Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California"

Transcription

1 Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California August 2002 Revised March 2003 Prepared for the California HealthCare Foundation by Jonathan Gruber, Ph.D. Massachusetts Institute of Technology and National Bureau of Economic Research

2 Authors Jonathan Gruber, Ph.D., is Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and a Research Associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research, where he directs their Program on Children s Economic Issues. Opportunities for Further Analysis Professor Gruber is available, through support from the California HealthCare Foundation, to analyze tax credit proposals introduced during California s 2003 legislative session. For more information contact Marian Mulkey at or mmulkey@chcf.org. Copyright 2003 California HealthCare Foundation ISBN Additional copies of this and other publications can be obtained by calling the California HealthCare Foundation at (510) or by visiting the Web site ( The California HealthCare Foundation is an independent philanthropy committed to improving California s health care delivery and financing systems. Our mission is to expand access to affordable, quality health care for underserved individuals and communities and to promote fundamental improvements in the health status of the people of California. 476 Ninth Street Oakland, CA Tel: Fax:

3 Contents Executive Summary...1 I. Introduction...4 II. Behavioral Modeling...8 III. Estimates of the Impact of Tax Subsidies on Insurance Coverage and Costs...12 IV. Conclusions...27 Notes...28

4 Executive Summary The lack of insurance is a major problem in California. From 1987 through 1998, the number of non-elderly uninsured rose by 43 percent in California, and over 6 million Californians now have no health insurance. One option that is frequently considered for increasing the insurance rate in California is to introduce tax subsidies to private insurance purchase. Tax subsidy proposals come in a variety of forms. Some proposals, such as the one put forward by President George Bush and many leading national legislators, would offer tax credits for the purchase of insurance in the nongroup market only (that is, not from employers). Other proposals, such as those proposed in the past by Assembly Bills 432 and 1734 in California, would offer tax credits to businesses in order to expand employer-based insurance coverage. Still others have proposed bypassing firms and subsidizing employees directly for their share of the costs of employerprovided health insurance. But the tax subsidy approach is not without its flaws. Foremost among these is the potential for poor targeting and inefficient use of public dollars. When a new health insurance subsidy is offered to firms or individuals, that subsidy will immediately be taken by a large share of those who already have insurance; after all, this is essentially a bonus for that group. Moreover, takeup may be much lower among those uninsured who have chosen, in the absence of subsidies, not to purchase insurance. Thus, the net effect could be a very small reduction in the number of uninsured, despite potentially large budgetary costs. Several key issues must be confronted in developing a rigorous analysis of tax subsidy proposals: To what extent will the uninsured take up subsidized private coverage? To what extent will those who already have private coverage in the subsidized form (that is, those with nongroup coverage when a new nongroup insurance subsidy is introduced) take up the new subsidies? To what extent will those who have private insurance in unsubsidized forms (that is, group coverage when there is a new nongroup subsidy) drop that unsubsidized insurance and move to the subsidized form of insurance? Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 1

5 If subsidies flow to individuals outside the employer-provided insurance system, to what extent will employers reduce their own expenditures on insurance? Likewise, if subsidies flow to employer-provided insurance, to what extent will that promote new insurance offering among employers? This list is representative of issues to be confronted, but a policy analysis requires first developing a behavioral model that incorporates responses to these questions in order to map policy changes into net effects on insurance coverage and public sector costs. This report describes such a model, building on earlier work by this author on the cost and coverage implications of nongroup tax subsidies for the nation as a whole. 1 This research extends that modeling to consider the impacts of tax subsidies for the state of California, and to consider the unique features of the California population and labor market. Two other types of tax policies are also considered: (1) subsidies to employers to offer insurance, and (2) subsidies to employees to take up insurance coverage that they are offered. These alternatives have significant appeal because they have the potential to promote, rather than undermine, the group insurance market. This paper reports several central findings: First, none of the tax policies contemplated is a silver bullet that can solve the problem of lack of insurance in California. Even the most generous policies modeled below are estimated to newly cover, at most, 2 million new people, or only one-third of the uninsured in the state. Additionally, these policies are expensive, with costs ranging from $1.6 billion to almost $15 billion per year. The discussion focuses on one concept of efficiency: the cost to the state per person newly insured. Even the most efficient policies spend roughly $2,500 per person newly insured, but that efficiency varies tremendously, with costs ranging up to $8,300 per newly insured. Second, there is a tradeoff between scale and efficiency. As credits get larger, the reduction in the number of uninsured rises, but the costs to the state government rise even faster so that costs per newly insured increase. The extent of this tradeoff varies by type of tax credit, but it is true for every type of policy considered. Third, targeting is key to policy effectiveness. Credits that target those income groups less likely to be covered by health insurance and that target the types of firms less likely to offer insurance are much more effective than more loosely targeted credits. Moreover, tightly targeted policies can lead to attractive outcomes in terms of distribution. In this report, for example, options are considered whereby the government can target half or more of the spending to those below 200 percent of the poverty line, and relatively little of the spending in the policies considered below usually about one-quarter goes to those above 300 percent of the poverty line. Finally, different types of credits have very different effects. Credits to employers, intended to induce them to offer insurance are the most efficient means of increasing insurance coverage when tightly targeted to the firms that are least likely to offer insurance ex ante. Credits for nongroup insurance are less effective, largely due to the Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 2

6 high costs of insurance in the nongroup market. Credits for employee purchase of insurance are the least effective of all, particularly when they are very generous in terms of either the credit level or the income ranges made eligible. Since almost everyone who is offered insurance already takes it up, these credits are very poorly targeted. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 3

7 I. Introduction The lack of insurance is a serious social problem in the United States that continued to worsen even as the economy improved throughout the 1980s and the 1990s. In 1987, 14.8 percent of non-elderly Americans were without health insurance. Over the next decade, the non-elderly population without insurance coverage grew by nearly 25 percent, to an overall rate of 18 percent, before falling for the first time in two decades last year; however, despite this recent good news, approximately 40 million Americans remain without health insurance. In California, these trends have been even more dramatic. From 1987 through 1998, the number of non-elderly uninsured rose by 43 percent in California. Currently, over 6 million Californians lack health insurance. 2 This represents an enormous potential problem for the state, as it does for the nation as a whole. It has been well documented that lack of health insurance affects an individual s health status. There is a large body of work showing that poor health is also associated with lower earnings and lower participation in the labor market, implying economic costs associated with the lack of insurance as well. 3 Moreover, the fear of losing health insurance coverage has been shown to impede job mobility, a key to success for a dynamic economy such as California s. 4 Thus, there is reason to be concerned about the effects of lack of insurance, both on the health of California s population and on its economy. There are a variety of policy options proposed for addressing the problem of lack of insurance coverage in California and elsewhere. Broadly speaking, these options fall into three categories. 1. Insurance market regulation. Examples include ensuring access and renewability of insurance policies, and limiting the prices that can be charged to sick individuals. California has been at the forefront of state efforts to impose such regulations; however, to date, there has been little evidence that these types of regulatory interventions can make a major dent in the number of uninsured. 2. Public expansions of insurance coverage. There is a substantial body of evidence that suggests public expansions are an effective means of increasing insurance coverage and improving the health of low-income populations, 5 but public expansions are also quite expensive and involve the kind of direct increase in government spending that may prove Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 4

8 politically difficult when there are competing priorities as there obviously are in California, given the state s current fiscal difficulties. Among opponents of governmental growth, public expansions also raise concerns about increasing encroachment of the public sector on private insurance markets through the crowdout of the privately insured and their move into the public program. 3. Tax subsidies. This alternative is receiving increasing attention. Like public insurance expansions, tax subsidies for health insurance can address affordability problems that plague the uninsured. Unlike public expansions, tax subsidies can be presented as a potentially more palatable tax cut. Additionally, tax subsidies promote, rather than supplant, private insurance markets, which may account for their growing popularity. Tax subsidy proposals come in a variety of forms. Some proposals, like that put forward by President Bush and many leading national legislators, would offer tax credits for the purchase of insurance in the nongroup market only (that is, not from employers). Other proposals, such as those proposed in the past by Assembly Bills 432 and 1734 in California, would offer tax credits to businesses in order to expand employer-based insurance coverage. Others have proposed subsidizing employees, rather than firms, for the share of employer-provided health insurance costs that they bear. The tax subsidy approach is not without its flaws. Foremost among these is the potential for poor targeting and inefficient use of public dollars. Indeed, in their analysis of AB 1734, the Tax Franchise Board suggested that 94 percent of the dollars spent by this program would flow to those firms already offering health insurance. The rationale behind analyses such as this is quite straightforward. When a health insurance subsidy is offered to firms or individuals, that subsidy will immediately be taken by a large share of those who already have insurance; this is, after all, essentially a bonus for that group. Take-up may be much lower among those uninsured who have chosen, in the absence of subsidies, not to purchase insurance. The net result is a very small effect on the number of uninsured despite potentially large budgetary costs. This analysis points out the key issue for analyzing tax subsidy proposals: the behavioral response of individuals and firms to those subsidies. Consider, for example, proposals to subsidize the purchase of nongroup insurance (such as the current Bush plan). To credibly analyze the impact that such proposals would have on insurance coverage and public sector costs, one must consider, minimally, the following set of questions regarding potential behavioral responses: To what extent will the uninsured take up these subsidies? To what extent will those already holding nongroup insurance policies take up the new subsidies (since there is a host of evidence that, in fact, individuals do not always take advantage of these types of offers)? To what extent will those who are employer-insured find nongroup insurance more attractive when it is subsidized and thus drop their employer policies to take the subsidy? Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 5

9 To what extent will firms now find it less attractive to offer insurance, since there is a subsidized alternative, and stop offering insurance? And to what extent will the resulting dropped workers take advantage of this nongroup credit? To what extent will firms continue to offer insurance but reduce their share of the payment in order to induce their employees to take advantage of this nongroup insurance market subsidy? And to what extent will workers respond to these higher costs by dropping their employer coverage? This list is representative of some of the critical questions to be confronted in developing a rigorous policy analysis. Such an analysis will require first developing a behavioral model that incorporates responses to these questions in order to map policy changes into net effects on insurance coverage and public sector costs. This report describes such a model. It builds on the author s earlier work on the cost and coverage implications of nongroup tax subsidies for the nation as a whole, 6 but extends that work in two directions. First, it focuses on California in particular. As discussed below, differences between the structure of the labor market and the demographic characteristics of residents in California and elsewhere may generate quite different policy impacts in this state from those in the nation as a whole. Thus, for understanding the impacts of tax policies on California, it is critical to pursue California-specific modeling. Second, in addition to nongroup tax credits, two other types of tax policies are modeled: subsidies to employers to offer insurance, and subsidies to employees to take up insurance coverage they are offered. These alternatives have significant appeal because they have the potential to promote, rather than undermine, the group insurance market. This paper reports several central findings: First, none of the tax policies contemplated is a silver bullet that can solve the problem of insurance coverage for Californians. Even the most generous policies modeled below are estimated to newly cover, at most, 2 million new people, or only one-third of the uninsured in the state. These policies are expensive, with costs ranging from $1.6 billion to almost $15 billion per year. The following discussion focuses on one concept of efficiency, that is, the cost to the state per person newly insured. Even the most efficient policies spend roughly $2,500 per person newly insured, but that efficiency varies tremendously, with costs ranging up to $8,300 per newly insured. Second, there is a tradeoff between scale and efficiency. As credits get larger, the reduction in the number of uninsured rises, but the costs to the state government rise even faster so that costs per newly insured increase. The extent of this tradeoff varies by type of tax credit, but it is true for every type of policy considered. Third, targeting is key to policy effectiveness. Targeting credits to the income groups that are less likely to be covered by health insurance and targeting to the types of firms that are less likely to offer insurance are much more effective policies than more loosely targeted credits. Moreover, tightly targeted policies can lead to attractive outcomes in terms of distribution. In this report, for example, options are considered whereby the Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 6

10 government can target half or more of the spending to those below 200 percent of the poverty line, and relatively little of the spending in the policies considered below usually about one-quarter goes to those above 300 percent of the poverty line. Finally, different types of credits have very different effects. When tightly targeted to the firms that are least likely to offer insurance ex ante, credits to employers to induce them to offer insurance are the most efficient means of increasing insurance coverage. Credits for nongroup insurance are less effective, largely due to the high costs of insurance in the nongroup market. Credits for employee purchase of insurance are the least effective of all. This is particularly true when they are very generous in terms of either the credit level or the income ranges made eligible. These credits are poorly targeted in that almost everyone who is offered insurance already takes it up. This report is organized into three chapters. Chapter 2 provides an overview of the behavioral model used to analyze tax policies for California. It highlights some of the author s previous behavioral health economics research, which is central to developing the current behavioral model. Chapter 3 presents an analysis of the alternative tax policies, comparing the effects in California to the effects in the nation as a whole and contrasting alternative tax policy approaches. Chapter 4 concludes by summarizing the key results of this analysis. For a broader discussion, including related issues such as institutional barriers that might prevent consumers from obtaining health coverage even if tax credits spurred them to seek it, see the companion report by Gruber and Karl Polzer, titled Assessing the Impact of State Tax Credits for Health Insurance Coverage. 7 Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 7

11 II. Behavioral Modeling The Underlying Model The results reported here are based on a detailed micro-simulation model developed over the past several years. 8 This model uses, as its base, microdata on a nationally representative sample of individuals from the Current Population Surveys (CPS) for February and March The February survey provides information on employer insurance offering, while the March survey gives information on insurance coverage from all sources, income levels, firm characteristics, self-assessed health status, and demographics. Additionally, in recent years, the March CPS has also provided a detailed calculation of taxable income and tax rates for each family in the sample. The CPS information is supplemented by data from the Kaiser-HRET (2001) employer health insurance survey, 9 which provides information by region and firm size on employer premiums, employee premium shares, and whether employee premiums are made on a pretax basis. Additional information was gathered from data from the Community Tracking Survey, as well as quotes from nongroup insurers on the costs of nongroup insurance policies. The model is updated to 2003 dollars. These data are used to simulate the impact of alternative tax policies on insurance coverage. This involves assessing how the policies affect individuals and employers in different circumstances (based on such factors as their insurance status, income, and tax rate) and how those individuals and employers respond. These behavioral responses include, but are not limited to: The extent to which the currently uninsured will purchase newly subsidized insurance coverage, and how that varies by whether or not those uninsured are currently offered health insurance. The extent to which those with existing insurance coverage will take up the bonus of subsidies to their insurance spending (either nongroup insured taking up nongroup subsidies, firms that offer insurance taking up subsidies to employers, or employees who are insured taking up subsidies to employees). Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 8

12 The extent to which those with one type of existing insurance will switch to another type when it is subsidized (for example, how many of the employer-insured will switch to nongroup insurance when it is subsidized). The extent to which firms that do not currently offer insurance will begin to do so in response to subsidies to employer-provided insurance, and the extent to which firms that do currently offer insurance will stop offering that insurance in response to subsidies to nongroup insurance. The extent to which firms will change the mix of employer and employee premium financing in response to subsidies; for example, when employee premiums are tax subsidized, will employers raise those premiums to have the government bear a larger share of insurance costs? These assumptions are based on academic studies, where available, as well as consultations with economic, actuarial, and policy experts. The particular model used in this report is influenced by the author s previous work, the most central being a paper with Michael Lettau, How Elastic is the Firm s Demand for Health Insurance? 10 That paper develops the best estimates to date of employers responsiveness to tax subsidies in their decisions to offer health insurance. The authors found that while employers in general are fairly price sensitive in their offer decisions, small employers in particular are very price sensitive. This is important, since many of the tax subsidy policies considered in California and elsewhere are focused on small firms. The model used in earlier work has been updated in a number of ways that are critical for the policy analyses conducted in this report. First, information on insurance coverage and costs is the most up-to-date available. In addition, all behavioral responses that were embedded in the old model have been updated based on the current research in health economics. Second, the model has been extended beyond the analysis of nongroup tax credits to consider tax credits for group insurance as well. This is important because, due to dissatisfaction with the nongroup insurance market as a vehicle for insurance coverage expansions, group credits are playing an important role in the policy debate in California and elsewhere. The model is now fully capable of analyzing tax subsidies to both employers (for their spending on insurance), as well as to employees (for their premium shares). The impact of both kinds of subsidy policy is discussed in detail below. Third, and critical for modeling the role of subsidies to group insurance, the newer model allows firm-wide reactions to subsidy policies. A limitation of all current microsimulation models is that they are estimated on individual data, and relatively little is known about a given worker s workplace. This was much less relevant in previous modeling efforts, since they focused on decisions by individuals to purchase nongroup insurance or not; however, it is a critical limitation in considering policies targeted to employee and employer purchase of group insurance, as the reaction to these policies will depend not simply on a given worker, but on the nature of coworkers as well. For example, whether a firm will offer insurance in reaction to a subsidy will depend on the demand for insurance among all workers in that firm, not just the given worker observed in the CPS. Similarly, if subsidies are targeted to low-wage firms, it is critical to measure whether a given CPS worker is part of such a qualifying firm or not. This will Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 9

13 require looking beyond that worker s own wages to those of the firm as a whole; many low-wage workers are actually working in high-wage firms, and vice versa. A key element of this revised model will be a more realistic model of firm decision making through the construction of synthetic firms. The Bureau of Labor Statistics keeps data that provide information on the wages of all workers within a nationally representative set of firms. These data can be used to correctly assign coworkers to the current CPS sample observations. That is, for a worker of given characteristics (wage, firm size, industry, insurance offering, etc.), the distribution of the characteristics of his or her coworkers can be determined. (For example, for a worker earning $10,000 in the services industry who is not offered insurance, the share of coworkers earning $10,000, $15,000, $20,000, etc., could be determined.) Using this information in conjunction with the CPS data, each CPS observation can be assigned a set of coworkers that matches this distribution. Thus, standard microdata like the CPS can be enhanced by the richness of firm-wide characteristics necessary to fully analyze subsidies for group insurance. California vs. the Nation as a Whole The importance of pursuing California-specific modeling is made apparent by Table 1, which summarizes the key demographic and labor market characteristics of California and the rest of the United States. Californians are younger than those in other states on average, and are less likely to be married. This is important because young and unmarried persons are those most likely to find nongroup credits most attractive, since relative costs for this group are lowest. At the same time, their overall demand for insurance may be lower. Offsetting this is the fact that individuals in California are less likely to report being in excellent health. Table 1. Characteristics of California and the Rest of the United States Characteristics California Rest of United States Average age Married 37.0% 40.6% Excellent health 37.9% 38.7% Very good health 30.3% 33.1% Good health 25.3% 21.6% Fair health 4.8% 4.9% Poor health 1.7% 1.7% Average income $44,000 $46,800 Firm < 100 employees 42.9% 39.3% Firm employees 17.6% 19.7% Firm 1,000+ employees 39.5% 41.0% Employer insured 59.4% 68.4% Nongroup insured 6.9% 6.1% Medicaid insured 12.9% 9.5% Uninsured 20.9% 16.0% Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 10

14 Californians also have significantly lower incomes, on average, than residents of other states. This is important because it suggests that even tightly targeted (to income) tax credits can have large impacts in the state. Workers in California are also more likely to be employed in small firms. This implies that employer credits targeted to small firms may be effective. It is also important because small firms are much more price sensitive in their insurance offering decisions than are larger firms. 11 The final rows in this table compare the insurance coverage of Californians to the remainder of the United States. Californians are much less likely to be covered by employer-provided insurance, and somewhat more likely to hold nongroup insurance. They are more likely to be on public insurance. Overall, the insurance rate is much lower in California than in other states. Thus, it is clear that the impact of tax credits might be quite different in California than in the nation as a whole. In particular, the lower income levels and lower insurance rates in the state suggest that targeted tax credits might play a more helpful role in this environment than elsewhere. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 11

15 III. Estimates of the Impact of Tax Subsidies on Insurance Coverage and Costs Nongroup Tax Credits The first type of tax credit modeled involves credits that are restricted for use to the nongroup insurance market only. This approach is comparable to the most popular tax credit proposals at the federal level, including those put forward during the presidential campaign and in subsequent budget proposals by President Bush. A prototypical nongroup tax credit proposal would have the following details: Individuals can take the credit against their nongroup health insurance expenditures, up to $1,000 per individual and $2,500 per family. The credit is fully refundable; that is, if the family runs out of tax liability against which to offset the credit, they receive the difference as a refund. The credit can only be used for nongroup insurance expenses and not for group insurance purchase. The credit is fully available to those individuals with annual incomes up to $20,000, and phases out as income reaches $40,000. It is fully available to families with incomes up to $40,000, and phases out as income reaches $80,000. The analysis of nongroup credits incorporates a host of assumptions about how individuals, families, and employers will respond to this change in the insurance environment. The key factor that determines this response is the subsidy rate implicit in nongroup credits. This is the amount of the credit divided by the underlying cost of nongroup insurance to the individual or family. It is assumed that those who are uninsured are more likely to take up nongroup credits as the subsidy rate rises. Importantly, the likelihood of take-up will fall as the unsubsidized portion of nongroup insurance costs rise relative to income. That is, a $2,000 credit that leaves the family with $5,000 in insurance costs will have a lower take-up rate for a family with only $30,000 in Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 12

16 income than for a family with $100,000 in income, since the remaining cost of nongroup insurance is such a high fraction of income for the lower income family. It is also assumed that employers, particularly small employers, react to the availability of nongroup subsidies. As noted above, existing evidence suggests that subsidies to the provision of employer-sponsored insurance (ESI) raises the odds that ESI is offered by firms. By the same logic, subsidies to insurance that is available only outside the firm will lower the odds that firms offer insurance. If their employees have a low-price option to purchase insurance elsewhere, firms, and in particular small firms, will be less likely to offer that insurance through the workplace. Those firms that continue to offer insurance will also react by increasing the premiums that employees pay for ESI in order to provide incentives for their employees to choose nongroup insurance instead, thereby reducing overall firm insurance costs. One key assumption that is important for modeling the impact of nongroup subsidies is the feasibility of advanceable tax credits for nongroup insurance. An important potential limitation of nongroup tax credits, especially for low-income groups, is that the tax refund for a given year is not available until the next spring. Low-income groups that do not have much savings will not be able to advance fund (prepay) their nongroup insurance purchases until that refund is available. For this reason, many plans, such as the current Bush Administration s nongroup tax credit proposal, seek to make these tax credits advanceable so that individuals can access them when they are needed. A sound idea in theory, advanceability has not, unfortunately, worked well in practice. The only experience with this concept in practice is for the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), an income supplement available to low-income wage earners. A given year s EITC is typically paid as a refund the next spring, but individuals do have the option of getting their EITC payments during the year, which would raise their value for the vast majority of recipients. Yet less than one percent of EITC recipients use this option. Presumably, this is due to fear among potential recipients that their income will end up higher than expected, so that they will have to pay back some or all of this credit if they claim it in advance. Advanceability is likely to work better in the context of nongroup credits. For example, the Bush proposal would base eligibility for an advanceable credit on taxable income in the previous year, so that there is no potential for costly reconciliation when taxes are due in April. However, even this approach has its limitations, such as difficulties in qualifying individuals whose incomes suddenly decrease. Given our inability to set up a working advanceability model in other contexts, the model assumes that advanceability mechanisms will only be effective for one-half of the low-income consumers who face funding problems in buying their nongroup health insurance. For the other half, the problem of mismatch between the time premiums are due and the time refunds are received will reduce their take-up of the credit. The results of estimating the model for California, using these assumptions, are shown in Table 2. As the first section of that table shows, this tax subsidy is taken up by 2.01 million people, or 7 percent of the state population. Two-fifths of those who take up the subsidy are uninsured, onethird have nongroup insurance, and about one-sixth have employer-provided insurance. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 13

17 Table 2 shows the net changes in insurance status as a result of this subsidy. Most importantly, there is a net reduction in the uninsured of 640,000, or 10.3 percent of the existing number of uninsured. This figure is smaller than the number of uninsured who Table 2. Nongroup Credit Base Case* No. of Persons (millions) Percent of Insurance Category Net Cost (millions) Total cost ,631 Total take-up of subsidy Previously employer insured Previously nongroup insured Previously Medicaid Previously uninsured Not offered and uninsured Offered and uninsured Total change in population size Nongroup Medicaid Uninsured Employer insured Firm dropped to nongroup Firm dropped to uninsured Switch to nongroup Uninsured due to increased employee contributions Change in federal tax revenue (millions) 708 Cost per newly insured 2,564 * $1,000/$2,500 refundable credit; $20,000 $40,000 / $40,000 $80,000 income range Calculated in 2003 dollars. take up the credit because the 830,000 who take up is offset by some increase in the number of uninsured resulting from employer dropping. As the table shows, there is an overall reduction of 580,000 in the number of persons with employer-sponsored insurance, or 3.1 percent of the existing number of ESI holders. This reduction in ESI applies to four groups. The first consists of those to whom firms no longer offer insurance because of the availability of nongroup insurance, and who, when dropped, take up the nongroup credit (220,000). The second consists of those who are dropped and who decide not to take up the credit, becoming uninsured (160,000). The third group is made up of those who switch from group insurance to nongroup insurance because they are very healthy and subsidized nongroup insurance proves to be less expensive (140,000). The fourth group consists of those who become uninsured because their firm increases employee premium contributions in response to the nongroup credit, and the employee chooses not to continue purchasing the group health insurance (30,000). Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 14

18 Table 2 also shows the costs associated with this credit. The total cost of this credit to the state is $1.63 billion per year. It is important to note, however, that this estimate does not include federal (income and payroll) tax revenue increases that result from individuals moving out of taxsubsidized ESI. As the next to last row shows in the Table, there is a federal income tax increase of $708 million, which is quite large relative to the net costs to the state. Therefore, if the state could somehow recapture these federal tax gains, it would lower costs by roughly 40 percent. The net cost of this credit per newly insured is approximately $2,550. This very large number results from the fact that only about 40 percent of program dollars are spent on the uninsured. Thus, this is a fairly poorly targeted approach to increasing health insurance coverage. But, once again, the poor targeting here would be greatly mitigated if federal tax savings were taken into account. Table 3 shows the distributional implications of this tax credit. It shows the spending and insurance coverage changes for those below the poverty line, between 100 and 200 percent of the poverty line, between 200 and 300 percent of the poverty line, between 300 and 400 percent of the poverty line, and above 400 percent of the poverty line. Most of the net reduction in the uninsured is among those below 200 percent of poverty; there is even some increase above 400 percent of poverty, due to firm dropping. The credit is fairly well targeted in terms of distribution, with 80 percent of spending going to those below 200 percent of the poverty line. Table 3. Nongroup Credit Base Case: Distributional Analysis* Group (by Percent of FPL) Net Cost (Millions) Percent of Costs Subsidy Take-up (Millions) Percent of Group Change in Uninsured (Millions) Percent of Uninsured Cost per Newly Insured <100% $ $2, % $ $2, % $ $3, % $ $3,483 >400% -$ $4,652 * $1,000 / $2,500 refundable credit; $1,000 $2,500 / $20,000 $40,000 / 40,000 $80,000 income range Calculated in 2003 dollars. Table 4 summarizes the key results of varying the parameters of the nongroup credit in various ways. It first shows the base case from Tables 2 and 3 for comparison. The second and third rows present the effect of expanding the generosity of the credit by raising it by 50 percent, and then by doubling it. This increased generosity results in a larger net reduction in the uninsured, but an even larger rise in net costs, so that the cost per newly insured increases. When the subsidy amount is increased by 50 percent, the reduction in the uninsured rises by nearly 65 percent, to 1.04 million. But costs more than double to more than $3.3 billion per year, so the cost per newly insured increases to $3,200. Similarly, doubling the credit more than doubles the reduction in uninsured but triples the costs, so that the cost per newly insured rises to almost $3,700. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 15

19 Table 4. Alternative Approaches to Nongroup Credit Base case $1,500/$3,750 credit $2,000/$5,000 credit Double income phaseouts Nonrefundable Total Take-Up Total Cost Change in Uninsured Change in Nongroup Insured Change in Employer Insured Cost per Newly Insured Percent of Benefits for <200% FPL , , , , , , These results illustrate a general principle that is common to all of the types of tax subsidies considered here: Increases in generosity reduce the efficiency of the policy, in terms of cost per newly insured. This happens for two reasons. First, each person who is subsidized is getting a larger amount of subsidy. Second, the larger subsidies increase take-up by all persons, whether previously insured or uninsured. On net, this makes the credit more inefficient since for every credit considered, the majority of those who take up already had private insurance. The fourth row in Table 4 shows the impact of making the credit available to a broader range of incomes by increasing the phaseout ranges to $40,000 $80,000 for singles, and $80,000 $160,000 for families. This change has essentially no impact on the number of newly insured resulting from the nongroup credit; a slight increase in take-up by the existing uninsured is offset by increased firm dropping. In this case, costs rise to just over $2.5 billion per year, so that the cost per newly insured rises to over $4,000. This finding has very important implications that are echoed throughout this report: the more tightly targeted the credit, the more cost efficient it is. In this case, loosening the targeting has no benefits, only costs. Moreover, as the distributional columns in this table show, the credit is now much less well targeted, with 65 percent of spending going to those below 200 percent of the poverty line. The final row of the table shows the results of a nonrefundable tax credit. This is an important case to consider because of the frequent political opposition to refundable credits as a form of welfare, but a state tax credit has very limited effect if it is not refundable, since state tax liabilities are limited relative to the size of the credit. This is shown very clearly by the results: the credit does essentially nothing if it is not refundable. Only 400,000 California residents take up the credit, and this is offset by a net increase in the number of uninsured (200,000). The credit is cheap at $53 million per year, but since the number of uninsured actually increases, this is not money well spent. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 16

20 This finding highlights the key limitations of state income tax policy as a vehicle for insurance reform. It is absolutely critical that credits be fully refundable, or they will essentially have no effect given relatively small state tax liabilities. Employer Tax Credits The second type of tax credit option modeled is a tax credit that can be used by employers to offset their costs for providing health insurance. These credits have two distinct advantages relative to nongroup tax credits. First, they promote, rather than supplant, the group insurance market. This is advantageous because it preserves the pooling mechanisms that work well in the group market, and also because it benefits from the lower prices in group markets. Moreover, group insurance coverage provides, in general, more comprehensive insurance than nongroup coverage; thus, broader coverage through the group market results in people being more fully insured than they would be by expansion of nongroup coverage. Second, these credits largely avoid the issue of advanceability because firms are much more likely to have the funds to pay for health insurance through directly lowering wage payments or other sources of firm capital until tax credits are available. Additionally, governments interact with employers on a more frequent basis (for example, quarterly payroll tax or unemployment insurance tax collections) so that it would be easy to have a more frequent subsidy payment. There are three key potential limitations of employer subsidies. The first is targeting. Since the subsidies go to employers and not individuals, they are necessarily tied to characteristics of that workplace. Workplaces are generally heterogeneous places, with continuous mixing of low- and high-income workers. This has one key advantage and one key disadvantage in terms of targeting. The advantage is that the lack of insurance in the United States is largely tied to firm offering; roughly two-thirds of the uninsured are employed but not offered health insurance. Therefore, targeting firms will target the source of the problem. Those firms that do not offer health insurance are tightly grouped into a set of small and lowwage firms. This is illustrated in Table 5, 12 which shows insurance offering rates by firm size and average firm earnings level (in 1997). In all firms of more than 100 employees, and in firms of more than 50 employees with moderately high average wage levels, rates of offering are very high. Only in the very smallest firms, or in those small-to-medium firms that are very low wage, is the offering rate very far from 100 percent. This makes it feasible, in theory, to fairly tightly target offering subsidies to those small firms that are most likely to be uninsured. The disadvantage is that many of the dollars flow to firms that have a nontrivial number of higher income workers. Some small, low-wage firms have one or several high-wage employees. Moreover, the targeting at the firm level is by necessity based on earnings and not total family income. So an apparently low-wage firm may be a high-income firm if it employs the spouses of higher income workers. By examining the effects of these subsidies along the income distribution, one can assess how much of a problem this is relative to nongroup subsidies. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 17

21 Table 5. Insurance Offer Rates by Firm Size and Average Earnings Categories Average Earning 1 9 Employees Employees Employees Employees 100+ Employees <$10, $10 15, $15 20, $20 25, $25 30, >$30, The second potential limitation of employer subsidies is that they are limited to those who have access to employer-sponsored insurance. This can be viewed as unfair to the unemployed, to the employed but uninsured whose employers are not eligible for subsidies, or to those uninsured whose employers do not respond to this subsidy by offering insurance. The final potential limitation is that, by subsidizing employer spending on insurance, the government encourages employers to offer more generous insurance plans, and this further erodes the tax base, since employer-sponsored insurance premiums are tax excluded. Earlier work by Gruber and Lettau 13 finds that employer spending on health insurance is very sensitive with respect to tax subsidies. This suggests that open-ended percentage subsidies to employer spending (for example, subsidies of a share of premium regardless of the richness of the benefits offered) can be quite costly. On the other hand, flat dollar subsidies will increase spending somewhat, as firms have more resources, but much less than an open-ended percentage subsidy. As a result, this paper considers a flat dollar subsidy that is equivalent to roughly 50 percent of the average spending of employers on health insurance. The current analysis considers an employer credit with the following characteristics: The maximum credit rate is $1,500 per employee taking up individual insurance coverage, and $3,500 per employee taking up family coverage. This maximum credit rate applies to firms with fewer than ten employees and with an average earnings level of less than $20,000 per year. This credit rate is reduced both as firm size increases and as average wages increase. The reduction with firm size is at a rate of percentage points per additional employee beyond ten employees, so that the credit reaches zero at 50 employees. The reduction with average earnings is a function of firm size. For firms of fewer than ten employees, the credit phases out fully by an average earnings level of $40,000. As firm size grows, the credit phases out faster with average earnings. In this way, the credit structure mimics Table 5, with the largest credits for small and low-wage, medium-size firms. Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 18

22 While this structure appears quite complicated, in practice it is fairly straightforward to implement a credit of this nature. Firms collect their earnings data regularly for paying other forms of payroll taxes. One important question is whether any employee should be counted in computing firm size, or only (for example) full-time employees. This is a difficult issue: on the one hand, part-time employees are unlikely to be eligible for insurance; on the other hand, if firm size is computed based only on full-time employees, there is an incentive to relabel employees as part-time. On balance, it seems that a sensible approach would be to count only full-time employees, but to define full-time fairly liberally (for example, 20 hours per week or more). Once again, the model used to analyze employer credits has embedded within it a number of important behavioral assumptions. In this case, larger subsidies will lead to a larger number of firms, particularly small firms, offering ESI. Firms will also share these subsidies with their employees by bearing a larger share of the cost of insurance, lowering employee premium shares. The results of simulating this credit are shown in Table 6. The total take-up of this subsidy is 3.1 million persons, about 25 percent of whom are uninsured, and 60 percent of whom are employerinsured. There is a net reduction in the number of uninsured of 780,000; 80 percent of this decrease is from new insurance offering, and the remaining 20 percent is from increased take-up of employer insurance among those already offered (since employers are lowering employee premium shares). There is a net increase in the number of employer insured of 1.2 million, incorporating both the reduction in the uninsured and new ESI take-up among some of those who had nongroup or Medicaid coverage. The total cost of this subsidy is $1.9 billion per year. About 45 percent of the spending on this credit is on those who were previously uninsured. The cost per newly insured is $2450. This is a lower cost than the nongroup credit, for a credit that covers more people and serves to promote, rather than displace, the group market. The reason for this lower cost is not better targeting; in fact, with the nongroup credit, a larger percentage of the dollars are spent on those who were previously uninsured. Rather it is the much lower cost of insurance in the group market, relative to the nongroup market, which makes this a much more efficient arena for promoting coverage. For the nongroup credit, federal tax savings would potentially offset much of the costs. This is not true for the employer credit; there is a negative impact on federal tax revenues. This is because the federal tax losses from firms newly offering insurance (thereby replacing taxable wages with non-taxable health insurance premiums) is only partially offset by the federal tax gains from firms passing these credits on to workers in the form of higher wages. Thus, if one were to net out federal tax revenues, the nongroup and employer credits would be much more comparable. But, at the state level, not accounting for federal tax changes, employer credits are more attractive. The distributional impacts of the employer credit are considered in Table 7. It is somewhat difficult to compare the distributional impacts of employer credits with nongroup credits (or the employee credits below) since the credit dollars go to employers, and not directly to workers. Thus, to assess distributional impacts, it is necessary to make some assumption about the incidence of the payments to employers; that is, who will benefit from subsidies to employers? Following a large literature in economics, this analysis assumes that the subsidy dollars that Cost Modeling for Tax Subsidies to Increase Health Insurance Coverage in California 19

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 19

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 19 This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 19 Volume Author/Editor: James M. Poterba, editor Volume Publisher:

More information

Assessing the Impact of State Tax Credits for Health Insurance Coverage

Assessing the Impact of State Tax Credits for Health Insurance Coverage Assessing the Impact of State Tax Credits for Health Insurance Coverage June 2003 Prepared for the California HealthCare Foundation by Karl Polzer and Jonathan Gruber About the Authors Karl Polzer, M.P.A.,

More information

President Bush s Health Care Tax Deduction Proposal: Coverage, Cost and Distributional Impacts. John Sheils and Randy Haught

President Bush s Health Care Tax Deduction Proposal: Coverage, Cost and Distributional Impacts. John Sheils and Randy Haught www.lewin.com President Bush s Health Care Tax Deduction Proposal: Coverage, Cost and Distributional Impacts John Sheils and Randy Haught President Bush proposes to replace the existing tax exemption for

More information

Tax Subsidies For Health Insurance: Costs And Benefits

Tax Subsidies For Health Insurance: Costs And Benefits I n s u r a n c e C o v e r a g e Tax Subsidies For Health Insurance: Costs And Benefits Even the most effective tax subsidies would cost almost $40 billion a year and cover only 30 percent of the uninsured.

More information

THE COST AND COVERAGE IMPACT OF THE PRESIDENT S HEALTH INSURANCE BUDGET PROPOSALS By Jonathan Gruber, MIT

THE COST AND COVERAGE IMPACT OF THE PRESIDENT S HEALTH INSURANCE BUDGET PROPOSALS By Jonathan Gruber, MIT 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org February 15, 2006 THE COST AND COVERAGE IMPACT OF THE PRESIDENT S HEALTH INSURANCE BUDGET

More information

Tax Credits for Health Insurance

Tax Credits for Health Insurance Tax Policy Issues and Options URBAN BROOKINGS TAX POLICY CENTER No. 11, June 2005 Tax Credits for Health Insurance Leonard E. Burman and Jonathan Gruber The tax system may not be the most efficient way

More information

Insurance Markets Ready or Not: Consumers Face New Health Insurance Choices. Employer-based. Insurance Premium. Contribution.

Insurance Markets Ready or Not: Consumers Face New Health Insurance Choices. Employer-based. Insurance Premium. Contribution. Insurance Markets Ready or Not: Consumers Face New Health Insurance Choices Introduction Not long ago, most working Californians, at least those working for large or midsize companies, could expect a standard

More information

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002. Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056. center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org.

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002. Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056. center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org. 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org July 1, 2009 SENATE FINANCE COMMITTEE FACES DIFFICULT CHOICES IN LOWERING COST OF HEALTH

More information

How To Calculate The Cost Of A Health Insurance Tax Credit In Oregona

How To Calculate The Cost Of A Health Insurance Tax Credit In Oregona Oregon Health Fund Board INITIAL ECONOMETRIC MODELING FOR THE OREGON HEALTH FUND BOARD Final Report February 2009 SUMMARY The Oregon Health Fund Board worked with consultants from the Massachusetts Institute

More information

Comparison of California Health Coverage Expansion Proposals

Comparison of California Health Coverage Expansion Proposals Note: A comparison of the Senate Republican proposal for the special session, CalCare Plus will be available shortly. Californians to Be Covered 1 Consumers/ Individuals Treatment of Self-Employed Employers

More information

Expanding Health Coverage in Kentucky: Why It Matters. September 2009

Expanding Health Coverage in Kentucky: Why It Matters. September 2009 Expanding Health Coverage in Kentucky: Why It Matters September 2009 As the details of federal health reform proposals consume the public debate, reflecting strong and diverse opinions about various options,

More information

The Hidden Public Costs of Low-Wage Jobs in California

The Hidden Public Costs of Low-Wage Jobs in California The Hidden Public Costs of Low-Wage Jobs in California Dr. Carol Zabin, Dr. Arindrajit Dube, and Ken Jacobs Center for Labor Research and Education, UC Berkeley Written for the National Economic Development

More information

Tax Subsidies for Private Health Insurance

Tax Subsidies for Private Health Insurance Tax Subsidies for Private Health Insurance Matthew Rae, Gary Claxton, Nirmita Panchal, Larry Levitt The federal and state tax systems provide significant financial benefits for people with private health

More information

Health Coverage among 50- to 64-Year-Olds

Health Coverage among 50- to 64-Year-Olds Health Coverage among 50- to 64-Year-Olds In 2005, more than 51 million Americans were age 50 64. This number is projected to rise to 58 million in 2010, when the first baby boomers turn 64. The aging

More information

How Non-Group Health Coverage Varies with Income

How Non-Group Health Coverage Varies with Income How Non-Group Health Coverage Varies with Income February 2008 Policy makers at the state and federal levels are considering proposals to subsidize the direct purchase of health insurance as a way to reduce

More information

Tax Credits and Health Insurance for the Self- Employed

Tax Credits and Health Insurance for the Self- Employed SPNA Review Volume 3 Issue 1 Article 3 4-1-2007 Tax Credits and Health Insurance for the Self- Employed Adam Buchalski Grand Valley State University Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.gvsu.edu/spnareview

More information

Social Insurance Arises, In Part, Because of Asymmetric Information

Social Insurance Arises, In Part, Because of Asymmetric Information Social Arises, In Part, Because of Asymmetric Information Assume there are 2 groups, each with 100 people. The first group has 5% chance of getting injured, and the second group has a 0.5% chance. The

More information

How To Get A Small Business Health Insurance Plan For Free

How To Get A Small Business Health Insurance Plan For Free Statement of Linda J. Blumberg, Ph.D. Senior Fellow The Urban Institute Committee on Energy and Commerce Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations United States House of Representatives Hearing: The

More information

california Health Care Almanac California s Uninsured

california Health Care Almanac California s Uninsured california Health Care Almanac december 2011 Introduction Over the past two decades, California has seen an increase in the percentage of people who are uninsured. California now has the largest number

More information

Introduction. California Employer Health Benefits

Introduction. California Employer Health Benefits Survey: Workers Feel the Pinch January 2014 Introduction Employer-based coverage is the leading source of health insurance in California as well as nationally. This edition of the annual Survey provides

More information

Retiree Drug Coverage under the MMA: Issues for Public Comment to Maximize Enhancement in Drug Coverage and Reductions in Drug Costs for Retirees

Retiree Drug Coverage under the MMA: Issues for Public Comment to Maximize Enhancement in Drug Coverage and Reductions in Drug Costs for Retirees Retiree Drug Coverage under the MMA: Issues for Public Comment to Maximize Enhancement in Drug Coverage and Reductions in Drug Costs for Retirees Discussion Paper: CMS Employer Open Door Forum I. Summary:

More information

Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance An Issue Brief

Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance An Issue Brief Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance An Issue Brief Prepared by the Kaiser Family Foundation July 2008 Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance Most workers pay both federal and state taxes for wages paid to them

More information

Profile of Rural Health Insurance Coverage

Profile of Rural Health Insurance Coverage Profile of Rural Health Insurance Coverage A Chartbook R H R C Rural Health Research & Policy Centers Funded by the Federal Office of Rural Health Policy www.ruralhealthresearch.org UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHERN

More information

Statement by Gary Claxton Vice President, Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation Director, Health Care Marketplace Project

Statement by Gary Claxton Vice President, Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation Director, Health Care Marketplace Project Statement by Gary Claxton Vice President, Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation Director, Health Care Marketplace Project Before the U.S. Senate Committee on Finance Roundtable on Health Care Coverage May

More information

Under current tax law, health insurance premiums are largely taxexempt

Under current tax law, health insurance premiums are largely taxexempt The Cost Of Tax-Exempt Health Benefits In 2004 Tax policies for health insurance will cost the federal government $188.5 billion in lost revenue in 2004, and most of the benefit goes to those with the

More information

Affordable Care Act, What s in it? Rural Young Adults. Alyssa Charney

Affordable Care Act, What s in it? Rural Young Adults. Alyssa Charney Affordable Care Act, What s in it? Rural Young Adults No. 13 June 2011 Alyssa Charney Center for Rural Affairs The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act includes significant benefits for young adults.

More information

MASSACHUSETTS UNDER THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT: EMPLOYER-RELATED ISSUES AND POLICY OPTIONS

MASSACHUSETTS UNDER THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT: EMPLOYER-RELATED ISSUES AND POLICY OPTIONS MASSACHUSETTS UNDER THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT: EMPLOYER-RELATED ISSUES AND POLICY OPTIONS JULY 2012 Fredric Blavin, Linda J. Blumberg, Matthew Buettgens, and Jeremy Roth of the Urban Institute ABOUT THE

More information

How To Determine The Impact Of The Health Care Law On Insurance In Indiana

How To Determine The Impact Of The Health Care Law On Insurance In Indiana ACA Impact on Premium Rates in the Individual and Small Group Markets Paul R. Houchens, FSA, MAAA BACKGROUND The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) introduces significant changes in covered

More information

2012 Vermont Household Health Insurance Survey: Comprehensive Report

2012 Vermont Household Health Insurance Survey: Comprehensive Report Vermont Department of Financial Regulation Insurance Division 2012 Vermont Household Health Insurance Survey: Comprehensive Report Brian Robertson, Ph.D. Jason Maurice, Ph.D. Table of Contents Page I.

More information

Cover Missouri Project: Report 9. Increasing Health Insurance Coverage in Missouri Through Subsidies

Cover Missouri Project: Report 9. Increasing Health Insurance Coverage in Missouri Through Subsidies MISSOURI FOUNDATION FOR HEALTH Cover Missouri Project: Report 9 Increasing Health Insurance Coverage in Missouri Through Subsidies MISSOURI FOUNDATION FOR HEALTH About MFH Established in 2000, the Missouri

More information

5. Defined Benefit and Defined Contribution Plans: Understanding the Differences

5. Defined Benefit and Defined Contribution Plans: Understanding the Differences 5. Defined Benefit and Defined Contribution Plans: Understanding the Differences Introduction Both defined benefit and defined contribution pension plans offer various advantages to employers and employees.

More information

PPACA Subsidy Model Description

PPACA Subsidy Model Description PPACA Subsidy Model Description John A. Graves Vanderbilt University November 2011 This draft paper is intended for review and comments only. It is not intended for citation, quotation, or other use in

More information

Higher and Rising (Figure 1)

Higher and Rising (Figure 1) Higher and Rising (Figure 1) Employer contributions to public school teacher pensions and Social Security are higher than contributions for privatesector professionals, the gap more than doubling between

More information

Health Care Reform without the Individual Mandate

Health Care Reform without the Individual Mandate Health Care Reform without the Individual Mandate Replacing the Individual Mandate would Significantly Erode Coverage Gains and Raise Premiums for Health Care Consumers Jonathan Gruber February 2011 Introduction

More information

Impact of the Health Insurance Annual Fee Tax

Impact of the Health Insurance Annual Fee Tax Impact of the Health Insurance Annual Fee Tax Robert A. Book, Ph.D. February 20, 2014 Executive Summary The Affordable Care Act's "annual fee on health insurance is a unique tax levied on health insurance

More information

Why did employee health insurance contributions rise?

Why did employee health insurance contributions rise? Journal of Health Economics 22 (2003) 1085 1104 Why did employee health insurance contributions rise? Jonathan Gruber, Robin McKnight Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, MIT

More information

In preparing the February 2014 baseline budget

In preparing the February 2014 baseline budget APPENDIX B Updated Estimates of the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act In preparing the February 2014 baseline budget projections, the Congressional Budget Office () and the staff

More information

Health Care Reform Frequently Asked Questions

Health Care Reform Frequently Asked Questions Health Care Reform Frequently Asked Questions On March 23, 2010, President Obama signed federal health care reform into law, also known as the Patient Protection and Affordability Act. A second, or reconciliation

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE. Jonathan Gruber

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE. Jonathan Gruber NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE Jonathan Gruber Working Paper 15766 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15766 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Massachusetts has garnered national attention recently for its bipartisan

Massachusetts has garnered national attention recently for its bipartisan Promising Elements of the Massachusetts Approach: A Health Insurance Pool, Individual Mandates, and Federal Tax Subsidies by President Institute for Health Policy Solutions Massachusetts has garnered national

More information

THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE

THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE National Tax Journal, June 2011, 64 (2, Part 2), 511 530 THE TAX EXCLUSION FOR EMPLOYER-SPONSORED HEALTH INSURANCE Jonathan Gruber This paper reviews the issues raised by and the impacts of the tax exclusion

More information

budget brief On Tuesday, August 3, legislative leaders proposed a new budget plan, including a tax swap that would increase some

budget brief On Tuesday, August 3, legislative leaders proposed a new budget plan, including a tax swap that would increase some UNDERSTANDING THE TAX SWAP budget brief AUGUST JUNE 2010 2005 On Tuesday, August 3, legislative leaders proposed a new budget plan, including a tax swap that would increase some of the state s personal

More information

Consensus Principles for Health Care Delivery

Consensus Principles for Health Care Delivery Consensus Principles for Health Care Delivery TABLE OF CONTENTS Consensus Principle for Healthcare Delivery... 3 Responsibilities of Various Parties to the Health Care System... 4 Individuals and Families...

More information

Tax subsidies for private health insurance: who currently benefits and what are the implications for new policies?

Tax subsidies for private health insurance: who currently benefits and what are the implications for new policies? Also see the report on this topic available at www.taxpolicycenter.org This policy primer is available at www.policysynthesis.org THE SYNTHESIS PROJECT NEW INSIGHTS FROM RESEARCH RESULTS Tax subsidies

More information

ASSESSING THE RESULTS

ASSESSING THE RESULTS HEALTH REFORM IN MASSACHUSETTS EXPANDING TO HEALTH INSURANCE ASSESSING THE RESULTS March 2014 Health Reform in Massachusetts, Expanding Access to Health Insurance Coverage: Assessing the Results pulls

More information

Health Insurance Expansions For Working Families: A Comparison Of Targeting Strategies

Health Insurance Expansions For Working Families: A Comparison Of Targeting Strategies Health Insurance Expansions For Working Families: A Comparison Of Targeting Strategies Finding the right criteria for targeting insurance expansions is crucial to maximizing the number of newly covered

More information

Declining Health Insurance in Low-Income Working Families and Small Businesses

Declining Health Insurance in Low-Income Working Families and Small Businesses ACA Implementation Monitoring and Tracking Declining Health Insurance in Low-Income Working Families and Small Businesses April 2012 John Holahan and Vicki Chen The Urban Institute Executive Summary Employer-sponsored

More information

Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act CBO s February 2014 Baseline

Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act CBO s February 2014 Baseline Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act CBO s February 2014 Baseline Table 1. Effects on the Deficit of the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act Table 2. Effects of

More information

Age Rating Under Comprehensive Health Care Reform: Implications for Coverage, Costs, and Household Financial Burdens

Age Rating Under Comprehensive Health Care Reform: Implications for Coverage, Costs, and Household Financial Burdens Age Rating Under Comprehensive Health Care Reform: Implications for Coverage, Costs, and Household Financial Burdens Timely Analysis of Immediate Health Policy Issues October 2009 Linda J. Blumberg, Matthew

More information

The primary purpose of a tax system is to support public goods and services. State and local taxes

The primary purpose of a tax system is to support public goods and services. State and local taxes Issue Brief UPDATED APRIL 2015 BY WILLIAM CHEN Who Pays Taxes in California? The primary purpose of a tax system is to support public goods and services. State and local taxes are the way that Californians

More information

Health Reform Across the States: Increased Insurance Coverage and Federal Spending on the Exchanges and Medicaid

Health Reform Across the States: Increased Insurance Coverage and Federal Spending on the Exchanges and Medicaid Health Reform Across the States: Increased Insurance Coverage and Federal Spending on the Exchanges and Medicaid Timely Analysis of Immediate Health Policy Issues March 2011 Matthew Buettgens, John Holahan

More information

ADP Annual Health Benefits Report

ADP Annual Health Benefits Report ADP RESEARCH INSTITUTE ADP Annual Health Benefits Report 2014 Benchmarks and Trends for Large Organizations Table of Contents Executive Summary... 2 About This Study... 4 Section One: Participation in

More information

Presented to: 2007 Kansas Legislature. February 1, 2007

Presented to: 2007 Kansas Legislature. February 1, 2007 MARCIA J. NIELSEN, PhD, MPH Executive Director ANDREW ALLISON, PhD Deputy Director SCOTT BRUNNER Chief Financial Officer Report on: Massachusetts Commonwealth Health Insurance Connector Program Presented

More information

Health Care Reform and Small Business

Health Care Reform and Small Business Jane G. Gravelle Senior Specialist in Economic Policy July 5, 2013 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40775 c11173008

More information

How to Avoid Sledgehammer Penalties on Your Employees

How to Avoid Sledgehammer Penalties on Your Employees A BNA, INC. PENSION & BENEFITS! DAILY Reproduced with permission from Pension & Benefits Daily, 105 PBD, 06/03/2010. Copyright 2010 by The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. (800-372-1033) http:// www.bna.com

More information

Prepared for State of Minnesota. February 2013

Prepared for State of Minnesota. February 2013 The Impact of the ACA and Exchange on Minnesota: Updated Estimates Prepared for State of Minnesota February 2013 Dr. Jonathan Gruber MIT Department of Economics 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 Gorman

More information

Medicare Buy-In Options for Uninsured Adults

Medicare Buy-In Options for Uninsured Adults MEDICARE BUY-IN OPTIONS: ESTIMATING COVERAGE AND COSTS John Sheils and Ying-Jun Chen The Lewin Group, Inc. February 2001 Support for this research was provided by The Commonwealth Fund. The views presented

More information

How Can Employment-Based Benefits Help the Nursing Shortage?

How Can Employment-Based Benefits Help the Nursing Shortage? How Can Employment-Based Benefits Help the Nursing Shortage? Joanne Spetz, Ph.D., Center for the Health Professions and Department of Community Health Systems University of California, San Francisco Sara

More information

FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WILL PICK UP NEARLY ALL COSTS OF HEALTH REFORM S MEDICAID EXPANSION By January Angeles and Matthew Broaddus

FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WILL PICK UP NEARLY ALL COSTS OF HEALTH REFORM S MEDICAID EXPANSION By January Angeles and Matthew Broaddus 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Updated March 28, 2012 FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WILL PICK UP NEARLY ALL COSTS OF HEALTH REFORM

More information

STATE CONSIDERATIONS ON ADOPTING HEALTH REFORM S BASIC HEALTH OPTION Federal Guidance Needed for States to Fully Assess Option by January Angeles

STATE CONSIDERATIONS ON ADOPTING HEALTH REFORM S BASIC HEALTH OPTION Federal Guidance Needed for States to Fully Assess Option by January Angeles 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org March 13, 2012 STATE CONSIDERATIONS ON ADOPTING HEALTH REFORM S BASIC HEALTH OPTION

More information

THE LONG-TERM CARE PARTNERSHIP PROGRAM

THE LONG-TERM CARE PARTNERSHIP PROGRAM A Guide to Long-Term Care for State Policy Makers THE LONG-TERM CARE PARTNERSHIP PROGRAM Financing the increasing demand for long-term care services will be a significant 21 st century challenge. A key

More information

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HEALTH CARE REFORM ON SMALL BUSINESSES AND THEIR EMPLOYEES

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HEALTH CARE REFORM ON SMALL BUSINESSES AND THEIR EMPLOYEES EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HEALTH CARE REFORM ON SMALL BUSINESSES AND THEIR EMPLOYEES JULY 25, 2009 THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HEALTH CARE REFORM

More information

Article from: Health Watch. October 2013 Issue 73

Article from: Health Watch. October 2013 Issue 73 Article from: Health Watch October 2013 Issue 73 What Is Available in 2014 for 2015 Individual Health Insurance Rate Filings By Jeff Rohlinger Jeff Rohlinger, FSA, MAAA, is associate actuary at Health

More information

UNINSURED ADULTS IN MAINE, 2013 AND 2014: RATE STAYS STEADY AND BARRIERS TO HEALTH CARE CONTINUE

UNINSURED ADULTS IN MAINE, 2013 AND 2014: RATE STAYS STEADY AND BARRIERS TO HEALTH CARE CONTINUE UNINSURED ADULTS IN MAINE, 2013 AND 2014: RATE STAYS STEADY AND BARRIERS TO HEALTH CARE CONTINUE December 2015 Beginning in January 2014, the federal Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) has

More information

Expanding Health Insurance to the Uninsured in Kentucky: Estimating Participants and Costs

Expanding Health Insurance to the Uninsured in Kentucky: Estimating Participants and Costs Expanding Health Insurance to the Uninsured in Kentucky: Steven N. Allen Many states have recently offered health insurance benefits to low-income populations who have previously been uninsured or underinsured.

More information

Changes in Health Insurance Coverage in the Great Recession, 2007-2010 John Holahan and Vicki Chen The Urban Institute Executive Summary

Changes in Health Insurance Coverage in the Great Recession, 2007-2010 John Holahan and Vicki Chen The Urban Institute Executive Summary I S S U E P A P E R kaiser commission on medicaid and the uninsured Changes in Health Insurance Coverage in the Great Recession, 2007-2010 John Holahan and Vicki Chen The Urban Institute Executive Summary

More information

Lynn A. Blewett, Ph.D. Professor, University of Minnesota

Lynn A. Blewett, Ph.D. Professor, University of Minnesota Lynn A. Blewett, Ph.D. Professor, University of Minnesota Westlake Forum III Healthcare Reform in China and the US: Similarities, Differences and Challenges Emory University, Atlanta, GA April 10-12, 2011

More information

Health Care Reform: What s in the Law

Health Care Reform: What s in the Law Health Care Reform: What s in the Law Professor Sidney D. Watson March 2013 On June 28, 2012, the United States Supreme Court upheld the Affordable Care Act, also known as ObamaCare. The Supreme Court

More information

A HAND UP How State Earned Income Tax Credits Help Working Families Escape Poverty in 2004. Summary. By Joseph Llobrera and Bob Zahradnik

A HAND UP How State Earned Income Tax Credits Help Working Families Escape Poverty in 2004. Summary. By Joseph Llobrera and Bob Zahradnik 820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org May 14, 2004 A HAND UP How State Earned Income Tax Credits Help Working Families Escape

More information

Health Insurance Transitions Under the ACA Experienced by People Previously Insured in Non-Group Plans

Health Insurance Transitions Under the ACA Experienced by People Previously Insured in Non-Group Plans BRIEF 46 OCTOBER 2015 Health Insurance Transitions Under the ACA Experienced by People Previously Insured in Non-Group Plans AUTHORS Giovann Alarcon Graduate Research Assistant, SHADAC Jessie Kemmick Pintor

More information

The Impact of the ACA on Maine s Health Insurance Markets

The Impact of the ACA on Maine s Health Insurance Markets The Impact of the ACA on Maine s Health Insurance Markets Prepared for the Maine Bureau of Insurance May 31, 2011 Gorman Actuarial, LLC 210 Robert Road Marlborough, MA 01752 Jennifer Smagula, FSA, MAAA

More information

Updated Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act

Updated Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act MARCH 2012 Updated Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act In preparing the March 2012 baseline budget projections, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the staff

More information

THE GROWING SHARE OF UNINSURED WORKERS EMPLOYED BY LARGE FIRMS. Sherry Glied Columbia University. Jeanne M. Lambrew George Washington University

THE GROWING SHARE OF UNINSURED WORKERS EMPLOYED BY LARGE FIRMS. Sherry Glied Columbia University. Jeanne M. Lambrew George Washington University THE GROWING SHARE OF UNINSURED WORKERS EMPLOYED BY LARGE FIRMS Sherry Glied Columbia University Jeanne M. Lambrew George Washington University Sarah Little Columbia University October 2003 The authors

More information

Public Health Insurance Expansions for Parents and Enhancement Effects for Child Coverage

Public Health Insurance Expansions for Parents and Enhancement Effects for Child Coverage Public Health Insurance Expansions for Parents and Enhancement Effects for Child Coverage Jason R. Davis, University of Wisconsin Stevens Point ABSTRACT In 1997, the federal government provided states

More information

Children s Health Coverage Under the ACA Part III: Issue Diagnosis Evolutionary Challenges

Children s Health Coverage Under the ACA Part III: Issue Diagnosis Evolutionary Challenges Children s Health Coverage Under the ACA Part III: Issue Diagnosis Evolutionary Challenges Prepared by Carolina Coleman Funded by the Lucile Packard Foundation for Children s Health January 2014 This brief

More information

Health Insurance in the Small Business Market: Availability, Coverage, and the Effect of Tax Incentives

Health Insurance in the Small Business Market: Availability, Coverage, and the Effect of Tax Incentives Health Insurance in the Small Business Market: Availability, Coverage, and the Effect of Tax Incentives by Quantria Strategies, LLC Cheverly, MD 20785 for Under Contract Number SBAHQ-09-Q-0018 Release

More information

Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act Updated for the Recent Supreme Court Decision

Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act Updated for the Recent Supreme Court Decision JULY 2012 Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act Updated for the Recent Supreme Court Decision The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the staff of the Joint Committee

More information

NJ CUPA HR The Affordable Care Act & Its Implication for Employers April 4, 2014

NJ CUPA HR The Affordable Care Act & Its Implication for Employers April 4, 2014 NJ CUPA HR The Affordable Care Act & Its Implication for Employers April 4, 2014 About NJBIA Represents 21,000 companies of all sizes and types, which employ over 1 million workers in the State. Advocate

More information

Health Insurance Affordability Study

Health Insurance Affordability Study Health Insurance Affordability Study Minnesota Department of Health January, 2009 Division of Health Policy Health Economics Program PO Box 64882 St. Paul, MN 55164-0882 (651) 201-3550 www.health.state.mn.us

More information

Issue Brief. Small Firm Self-Insurance Under the Affordable Care Act. Matthew Buettgens and Linda J. Blumberg OVERVIEW

Issue Brief. Small Firm Self-Insurance Under the Affordable Care Act. Matthew Buettgens and Linda J. Blumberg OVERVIEW November 2012 Issue Brief Small Firm Self-Insurance Under the Affordable Care Act Matthew Buettgens and Linda J. Blumberg The Urban Institute The mission of The Commonwealth Fund is to promote a high performance

More information

The Massachusetts Health Reform Law: Public Opinion and Perception

The Massachusetts Health Reform Law: Public Opinion and Perception The Massachusetts Health Reform Law: Public Opinion and Perception A REPORT FOR THE BLUE CROSS BLUE SHIELD OF MASSACHUSETTS FOUNDATION November 2006 Robert J. Blendon Tami Buhr Channtal Fleischfresser

More information

Transitional Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage

Transitional Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage Transitional Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage Jonathan Gruber MIT and NBER June, 2000 Paper prepared as part of Commonwealth Fund Workable Solutions Project. I am grateful to Sherry Glied, Larry

More information

Tax CHealth Insurance Tax Credits for Workers: An Efficient and Effective Administrative System Uninsured Workers

Tax CHealth Insurance Tax Credits for Workers: An Efficient and Effective Administrative System Uninsured Workers No. 09, September 2001 Tax CHealth Insurance Tax Credits for Workers: An Efficient and Effective Administrative System Uninsured Workers Lynn Etheredge Prepared with support from the Robert Wood Johnson

More information

How Many People Have Nongroup Health Insurance?

How Many People Have Nongroup Health Insurance? How Many People Have Nongroup Health Insurance? Gary Claxton, Larry Levitt, Anthony Damico, Matthew Rae The implementation of the Affordable Care Act (ACA) has focused attention on the composition of the

More information

Health Reform Employer Impact Analysis. Sample Employer. Prepared for. Date

Health Reform Employer Impact Analysis. Sample Employer. Prepared for. Date Health Reform Employer Impact Analysis Prepared for Sample Employer Date 2 Health Reform Employer Impact Analysis Overview Beginning in 2014, an applicable large employer becomes subject to what are referred

More information

TRANSCENDING OBAMACARE

TRANSCENDING OBAMACARE TESTIMONY BEFORE THE UNITED STATES CONGRESS House Committee on Energy & Commerce Subcommittee on Health TRANSCENDING OBAMACARE Achieving Truly Affordable, Patient-Centered, Near-Universal Coverage AVIK

More information

C A LIFORNIA HEALTHCARE FOUNDATION. s n a p s h o t California s Uninsured

C A LIFORNIA HEALTHCARE FOUNDATION. s n a p s h o t California s Uninsured C A LIFORNIA HEALTHCARE FOUNDATION s n a p s h o t 2008 Introduction Over the past 20 years, the percent of uninsured Californians under age 65 has continued to rise as employer-sponsored health insurance

More information

Health Care in Rural America

Health Care in Rural America Health Care in Rural America Health care in rural communities has many aspects access to physicians, dentists, nurses, and mental health services; the financial circumstances of rural hospitals; federal

More information

USES OF CONSUMER PRICE INDICES

USES OF CONSUMER PRICE INDICES USES OF CONSUMER PRICE INDICES 2 2.1 The consumer price index (CPI) is treated as a key indicator of economic performance in most countries. The purpose of this chapter is to explain why CPIs are compiled

More information

Health Insurance Exchange Study

Health Insurance Exchange Study Health Insurance Exchange Study Minnesota Department of Health February, 2008 Division of Health Policy Health Economics Program PO Box 64882 St. Paul, MN 55164-0882 (651) 201-3550 www.health.state.mn.us

More information

Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance

Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance The U.S. social security system is based mainly on the private sector; the state s responsibility is restricted to the care of the most vulnerable groups,

More information

Data Bulletin Findings from the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Insurance Component

Data Bulletin Findings from the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Insurance Component Data Bulletin Findings from the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Insurance Component Employer Sponsored Health Insurance Coverage in Ohio, 2000 By Dave Dorsky Center for Public Health Data and Statistics

More information

Access and Barriers to Post-Secondary Education Under Michigan's Welfare to Work Policies

Access and Barriers to Post-Secondary Education Under Michigan's Welfare to Work Policies Access and Barriers to Post-Secondary Education Under Michigan's Welfare to Work Policies Policy Background and Recipients' Experiences Coalition for Independence Through Education (CFITE) February 2002

More information

Free Ride: The Senate Health Bill s Approach to Employer Responsibility Means Some Large Employers Get to Take It Easy

Free Ride: The Senate Health Bill s Approach to Employer Responsibility Means Some Large Employers Get to Take It Easy Issue Brief December 2009 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Ave, NW Suite 400 Washington, DC 20009 tel: 202-293-5380 fax: 202-588-1356 www.cepr.net Free Ride: The Senate Health Bill

More information

Health Policy Online Timely Analyses of Current Trends and Policy Options

Health Policy Online Timely Analyses of Current Trends and Policy Options Health Policy Online Timely Analyses of Current Trends and Policy Options URBAN INSTITUTE No. 2 Could Subsidizing COBRA Health Insurance Coverage Help Most Low-income Unemployed? By Stephen Zuckerman,

More information

West Virginia Children and Families Funding Study

West Virginia Children and Families Funding Study West Virginia Children and Families Funding Study Update and Report on Nine Year Trends in Public Expenditures FY 1999 through FY 2007 June, 2009 Supported By: Division of Criminal Justice Services / Department

More information

HOW WILL THE ACA AFFECT SIZES? Lisa Clemans-Cope, The Urban Institute

HOW WILL THE ACA AFFECT SIZES? Lisa Clemans-Cope, The Urban Institute HOW WILL THE ACA AFFECT EMPLOYERS OF DIFFERENT SIZES? Lisa Clemans-Cope, The Urban Institute ACA impacts on employers can vary on various characteristics ti Employer size; Whether currently offer insurance;

More information

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE? Solutions and Activities to CHAPTER 1 WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE? Questions and Problems 1. Many states have language in their constitutions that requires the state to provide for an adequate level of education

More information