. In section 6, we discuss our results and relate them to the empirical pattern of basic research. Our conclusions are presented in section 7. 2 Relation to the Literature on Economic Growth Theoretical literature on economic growth has mostly focused on private R&D activities. In the standard innovation-driven growth models (Romer 1990, Aghion and 2

5 Howitt 1992) profit-maximizing firms engage in R&D activities to generate (partially) excludable knowledge or blueprints for new marketable intermediate goods. There are a few attempts in literature to include basic research in an R&D-driven growth model. Contributions to the discussion mostly focus on the optimal basicresearch investment for economic growth in closed countries. Shell (1967) presented the first model of this kind. However, his model does not consider applied research by private firms. Profit-maximizing firms conducting different kinds of research are the focus chosen by Osano (1992), who investigates how the composition of basic and applied research affects growth. He does not include a public basic-research sector. In Bailén (1994) the same issue is examined, this time with publicly financed basic research. Morales (2004) combines the approaches of Osano and Bailén in a model where both the firms and the government perform basic research. She analyzes what kind of research policy pertaining to public provision and subsidies for basic/applied research leads to optimal growth. In another article, Pelloni (1997) examines the government s task to generate the conditions for growth by financing higher education and/or scientific research, whereas both are perfect substitutes. The papers closest to ours are those by Park (1998) and Carillo and Papagni (2007). The former analyzes cross-country spillovers of basic research in a growth model with two identical countries and determines the efficient size of a country s basic research sector in relation to the economy s openness. Here basic research is considered as a global public good, whereas we focus on basic research as an instrument in enhancing the innovation prospects of domestic firms. Additionally, we allow for different levels of technology across countries. The paper by Carillo and Papagni (2007) delivers an explanation for the high cross-country inequalities observed in basic research investments by examining the scientific reward system in relation to the size of the scientific sector. We focus on how openness and the state of technology impact on the size of the basic-research sector. 3 The Model Building on the Schumpeterian growth model proposed by Aghion et al. (2006), we introduce a basic-research sector operated by the government. We assume that there is a continuum of identical households that live for one period, enjoy strictly increasing utility in consumption, inelastically supply one unit of labor, and receive an equal share 3

6 of the final good and intermediate firms profits. We consider a government maximizing domestic consumption over a single period by publicly providing basic research financed by an income tax. 4 Accordingly, we first describe the production side of the economy and derive the equilibrium for a given level of basic research. We then proceed to solve the government s optimization problem. 3.1 Final-Good Sector In the final-good sector, a continuum of competitive firms produces the homogeneous consumption good y according to: y = 1 0 A(i) 1 α x(i) α di. (1) x(i) stands for the amount of intermediate input of variety i and A(i) is this variety s productivity factor. The parameter α determines the output elasticity of the intermediate goods or the level of technology. The price of the final consumption good is normalized to one. In the following we will operate with one representative finalgood firm. Maximization of the final-good firm s profits π y gives the inverse demand functions for intermediate goods x(i): max x(i) πy = y 1 where p(i) is the price of good x(i). 0 p(i)x(i) di = p(i) = α ( ) 1 α A(i), (2) x(i) 3.2 Intermediate-Goods Sectors The intermediate goods x(i) are produced by labor L x (i) only, using a linear technology: x(i) = L x (i). (3) Intermediate-goods firms act competitively in the labor market and compete à la Bertrand in their intermediate sector. The productivity leader is able to establish a monopoly position and perfect competition prevails if there is no technological leader. 4 The model can be seen as a non-overlapping generations model in which each generation elects a government to provide public goods (here basic research) in order to maximize its well-being. The latter is equivalent to maximizing the consumption of the current generation. This, however, does not square with a social planner aiming at maximizing the utility of all generations. As we are only considering a single period, we omit the time index t. 4

7 Hence the intermediate firms are either monopolistic or fully competitive. A competitive intermediate firm sets prices equal to the marginal costs, p c (i) = w, and profits vanish. Using (2), the labor demand of a competitive intermediate firm can be written as where w denotes the wage level. L xc (i) = The monopolistic intermediate firm asks a price p m (i) = w α labor demand of and profits ( α w ) 1 1 α A(i), (4) for its goods, leading to a ( ) 1 α L xm 2 1 α (i) = A(i) (5) w π xm (i) = ma(i) w α 1 α ) (m := (1 α)α 1+α 1 α. (6) 3.3 Technological State, Innovation, and Foreign Entry We assume that there is a world technological frontier which at the end of the observed period is given by Ā and grows exogenously over time in accordance with Ā = γā 1, where Ā 1 denotes the technological frontier of the preceding period. 5 assume that 1 < γ 2. Further, we At the end of the preceding period, each intermediate firm can be of three types: Type 1 firms produce at the current technological frontier, A 1 (i) = Ā 1. Type 2 firms are one step behind the technological frontier, A 1 (i) = Ā 2. Type 3 firms are two steps behind the technological frontier, A 1 (i) = Ā 3. By investing in research and development, each intermediate firm can enhance its probability of realizing a successful innovation. A successful innovation increases the firm s technology level by a factor γ, thus allowing it to retain its relative position vis-à-vis the technological frontier. We specify the probability of type 1 and type 2 firms innovating successfully as ρ(i) = min { 2θ } L I (i)l B, 1, (7) 5 In general, the index j (j N) indicates how many periods back the indexed term is. 5

8 where θ > 0 is a parameter that captures the efficiency of research. L I (i) denotes the intermediate firm s labor employed for R&D and L B the amount of labor in the basic-research sector financed by the government. Throughout the paper, we will look at economies where we have an interior solution for all ρ(i). Note that basic research is a necessary input for innovation activities and constitutes a public good from which domestic intermediate firms that are technological leaders in their respective sector can benefit. Domestic intermediate firms lagging technologically have no incentive to invest in innovation, as such an investment would not enable them to get ahead of their rivals and earn profits. Like Aghion et al. (2006), we neglect the adoption costs of mature technologies, i.e. technologies two steps behind the world s frontier, and consequently assume that a type 3 firm s technology is automatically upgraded. From a long term perspective, each intermediate sector is in one of three states at the beginning of the period considered: State 1 Type 1 leader holding a monopoly State 2 Type 2 leader holding a monopoly State 3 Two (or more) type 3 firms acting competitively We denote the fractions of the states by s 1 (state 1), s 2 (state 2), and s 3 (state 3), where s 1, s 2, s 3 0 and s 1 + s 2 + s 3 = 1. In each sector i not producing at the world s technological frontier, either because the domestic intermediate firm has failed to innovate or has been lagging behind previously, the probability of a foreign competitor entering the domestic market is σ. We assume that the foreign intermediate firm enters with frontier technology Ā and consequently takes over the whole market. 6 There are many empirical studies indicating for industrialized countries that foreign direct investment by leading-edge companies can transfer the best production techniques to the host countries (e.g. Baily and Gersbach 1995, Keller and Yeaple 2003 or Alfaro et al. 2006). In sectors where the domestic intermediate firm produces at the highest possible level, foreign competitors will stay outside 7, so this can only be the case in sectors where a type 1 leader innovates successfully. 6 This implies that there is a fourth state for the intermediate sectors, i.e. with a foreign type 1 leader holding a monopoly. For simplicity, we assume that at the beginning of the period considered no intermediate sector is in this state. Allowing for foreign firms from the outset would only lead to a downscaling of the effects and thus does not alter the results substantially. 7 This statement can be justified by small entry costs preventing the foreign firm from entering the market under perfect competition (see Aghion et al. 2006). 6

9 3.4 R&D Decisions of Intermediate Firms Given the state of their sector, the entry threat of foreign firms, and the level of basic research, the domestic intermediate firms maximize their expected profits with respect to the amount of labor employed in private R&D: State 1 leader {( max L I (i) ρ(i) m w α 1 α Ā + ( 1 ρ(i) ) (1 σ) m w α 1 α ) } Ā 1 wl I (i) The state 1 leader will retain the market and make profits if it innovates successfully or if it does not innovate and there is no entry. The maximization problem leads to the following labor demand: L I 1 = LB w 2 1 α Ā 2 1m 2 θ 2( γ (1 σ) ) 2. (8) This implies innovation probability and expected profits for the state 1 leader in accordance with State 2 leader ρ I 1 = 2 LB Ā w 1 1 mθ 2( γ (1 σ) ) (9) 1 α LB m π I 1 = w 1+α 1 α m 2 θ 2( γ (1 σ) )2Ā (1 σ) { max L I (i) ρ(i)(1 σ) m w α 1 α } Ā 1 wl I (i) w α 1 α Ā 1. (10) The state 2 leader will only make profits if it innovates successfully and there is no foreign entry. If it does not innovate, the type 3 rival will automatically catch up. The sector is then subject to perfect competition and the profits vanish. The solution to the problem yields L I 2 = LB w 2 1 α Ā 2 1m 2 θ 2 (1 σ) 2, (11) ρ I 2 = 2 LB Ā w 1 1 mθ 2 (1 σ), (12) 1 α π I 2 = LB w 1+α 1 α m 2 θ 2 (1 σ) 2 Ā 2 1. (13) All the remaining domestic firms will not invest in R&D as they have no prospects of making profits. 7

10 3.5 Equilibrium The economy comprises the market for the final consumption good with price unity, the labor market with wage rate w, and a continuum of intermediate-good markets with prices {p(i)} 1 i=0. It follows from section 3.2 that the market clearing conditions in the intermediate-good markets yield prices p m (i) = w in the monopolistic sectors and α p c (i) = w in the competitive ones. From (3), (4), and (5) we obtain the values for the supply of intermediate goods as x c (i) = ( α x m 2 (i) = w ( α w ) 1 1 α A(i) (14) ) 1 1 α A(i) (15) in the monopolistic intermediate sectors and the competitive intermediate sectors, respectively. In the labor market, labor L is supplied inelastically. Labor demand consists of the government s demand for basic researchers, the intermediate firm s demand for private R&D personnel, and the demand of workers for the production of the intermediate goods. Hence the labor market clears when L = L B L I (i) di L x (i) di. (16) As we know from section 3.3, the demand for R&D personnel depends on the state of the intermediate firms sector. Consequently, the first integral in equation (16) is given by 1 0 L I (i) di = s 1 L I 1 + s 2 L I 2. (17) Note that the total demand for private researchers is determined by the number of sectors characterized by domestic monopolies at the beginning of the period. By contrast, the demand for workers in intermediate-goods production depends on the sector s technological level after innovation activities and foreign entry have occurred. This reflects our assumption that foreign intermediate firms bring leading technology with them from abroad but produce the intermediate goods within the country. Accordingly, in order to determine the second integral in (16) we need to know how sector states evolve during the period. The following scheme displays the probabilities for levels of technology achieved by an intermediate sector. The illustration also shows the resulting 8

11 market structure in terms of the mode of competition and of whether intermediate firms are domestic or foreign. ρ I 1 : Ā, local, monopoly s 1 (1 ρ I 1 )σ : Ā, foreign, monopoly (1 ρ I 1 )(1 σ) : Ā 1, local, monopoly s 2 s 3 { σ : Ā, foreign, monopoly (1 σ)ρ I 2 : Ā 1, local, monopoly (1 ρ I 2 )(1 σ) : Ā 2, local, perfect competition σ : Ā, foreign, monopoly (1 σ) : Ā 2, local, perfect competition Consequently, the total intermediates demand for production workers is given by 1 0 L x (i) di = ( σ + s 1 (1 σ)ρ ) I 1 xm L (Ā)+ ( s1 (1 σ)(1 ρ I 1 ) + s 2 (1 σ)ρ ) I 2 L xm (Ā 1)+ (18) ( s2 (1 σ)(1 ρ I 2 ) + s 3 (1 σ) ) L xc (Ā 2). Inserting (17) and (18) into (16) we obtain the equilibrium wage level. In general, the equilibrium wage is not unique. By assuming α = 1 and L = 1, we can solve the 2 market clearing condition for basic-research labor as a function of wage w: with C = A = L B (w) = w 2 w 2 A w 4 + B + C B = (19) Ā 16γ 2 [ σγ 2 + (1 σ) ( s 1 γ + 4(s 2 + s 3 ) )] > 0 (20) Ā2 256γ 2 θ2 [s 1 (γ 1 + σ) 2 + s 2 (1 σ) 2 ] > 0 (21) Ā2 128γ 3 θ2 (1 σ)[s 1 γ(γ 1)(γ 1 + σ) + s 2 (γ 4)(1 σ)]. (22) As the number of researchers can never be negative, the equilibrium wage must be higher than A. Further, we slightly restrict our parameter space in accordance with the following assumption: Assumption 1 B + C > A 2. We are now in a position to state 9

12 Lemma 1 Under Assumption 1 there exists a unique solution to the government s problem. Proof : See Appendix A.1. From the equilibrium wage we obtain the equilibrium prices for intermediate goods from which the equilibrium quantities and the firms profits follow. To simplify notation, we will henceforth use w to denote the equilibrium wage associated with a particular level of basic research. 3.6 Government The government chooses the amount of basic-research labor L B required to maximize aggregate consumption c of the current generation. The expenditures wl B are financed by a tax τ [0, 1] on household income. Households earn wages and obtain profits from final-good and domestic intermediate-goods production. Consequently, the budget constraint for the government is wl B = τ(w L + s 1 π I 1 + s 2 π I 2 + π y ), (23) where π y denotes the profits of the final-good sector. 8 Aggregate consumption c equals total income after taxes: c = (1 τ) ( w L + s 1 π I 1 + s 2 π I 2 + π y). (24) With uniqueness of the equilibrium wage w for given L B, the government s problem can also be solved via the control w. We will take this path as it permits an explicit solution for L B as a function of w. Economically, this approach could be interpreted as a wage offer by the government for doing basic research in order to attract the corresponding (equilibrium) number of researchers. Inserting L B (w) from equation (19) and budget constraint (23) into (24), we obtain overall consumption solely as a function of the equilibrium wage level w: c(w) = w4 (2A + 2D + E) + w 2 (2B + 3C + F) + (B + C)(2D + E) A(C + F), (25) w(w 4 + B + C) 8 Note that the profits in the final-good sector amount to π y = (1 α)y. 10

13 with F = D = Ā 16γ s 1(1 σ) > 0 (26) E = Ā 16 σ > 0 (27) Ā2 32γ s 2(1 σ) 2 θ 2 3 > 0. (28) This is the objective function the government maximizes with respect to the wage w. Lemma 2 Under Assumption 1 there exists a unique maximum consumption level. Proof : See Appendix A.2. However, it is impossible to derive an analytical solution to the problem in its entire generality. Accordingly, we will first focus our analysis on two particular settings and then discuss the effects of basic research more generally on the basis of numerical simulations. 4 Effects of Basic Research Before turning to comparative statics, we now introduce the different direct and indirect effects of basic-research investment on aggregate consumption. 4.1 Direct Effects Recall that aggregate consumption is defined by (24) and consists of total income after taxes, which includes labor income and the profits of the type 1 firms, the type 2 firms, and the final-good sector. If the government decides to increase basic research L B, the direct effects on consumption are the following: Escape Entry Effect: State 1 leaders (type 1 firms) will avoid foreign entry and retain the domestic market if they innovate successfully to keep up with the technological frontier. As basic research facilitates innovation, it helps state 1 leaders to retain domestic profits, which increases the consumption of households as shareholders. 11

14 Monopoly Effect: State 2 leaders (type 2 firms) can only preserve their technological advantage and retain their monopoly position if they innovate successfully (and no foreign entry takes place). Otherwise they will lose their competitive edge as type 3 firms will catch up technologically. In this way, basic research helps state 2 leaders to make profits, which has a positive effect on consumption. However, the monopoly of the state 2 leaders lowers the profits of the competitive final-good sector caused by higher intermediate-goods prices. The second effect dominates as a result of the well-known monopoly distortion factor. The net effect is what we call the monopoly effect. Productivity Effect: Basic research increases the probability of successful innovation and thus enhances technology growth. Higher technology raises profits for both the intermediate firms and the final-good sector. Consequently this effect on consumption is positive. Wage Income Effect: Higher labor employment in the basic-research sector reduces the labor supply for the intermediate firms. Consequently the equilibrium wage increases, which leads to higher consumption. Direct Tax Effect: Enlarging the public sector implies a higher tax rate τ. lowers consumption. This 4.2 Indirect Effects Indirect effects of basic research on consumption arise from changes in the equilibrium wage rate. The higher wage caused by an increase of basic research influences the profits and the tax rate in the following way: Labor Price Effect: The higher price for labor increases the production and innovation costs of the intermediate firms and thus lowers their profits. This effect on consumption is negative. Intermediate Price Effect: As the production costs of the intermediate firms increase with the wage rate, the price of the intermediate goods will also rise. This leads to lower profits in the final-good sector with negative effects on consumption. 12

15 Indirect Tax Effect: A higher wage means that the costs for one unit of labor in public basic research are higher. Therefore the tax has to be increased, which lowers consumption. 4.3 Magnitude of Effects In general, the magnitude of the effects of basic research on domestic consumption depends on the values of the exogenous parameters. However, it is instructive to recall that the impact of basic research depends on the extent to which it is used, i.e. how much private research is done by the domestic intermediate firms. The total amount of private R&D depends on how many intermediate firms are investing in private research and the intensity with which they do so. The former is exogenous, whereas the latter is endogenously determined within the model. The exogenously given use of basic research depends on the country s industry structure, i.e. shares s 1, s 2, s 3. Suppose that in each kind of intermediate sector the firms display certain research intensities. Then the benefits of basic research will increase in the shares of sectors with high research intensities. However, the extent to which intermediate firms invest in private R&D is endogenously determined in the model. A type 1 firm will still retain a monopoly position without innovation, whereas a type 2 firm would lose all its profits if it fails to innovate. Hence, innovation incentives in a closed economy are higher for a type 2 firm than for a type 1 firm. This changes with higher degrees of openness, as for a type 1 firm the probability of retaining a monopoly position without innovating decreases as does the probability of retaining the monopoly with innovation for type 2 firms. Hence, the innovation incentive for type 1 firms increases with the degree of openness, whereas that of the type 2 firms decreases. These effects are similar to the escape entry effects identified in Aghion et al. (2006). 5 Comparative Statics 5.1 Corner Scenarios First, we take a look at the corner scenarios. This will enable us to derive analytical results. We start by analyzing how the government should behave in an economy that 13

16 only has technologically advanced intermediate firms (s 1 = 1), followed by the analysis of an economy that only has technologically backward intermediate firms (s 2 = 1). The scenario s 3 = 1 is of no interest, as we already know that in this state firms will not invest in R&D and consequently the government has no incentive to invest in basic research at all Technologically Advanced Country: s 1 = 1 The equations (19) and (25) remain the same, while (20)-(26), (27), and (28) simplify to C = A = B = Ā [σγ + (1 σ)] 16γ > 0 (29) Ā2 256γ 2 θ2 (γ 1 + σ) 2 > 0 (30) Ā2 128γ 2 θ2 (1 σ)(γ 1)(γ 1 + σ) > 0 (31) D = Ā (1 σ) 16γ > 0 (32) E = Ā 16 σ > 0 (33) F = 0. (34) We thus obtain Lemma 3 (i) L B (w), defined by (19), starts at zero for w = 0. It then declines and becomes zero again at the wage level denoted by w zero = A. In the range w > w zero it is positive and strictly increasing. It finally converges to L = 1 for w. (ii) For w w zero, c(w) is either always decreasing and converging to zero or it increases first, reaches a unique maximum, and then monotonically declines and converges to zero for w. Proof : (i) follows directly from equations (19) and (29)-(31). For the proof of (ii) see Appendix A.3. It is clear from Lemma 3 (i) that for an eligible equilibrium w w zero must hold. This accords with economic intuition, as w zero is the equilibrium wage level resulting when the government does not intervene in the economy, i.e. when it does not invest in basic 14

17 research. Only if the government offers a higher wage than w zero can it attract labor for basic research. Lemma 3 also illustrates that, in principle, the government can achieve any value L B < L = 1 by offering a wage rate that is high enough. Of course, a level of basic research arbitrarily close to L cannot be optimal. This follows directly from the decreasing marginal product of basic research and the production function of final goods satisfying the Inada conditions. Intuitively, as the high governmental wage will draw labor from production, the marginal increase in technology will not compensate for the marginal loss in the production of intermediates, and consequently final output will decline. Proposition 1 (i) The government s maximization problem has a unique solution w. w > w zero implies a positive level of optimal basic research, L B > 0. (ii) For all parameter values there exists a θ crit such that for θ crit θ < θ max a positive amount of optimal basic research L B results. θ max denotes the value of the research productivity coefficient that leads to ρ I 1 = 1. Proof : (i) follows directly from Lemma 3; (ii) see Appendix A.4. In general, two characteristics of a country whose intermediate sectors are all of the state 1 variety favor basic research investments. First, as state 1 leaders will still retain a monopoly position even if they do not innovate (as long as there is no foreign entry), the negative implications of the monopoly effect on total consumption are absent. Second, the magnitude of the escape entry effect will reach its maximum, as basic research only enables s 1 firms to escape foreign competition. However, it is still possible that the negative effects described in section 4 will dominate, so that it would be favorable for the government to abstain from basic-research investments. From Proposition 1, this may occur when research productivity as reflected by θ is sufficiently low. 15

18 5.1.2 Technologically Backward Country: s 2 = 1 For s 2 = 1, the terms (20)-(26), (27), and (28) take the form Lemma 4 A = C = Ā 16γ 2 [ σγ 2 + 4(1 σ) ] > 0 (35) B = Ā2 256γ 2 θ2 (1 σ) 2 > 0 (36) Ā2 128γ 3 θ2 (γ 4)(1 σ) 2 < 0 (37) F = (i) L B (w), defined by (19), always increases in w. D = 0 (38) E = Ā 16 σ > 0 (39) Ā2 32γ (1 3 σ)2 θ 2 > 0. (40) (ii) c(w), defined by (25), always falls in w in the relevant space w > w zero. Proof : (i) see proof of Lemma 1; (ii) see Appendix (A.5). The curvature of the functions L B (w) and c(w) indicate that for all L B the negative effects of basic research on consumption will dominate. Proposition 2 The government does not invest in basic research. Proof : Follows directly from Lemma 4. In contrast to the scenario where s 1 = 1, the positive escape entry effect does not exist when s 2 = 1. The domestic intermediate firms cannot avoid the entry of the foreign firms by innovating successfully, as they are too far away from the technological frontier. Further, the monopoly effect is maximal because the government could remove all monopoly distortions by forgoing basic research. Hence, the government s incentives to invest in basic research tend to be low. Thus we can state: Proposition 3 L B (w ) s1 =1 L B (w ) s2 =1 Proof : Follows directly from Propositions 1 and 2. 16

19 According to Proposition 3, technologically advanced countries should always spend at least as much on basic research as technologically backward countries. More precisely, when comparing an economy characterized by s 1 = 1 with another characterized by s 2 = 1, only the advanced country is likely to conduct basic research. This result follows the intuition given with respect to Propositions 1 and 2. That is, in an economy where s 1 = 1, the negative monopoly effect of basic research on consumption has no effect. On the other hand, in the s 2 = 1 scenario the positive escape entry effect is irrelevant. Hence, basic research affects consumption more positively in the s 1 = 1 scenario than in the s 2 = 1 scenario. 5.2 Numerical Simulations In this section we leave the corner scenarios to look at the comparative statics of more general settings that cannot be solved analytically. 9 Therefore we will use numerical simulations as the basis for the following discussion. The basic parametrization of the model will be: Ā = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, σ = 0.7, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0. We will then derive our comparative statics results by varying one parameter while holding the others fixed. This enables us to isolate the effects of different parameters on optimal basic-research expenditures. Our simulations indicate that these are valid for large parameter sets and are not specific to our parametrization. We will also address special cases Distance from Technological Frontier We first consider the effect of a country s distance from the world s technological frontier on the optimal amount of basic research. The technological level of the economy varies across sectors and is thus characterized by the country s industry structure as reflected by the parameters s 1, s 2, and s 3. Since the shares of the different sector-types must add up to 1 the most, we will always vary the share of one sector type at the expense of the share of exactly one other sector type. In particular, we will discuss the following three cases: s 1 vs. s 2, s 1 vs. s 3, and s 2 vs. s 3. 9 The optimal wage w is given by the derivative of equation (25), which is a polynomial of degree eight. 17

20 L B s 1 Figure 1: Effect of Distance from Frontier: s 1 vs. s 2 (Ā σ = 0.7, s 2 = 1 s 1, s 3 = 0) = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, s 1 vs. s 2 This case generalizes the corner scenarios in the preceding section. Accordingly, we would expect the escape entry effect to monotonically increase in s 1, starting out from zero at s 1 = 0 and reaching its maximum at s 1 = 1. By contrast, the monopoly effect should decrease from its maximum value at s 1 = 0 to zero at s 1 = 1. Hence, optimal basic-research investment would increase in the share of technologically advanced sectors. As can be seen in Figure 1, the results are consistent with the intuition. Robustness checks show that this result holds for a wide range of parameters. However, when openness σ is low, we may have the case where the optimal amount of basic research first increases in s 1 and then falls later on. When σ is low, the escape entry effect is smaller, and the remaining effects have relatively more weight. The costs of basic research increase in s 1 as type 1 firms have a higher demand for workers than type 2 firms due to their higher technological level and this leads to a wage increase. Where the escape entry effect is small due to a low degree of openness, the negative effect described becomes dominant for a high share of state 1 sectors. This induces the government to lower basic research when s 1 increases. 18

21 L B s 1 Figure 2: Effect of Distance from Frontier: s 1 vs. s 3 (Ā σ = 0.7, s 2 = 0, s 3 = 1 s 1 ) = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, s 1 vs. s 3 The way in which the optimal amount of basic research is affected by a rise of s 1 coupled with a decline of s 3 is shown in Figure 2. Optimal basic-research investments increase in proportion with the share of state-1 sectors. The intuition is clear. The government has no incentive to invest in basic research to support the intermediate firms in state 3, because they will never invest in R&D. However, as we already know, there are positive incentives to provide basic research for state 1 leaders. Nonetheless, robustness checks have shown that, as in the s 1 vs. s 2 analysis, when σ is low, optimal basic research may first increase with s 1, reach a maximum, and then fall. Again, the escape entry effect is small, and the costs of basic research, i.e. the wage rate increase in s 1, will assume a dominant role at some point. The reason is that the state 1 leaders demand for labor in production and innovation for a given L B is higher than the labor employment of intermediate firms in state 3. Hence, the larger the share s 1 is, the higher the wage and consequently the costs of basic research will be. s 2 vs. s 3 Figure 3 shows that an increase of s 2 at the expense of s 3 has a positive effect on the optimal amount of labor for basic research. Simulations across all parametrical 19

22 L B s Figure 3: Effect of Distance from Frontier: s 2 vs. s 3 (Ā σ = 0.7, s 1 = 0.8, s 3 = 0.2 s 2 ) = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, values confirm this result. Intermediate firms in state 3 are automatically upgraded in technological terms and thus do not need support from basic research. This explains the pattern in figure 3. Summary According to the analysis of these three distinct cases, the broad picture is that the closer a country is to the technological frontier, the more the government should invest in basic research. There are exceptions however, in particular when openness is small and research productivity is very high Openness We next consider how variations in the degree of openness affects optimal basic research. The influence of openness on optimal basic research is ambiguous, as shown by the comparison of Figures 4 and 5. If we choose a lower innovation size γ as in Figure 4, we have a positive relationship between optimal basic research and openness. An increase of innovation size will cause the effect to go in the opposite direction, as illustrated by Figure 5. What explanation is there for this result? The direction of the openness effect depends on the weight of the productivity effect relative to the escape entry effect. The latter is larger the more open a country is, because the threat of losing domestic profits increases. By contrast, the productivity 20

23 L B Σ Figure 4: Effect of Openness (Ā = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) L B Σ Figure 5: Effect of Openness (Ā = 100, γ = 1.5, θ = 2.5, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) effect decreases with openness, as foreign intermediate firms transfer leading technology to the domestic country. Consequently, the government has less incentive to invest in basic research and hence in technological progress itself. As the innovation size γ scales the productivity effect, the escape entry effect dominates when γ is low, so that optimal basic-research expenditures increase with the country s degree of openness. Vice versa, a large innovation size implies that the productivity effect plays the more important role and optimal basic-research investments will decline with openness. Note that the escape entry effect is still present, but due to the higher magnitude of the productivity effect, optimal basic-research investments are in general higher with larger values of γ. With σ = 1 when the productivity effect reaches its minimum, optimal basic-research 21

24 L B Γ Figure 6: Effect of Innovation Size (Ā = 100, θ = 2.5, σ = 0.7, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) expenditures are, in principle, independent of the innovation size. Robustness checks support this result for all parameter values. However, we note that the presence of a certain number of state 1 sectors is needed to obtain a positive relationship between openness and basic research. The reason is that the magnitude of the escape entry effect depends positively on the share of state 1 sectors. This is clear, as only type 1 firms can compete with foreign intermediate firms. Additionally, with an increasing degree of openness, private research intensity also increases in state-1 sectors Innovation Size In this section we examine how the size of innovation γ influences optimal basic research. As expected and depicted in Figure 6, the higher the innovation size is, the more labor a government should employ for basic research. This is obvious, as basic research fosters innovation and so a higher innovation size will improve the efficiency of basic research. In other words, a larger innovation size implies a larger productivity effect. Our result is confirmed by simulations across all parametrical values. 22

25 L B Θ Figure 7: Effect of Research Productivity (Ā = 100, γ = 1.3, σ = 0.7, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) Research Productivity We can alter the productivity of both company research and basic research by modifying θ. The higher θ is, the more probable a successful innovation becomes, so research productivity is higher. It is straightforward to show that the optimal amount of basic research increases with research productivity, as can be seen in Figure 7. Higher research productivity mainly increases the escape entry effect and the productivity effect. 6 Discussion of the Results 6.1 Empirical Patterns The two main implications of the preceding comparative statics analysis are the following: First, the higher the share of technologically advanced sectors in a country is, the more the government should invest in basic research. Second, the relationship between openness and the optimal amount of basic research is ambiguous. If innovation sizes are low, open countries should invest more in basic research in order to compete with foreign intermediate firms. By contrast, if innovation sizes are large and the productivity effect dominates accordingly a country s policy might be to undertake less basic research the more open it is. 10 This effect is similar to the escape entry effect identified in Aghion et al. (2006). 23

26 Figure 8: Relationship between Basic Research and Productivity How do our results square with empirical patterns of basic research? In Figure 8 the relationship between basic research and productivity is shown based on country data. We observe that the technological level and basic-research expenditures are positively associated. 11 There is further empirical evidence supporting the positive relationship between economic development and basic research (e.g. Cole and Phelan (1999) and Schofer (2004)). Figure 9 presents the data on openness and basic research. To quantify openness we construct an exposure index that measures to which degree domestic industries are exposed to foreign competition. The exposure index consists of the variables trade (percent of GDP), FDI flows (percent of GDP), FDI stocks (percent of GDP), hidden import barriers, mean tariff rate and taxes on international trade (percent of current revenue). 12 In figure 9 we consider only advanced countries, as the numerical simulations of section 5.2 indicate that positive basic-research investments require a certain proportion of technologically advanced sectors. The data indicate no clear correlation 11 A more detailed empirical study that goes beyond a simple correlation would be desirable, but this is impeded by data availability. 12 A broader economic globalization index is given in Dreher (2006) that takes into account international economic linkages beyond foreign competition. We refer to this work for a detailed description of the data sources and on how the variables are normalized. Dreher uses a principal components analysis to determine the weights of the variables. As equal weights produce approximately the same results, we choose the simple weighting scheme. 24

27 Figure 9: Relationship between Basic Research and Openness between a country s degree of openness and its basic-research expenditures. 13 Taking the total factor productivity as a proxy for the total share of advanced sectors in the economy, the two figures 8 and 9 can be interpreted in different ways, as we exemplify for France and Ireland. Consider the two countries France (FRA) and Ireland (IRL), which have about the same productivity but different levels of basic-research expenditures. Hence, we could explain the France/Ireland case as a negative relationship between basic research and openness. With Ireland being more open, it would invest less in basic research than France. The France/Ireland case might also be consistent with a positive association between basic research and openness when we take into account the role of foreign direct investment. Ireland s policy over the last decades has been characterized by abandoning trade barriers and attracting foreign direct investment, which has helped to increase its total factor productivity considerably. Accordingly, the share of domestic high technology firms is substantially lower than in France as many leading sectors are populated by foreign firms. 14 Ireland may invest less in basic research for this reason despite be- 13 An equivalent figure for the less developed countries leads to the same conclusion. Again, these results are only an initial impulse and should be considered with care. 14 FDI data can be found in UNCTAD (2007) and World Bank (2007). 25

28 L B L B c c Σ 7.5 Figure 10: Effect of Openness on Consumption and Optimal Basic Research (Ā = 100, γ = 1.3, θ = 2.5, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) ing more open. Which of these explanations is more accurate is left to detailed future empirical research. 6.2 Joint Policies: Openness and Basic Research Are we able to say anything about optimal policies with respect to both basic research and openness from our previous examinations? Extending Figure 4 by including the graph of domestic consumption yields Figure 10. It shows a decrease of consumption with openness. Hence, the government s optimal policy is to set σ = 0 and not to invest in basic research in such a setting. On the one hand, low innovation size makes basic research less beneficial, and on the other, foreign firms do not greatly advance the technological level but take the profits away from some domestic firms. As illustrated by Figure 11, if the innovation size is high, the government should open the borders to allow foreign firms to enter the market and bring in high technology. However, it should still invest in basic research, as is clear if we bear in mind that optimal basic-research expenditures with a high innovation size are always above those with a low innovation size. As a hypothesis we can state that if the productivity effect dominates over the escape entry effect, the government should choose a high degree of openness and simultane- 26

29 L B L B c 0.08 c Σ 7.4 Figure 11: Effect of Openness on Consumption and Optimal Basic Research (Ā = 100, γ = 1.9, θ = 2.5, s 1 = 0.8, s 2 = 0.2, s 3 = 0) ously a relatively low level of basic-research investments. In the opposite case, if the escape entry effect plays the central role, borders should be closed and basic-research expenditures should be very low or even zero. 7 Conclusion In this paper, we have augmented the Schumpeterian growth model of Aghion et al. (2006) with a public basic-research sector which allows to determine how much a country should invest in basic research depending on its technological level and its openness to the world market. Our model opens up a variety of avenues for future research. For instance, it might be useful to endogenize the behavior of foreign countries and to examine the problem of choosing basic research from a global perspective. It may also be interesting, and by no means trivial, to establish the dynamics of our model and to examine a social planner s solution for basic-research investment across many generations. 27

30 A Proofs A.1 Proof of Lemma 1 We show that the function L B (w) strictly increases in w, hence the inverse function exists. As L B < 0 is not feasible, wages lower than A are not possible in equilibrium. Rewriting equation (19) as L B (w) = 1 A w B+C w 4 (41) reveals that L B will be zero for w = w zero = A and converges to 1 for w. No equilibrium exists for w < A. For w w zero, it is convenient to replace w by xa, where x 1. We obtain L B (x) = 1 1 x 1 + B+C x 2 A 2. (42) We now need to show that L B (x) is strictly increasing in x, i.e. that L B (x) x = 1 B+C ( ) x 1 + B+C 2 x 2 A + 2 x 1 2 x x 3 A ( ) B+C 2 > 0. (43) x 2 A 2 This condition can be rewritten as 1 B + C x 2 A 2 + 2B + C xa 2 > 0. (44) If B + C > 0, we can estimate the left-hand side from below by multiplying the last term with 1. This gives us x 1 which is obviously satisfied. + B + C x 2 A 2 > 0, We now consider the case where B + C < 0. As the left hand side of (44) is increasing in x, we know that if condition (44) is satisfied for x = 1, it will also be satisfied for x > 1. Inserting x = 1, we obtain This holds under Assumption 1, i.e. if B + C > A B + C A 2 > 0. (45) 28

Online Supplementary Material

Online Supplementary Material Online Supplementary Material The Supplementary Material includes 1. An alternative investment goal for fiscal capacity. 2. The relaxation of the monopoly assumption in favor of an oligopoly market. 3.

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization 2.1. Introduction Suppose that an economic relationship can be described by a real-valued

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade 19. Transfer Prices A. The Transfer Price Problem A.1 What is a Transfer Price? 19.1 When there is a international transaction between say two divisions of a multinational enterprise that has establishments

More information

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Wyatt Brooks University of Notre Dame Pau Pujolas McMaster University February, 2015 Abstract In this paper we use production and trade data to measure gains from

More information

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself

More information

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Filipe R. Campante Davin Chor July 200 Abstract In this online appendix, we present the proofs for

More information

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1 1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1 To be included in: Elmar Wolfstetter. Topics in Microeconomics: Industrial Organization, Auctions, and Incentives. Cambridge University Press, new edition,

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE I. Alternatives to Comparative Advantage Economies of Scale The fact that the largest share of world trade consists of the exchange of similar (manufactured) goods between

More information

14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 2, 2014. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 11 December 2, 2014. 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing. Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of International Consumption Risk Sharing. Ergys Islamaj June 2014 Abstract This paper investigates how output volatility and productivity correlations

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC MARKET STRUCTURE AND INSIDER TRADING WASSIM DAHER AND LEONARD J. MIRMAN Abstract. In this paper we examine the real and financial effects of two insiders trading in a static Jain Mirman model (Henceforth

More information

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix De Loecker Jan - Warzynski Frederic Princeton University, NBER and CEPR - Aarhus School of Business Forthcoming American Economic Review Abstract This is

More information

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions We saw in the text that utility functions and indifference curves are different ways to represent a consumer s preferences. Calculus can

More information

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS Sensitivity Analysis 3 We have already been introduced to sensitivity analysis in Chapter via the geometry of a simple example. We saw that the values of the decision variables and those of the slack and

More information

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets Chapter 6 Competitive Markets After reading Chapter 6, COMPETITIVE MARKETS, you should be able to: List and explain the characteristics of Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition Explain why a

More information

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position Chapter 27: Taxation 27.1: Introduction We consider the effect of taxation on some good on the market for that good. We ask the questions: who pays the tax? what effect does it have on the equilibrium

More information

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth Tom-Reiel Heggedal Economics Department 2014 TRH (Institute) Solow model 2014 1 / 27 Theory and models Objective of this lecture: learn Solow

More information

Lecture Notes on Elasticity of Substitution

Lecture Notes on Elasticity of Substitution Lecture Notes on Elasticity of Substitution Ted Bergstrom, UCSB Economics 210A March 3, 2011 Today s featured guest is the elasticity of substitution. Elasticity of a function of a single variable Before

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe

The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe Olivier Blanchard October 2001 Let me start by sketching a toy model of immigration. Think of all the capital as being in the West (Western Europe).

More information

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market TOPIC 2: The Goods Market Annaïg Morin CBS - Department of Economics August 2013 Goods market Road map: 1. Demand for goods 1.1. Components 1.1.1. Consumption 1.1.2. Investment 1.1.3. Government spending

More information

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Daniel McFadden Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley April 8, 2002 I. This note is concerned with the economics of

More information

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality ROBERTO ROSON Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Venice, Italy. Abstract I review two papers, addressing the issue of

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Description of the model. This is a special case of a Mirrlees model.

More information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information by Sanford Grossman This model shows how the heterogeneous information

More information

Macroeconomic impact of Pannonia Ethanol in Hungary

Macroeconomic impact of Pannonia Ethanol in Hungary Macroeconomic impact of Pannonia Ethanol in Hungary Simulation results from a calibrated CGE model Written for Pannonia Ethanol Zrt. Author: Major, Klára Budapest 2016.03.30. For Applicable Knowledge HÉTFA

More information

Competition and Regulation. Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition

Competition and Regulation. Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition Competition and Regulation Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition Monopoly A monopolist maximizes its profits, choosing simultaneously quantity and prices, taking the Demand as a contraint; The

More information

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg Outline Alternative Market Models Wirtschaftswissenschaften Humboldt Universität zu Berlin March 5, 2006 Outline 1 Introduction Introduction Alternative Market Models 2 Game, Reaction Functions, Solution

More information

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation Jon Bakija This example shows how to use a budget constraint and indifference curve diagram

More information

MEASURING A NATION S INCOME

MEASURING A NATION S INCOME 10 MEASURING A NATION S INCOME WHAT S NEW IN THE FIFTH EDITION: There is more clarification on the GDP deflator. The Case Study on Who Wins at the Olympics? is now an FYI box. LEARNING OBJECTIVES: By the

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

tariff versus quota Equivalence and its breakdown

tariff versus quota Equivalence and its breakdown Q000013 Bhagwati (1965) first demonstrated that if perfect competition prevails in all markets, a tariff and import quota are equivalent in the sense that an explicit tariff reproduces an import level

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline I. Learning Objectives In this chapter students will learn: A. The significance of resource pricing. B. How the marginal revenue productivity of a resource relates to a firm s demand for that resource.

More information

Income and the demand for complementary health insurance in France. Bidénam Kambia-Chopin, Michel Grignon (McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario)

Income and the demand for complementary health insurance in France. Bidénam Kambia-Chopin, Michel Grignon (McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario) Income and the demand for complementary health insurance in France Bidénam Kambia-Chopin, Michel Grignon (McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario) Presentation Workshop IRDES, June 24-25 2010 The 2010 IRDES

More information

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY EXERCISE 1 Firstly, we analyze the equilibrium under the monopoly. The monopolist chooses the quantity that maximizes its profits; in particular, chooses the

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

PART I: A STANDARD ANALYSIS OF FACTOR MOBILITY

PART I: A STANDARD ANALYSIS OF FACTOR MOBILITY 1 PART I: A STANDARD ANALYSIS OF FACTOR MOBILITY CHAPTER 1: BENEFICIAL vs. DISTORTIONARY MOBILITY OF FACTORS OF PRODUCTION Introduction Classical economic setups suggest that factors of production move,

More information

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 11 FISCAL POLICY* Key Concepts The Federal Budget The federal budget is an annual statement of the government s expenditures and tax revenues. Using the federal budget to achieve macroeconomic

More information

Do R&D or Capital Expenditures Impact Wage Inequality? Evidence from the IT Industry in Taiwan ROC

Do R&D or Capital Expenditures Impact Wage Inequality? Evidence from the IT Industry in Taiwan ROC Lai, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 6(1), June 2013, 48-53 48 Do R&D or Capital Expenditures Impact Wage Inequality? Evidence from the IT Industry in Taiwan ROC Yu-Cheng Lai * Shih

More information

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade Michele Connolly Duke University and Diego Valderrama Federal Reserve

More information

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Professor Ralph Ossa 33501 International Commercial Policy Introduction Remember that countries trade either because they are different from one another or

More information

MONOPOLIES HOW ARE MONOPOLIES ACHIEVED?

MONOPOLIES HOW ARE MONOPOLIES ACHIEVED? Monopoly 18 The public, policy-makers, and economists are concerned with the power that monopoly industries have. In this chapter I discuss how monopolies behave and the case against monopolies. The case

More information

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost: Chapter 9 Lecture Notes 1 Economics 35: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes and Sample Questions Chapter 9: Profit Maximization Profit Maximization The basic assumption here is that firms are profit maximizing.

More information

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February 2013. Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February 2013. Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32 Advertising Sotiris Georganas February 2013 Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Main questions about advertising 3 How does advertising work? 4 Persuasive advertising

More information

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet) DEREE COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS EC 1101 PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS II FALL SEMESTER 2002 M-W-F 13:00-13:50 Dr. Andreas Kontoleon Office hours: Contact: a.kontoleon@ucl.ac.uk Wednesdays 15:00-17:00 Study

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 9-1 Explain what relationships are shown by (a) the consumption schedule, (b) the saving schedule, (c) the investment-demand curve, and (d) the investment schedule.

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Product Mix as a Framing Exercise: The Role of Cost Allocation. Anil Arya The Ohio State University. Jonathan Glover Carnegie Mellon University

Product Mix as a Framing Exercise: The Role of Cost Allocation. Anil Arya The Ohio State University. Jonathan Glover Carnegie Mellon University Product Mix as a Framing Exercise: The Role of Cost Allocation Anil Arya The Ohio State University Jonathan Glover Carnegie Mellon University Richard Young The Ohio State University December 1999 Product

More information

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005 Page 1 of 10 November 3, 2005 Answer in blue book. Use the point values as a guide to how extensively you should answer each question, and budget your time accordingly. 1. (8 points) A friend, upon learning

More information

3. Reaction Diffusion Equations Consider the following ODE model for population growth

3. Reaction Diffusion Equations Consider the following ODE model for population growth 3. Reaction Diffusion Equations Consider the following ODE model for population growth u t a u t u t, u 0 u 0 where u t denotes the population size at time t, and a u plays the role of the population dependent

More information

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1 Homework #1 1. In 1900 GDP per capita in Japan (measured in 2000 dollars) was $1,433. In 2000 it was $26,375. (a) Calculate the growth rate of income per capita in Japan over this century. (b) Now suppose

More information

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run? Perfect Competition Questions Question 1 Suppose there is a perfectly competitive industry where all the firms are identical with identical cost curves. Furthermore, suppose that a representative firm

More information

2. THE ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF EDUCATION

2. THE ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF EDUCATION 2. THE ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF EDUCATION How much more do tertiary graduates earn? How does education affect employment rates? What are the incentives for people to invest in education? What are the incentives

More information

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds Internet Appendix for A Model of hadow Banking * At t = 0, a generic intermediary j solves the optimization problem: max ( D, I H, I L, H, L, TH, TL ) [R (I H + T H H ) + p H ( H T H )] + [E ω (π ω ) A

More information

R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand

R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand Georg Götz This draft: September 005. Abstract: This paper shows that R&D cooperation leads to the monopoly outcome in terms of price and quantity if demand is

More information

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization Dudley Cooke Trinity College Dublin Dudley Cooke (Trinity College Dublin) Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization 1 / 51 EC2040 Topic 3 - Multi-variable Calculus

More information

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy After reading Chapter 7, MONOPOLY, OLIGOPOLY AND STRATEGY, you should be able to: Define the characteristics of Monopoly and Oligopoly, and explain why the are

More information

A Static Version of The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation

A Static Version of The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation A tatic Version of The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation Matthias Doepke CLA Fabrizio Zilibotti niversity of Zurich October 2007 1 Introduction In Doepke and Zilibotti 2005) we present an analysis

More information

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers. 1. Which of the following would shift the demand curve for new textbooks to the right? a. A fall in the price of paper used in publishing texts. b. A fall in the price of equivalent used text books. c.

More information

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D) ECO 352 Spring 2010 No. 14 Mar. 25 OLIGOPOLY TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D) Example using numbers from Precept Week 7 slides, pp. 2, 3. Ingredients: Industry with inverse

More information

Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics

Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics The simple Keynesian model Tom-Reiel Heggedal BI August 2014 TRH (BI) Keynes model August 2014 1 / 19 Assumptions Keynes model Outline for this lecture: Go

More information

The Stewardship Role of Accounting

The Stewardship Role of Accounting The Stewardship Role of Accounting by Richard A. Young 1. Introduction One important role of accounting is in the valuation of an asset or firm. When markets are perfect one can value assets at their market

More information

Section 10.4 Vectors

Section 10.4 Vectors Section 10.4 Vectors A vector is represented by using a ray, or arrow, that starts at an initial point and ends at a terminal point. Your textbook will always use a bold letter to indicate a vector (such

More information

Effects of electricity price volatility and covariance on the firm s investment decisions and long-run demand for electricity

Effects of electricity price volatility and covariance on the firm s investment decisions and long-run demand for electricity Effects of electricity price volatility and covariance on the firm s investment decisions and long-run demand for electricity C. Brandon (cbrandon@andrew.cmu.edu) Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh,

More information

Competitive Screening in Credit Markets with Adverse Selection: A Cover Version of Bester s Model

Competitive Screening in Credit Markets with Adverse Selection: A Cover Version of Bester s Model Competitive Screening in Credit Markets with Adverse Selection: A Cover Version of Bester s Model Ran Spiegler April 18, 2013 Abstract This note presents a simple model of competitive screening in a credit

More information

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract Interconnection Agreement between Internet Service Providers and the Optimal Policy Intervention: The Case of Cournot-type Competition under Network Externalities Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku

More information

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE CHAPTER SUMMARY This chapter presents an economic analysis of market structure. It starts with perfect competition as a benchmark. Potential barriers to entry, that might limit

More information

On the relationship between defense and non-defense spending in the U.S. during the world wars

On the relationship between defense and non-defense spending in the U.S. during the world wars Economics Letters 95 (2007) 415 421 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase On the relationship between defense and non-defense spending in the U.S. during the world wars Roel M.W.J. Beetsma a,, Alex Cukierman

More information

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year. Answers To Chapter 2 Review Questions 1. Answer a. To be classified as in the labor force, an individual must be employed, actively seeking work, or waiting to be recalled from a layoff. However, those

More information

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers Sam C.M. Lee John C.S. Lui + Abstract The current Internet architecture comprises of different privately owned Internet service providers

More information

5. R&D based Economic Growth: Romer (1990)

5. R&D based Economic Growth: Romer (1990) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics I Lecture SS 13 5. R&D based Economic Growth: Romer (1990) Introduction The challenge of modeling technological change The structure of the model The long

More information

Unionized Oligopoly and Outsourcing

Unionized Oligopoly and Outsourcing 68 JCC Journal of CENTRUM Cathedra by Arsen Melkumian* Ph. D. in Economics, West Virginia University, USA Assistant Professor in Economics, Western Illinois University, USA Abstract The interaction between

More information

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? No. 11-1 Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? Geoffrey M.B. Tootell Abstract: This public policy brief examines the relationship between trend inflation and commodity price increases and

More information

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Employment and Pricing of Inputs Employment and Pricing of Inputs Previously we studied the factors that determine the output and price of goods. In chapters 16 and 17, we will focus on the factors that determine the employment level

More information

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity? Elasticity I. What is Elasticity? The purpose of this section is to develop some general rules about elasticity, which may them be applied to the four different specific types of elasticity discussed in

More information

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) (Refer Slide Time: 00:28) Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) We will continue our discussion

More information

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly?

More information

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Prep. Course Macroeconomics Prep. Course Macroeconomics Intertemporal consumption and saving decision; Ramsey model Tom-Reiel Heggedal tom-reiel.heggedal@bi.no BI 2014 Heggedal (BI) Savings & Ramsey 2014 1 / 30 Overview this lecture

More information

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits. Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits. Profit depends upon two factors Revenue Structure Cost Structure

More information

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS Due the Week of June 23 Chapter 8 WRITE [4] Use the demand schedule that follows to calculate total revenue and marginal revenue at each quantity. Plot

More information

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

1 Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig

1 Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig. Simplex Pivoting: Dictionary Format We illustrate a general solution procedure, called the simplex algorithm, by implementing it on a very simple example.

More information

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Credible iscovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Warren F. Schwartz Abraham L. Wickelgren Abstract: This paper introduces the option to conduct discovery into a model of settlement bargaining

More information

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Capital Structure Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Debt and Equity There are two main types of financing: debt and equity. Consider a two-period world with dates 0 and 1. At

More information

1 National Income and Product Accounts

1 National Income and Product Accounts Espen Henriksen econ249 UCSB 1 National Income and Product Accounts 11 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Can be measured in three different but equivalent ways: 1 Production Approach 2 Expenditure Approach

More information

The Difference Between Market and Barter: Money and the Making of Markets

The Difference Between Market and Barter: Money and the Making of Markets The Difference Between Market and Barter: 2 Money and the Making of Markets Market is in many respects distinct from barter. This distinction needs to be emphasized, because the conventional theory treats

More information

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg-Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni-essen.de 14th March 2005 Abstract

More information

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes. I. The Definition of Monopoly ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes. This definition is abstract, just

More information

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth Michael Bräuninger October 2002 Abstract This paper analyzes the effects of public debt on endogenous growth in an overlapping generations model. The

More information

A Dynamic Analysis of Price Determination Under Joint Profit Maximization in Bilateral Monopoly

A Dynamic Analysis of Price Determination Under Joint Profit Maximization in Bilateral Monopoly A Dynamic Analysis of Price Determination Under Joint Profit Maximization in Bilateral Monopoly by Stephen Devadoss Department of Agricultural Economics University of Idaho Moscow, Idaho 83844-2334 Phone:

More information

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market Intermediate Macroeconomics Lecture 4: Introduction to the Goods Market Review of the Aggregate Expenditures model and the Keynesian Cross ECON 302 Professor Yamin Ahmad Components of Aggregate Demand

More information

5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents

5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents Section 5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents 1 5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents We now review how exponents can be used to describe not only powers (such as 5 2 and 2 3 ), but also roots

More information