Chapter 17: Aggregation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Chapter 17: Aggregation"

Transcription

1 Chapter 17: Aggregation 17.1: Introduction This is a technical chapter in the sense that we need the results contained in it for future work. It contains very little new economics and perhaps contains nothing that is not reasonably obvious after a little thought, but it is nevertheless very important. The basic point concerns aggregation of supply and demand. To date most of the book has been concerned with individuals with individual demand and individual supply. To apply this material in the real world, where we are dealing with lots of individuals, we need to be able to move from the individual level to the aggregate level we need to be able to aggregate the results we have obtained. In essence there are two parts to this one obvious and one perhaps not so obvious. The first is the simple aggregation of the demand and supply functions with which we have been working. The second is the aggregation of the important concept of surplus that we have been using. With regard to the first of these we want to ask how we do the aggregation, and perhaps we are also interested in whether the aggregate functions retain the properties of the individual functions. With regard to the second of these we want to know whether the surplus as measured with respect to the aggregate function is in fact the aggregate of the surpluses as measured with respect to the individual functions. Depending on your technical sophistication you may regard this latter question as either obvious or meaningless. To make this chapter easy I use just two individuals, individual A and individual B: if we can aggregate two individuals we can aggregate more than two. 17.2: Aggregating Demand We start with a familiar example one for the demand for a discrete good. We have in fact already done this. You will recall that the demand function for a good that is discrete takes the form of a step function, with a step at every reservation price. You might then be able to anticipate the results that follow. We work with a simple example. Let us ssume that individual A would buy up to 3 units of the good and has reservation prices 10, 5 and 1 for the 3 units. So his or her demand function is as in figure 17.1.

2 For B let us assume that he or she would buy up to 2 units with reservation prices of 8 and 4 as in figure The aggregation process is simple if we remind ourselves that we should add up horizontally because the quantity demanded is on the horizontal axis and we want to find the aggregate demand at any given price. So the aggregation process is the following: for each price we find the demand of A and the demand of B and then add them together. For example, at a price of 5 A s demand is 2 and B s demand is 1 so the aggregate demand is 3. Proceeding in this way we get figure Another way of thinking about this is through reservation prices. We know that the demand curve for a discrete good is in the form of a step function with a step at every reservation price. Now we already know that A has reservation prices of 10, 5 and 1 and that B has reservation prices of 8 and 4. Taken together then (and put in order) the two individuals have reservation prices of 10, 8, 5, 4 and 1. Hence the aggregate function is as in figure You will notice that it has the same form as the individual functions in that they are step functions and so is the aggregate. This is not necessarily the case, though there are other examples where the aggregate function has the same form as the individual functions. One example is when the individual demand functions all have the same intercept on the vertical axis. We will present this algebraically. Suppose A s demand function is q A = 10 p so that A s demand becomes zero at a price of 10. Suppose that B s demand function is q B = 20 2p so that B s demand becomes zero also at a price of 10. Now find the aggregate demand. If Q denotes the aggregate demand then Q = q A + q B = (10 p) + (20 2p) = 30 3p. The aggregate demand function is Q = 30 3p. You will see that the aggregate demand becomes zero also a price of 10. This is a second example where the aggregate function has the same form as the individual functions.

3 But this is not always the case. Consider the more general case of linear individual demand functions. We present this case graphically as the algebra is messy while it is clear from the graphs what is happening. We start with A. His or her demand function is linear. The same is true for B. When we aggregate we have to be careful. Remember that we are adding up horizontally. Note that A does not start buying until the price is below 10 whereas B does not start buying until the price is below 7. Therefore when looking at the aggregate, when the price is between 7 and 10, only A is in the market and therefore the aggregate function in this price range is simply A s demand. For prices below 7 however both A and B are in the market. We thus get the aggregate demand of figure Note that below a price of 7 A s demand is linear in price and so is B s. It follows that the sum of their demands must also be linear in price.

4 Note the kink at the price of 7. This is the price at which B enters the market. You will note that, whereas the individual demand curves are linear the aggregate demand curve is piecewise linear it has a different form from the functions from which it was aggregated. This is almost certainly going to be the case. Note moreover that while the aggregate demand is a function of the price of the good it will, in general, also be a function of all the individual incomes. Only in very exceptional circumstances will aggregate demand be a function of the price of the good and aggregate income. To show this let us do a little algebra. Suppose there are two goods, good 1 and good 2, with prices p 1 and p 2, and two individuals A and B with incomes m A and m B, and we denote the demand for individual A for good 1 as q 1 A and so on, then, in general we have that the demands are given by q 1 A = f 1 A (p 1, p 2, m A ) and q 1 B = f 1 B (p 1, p 2, m B ) for good 1 and similarly for good 2, where f 1 (.) and f 2 (.) are two functions whose form depends upon the preferences of the two individuals. The aggregate demand for good 1 is therefore given by: Q 1 = q 1 A + q 1 B = f 1 (p 1, p 2, m A ) + f 2 (p 1, p 2, m B ) Only in very special circumstances can we write this as Q 1 = f 1 (p 1, p 2, m) where m = m A + m B is the aggregate income of the two individuals. One circumstance in which we can do this is when the individual functions are linear in the variables and the coefficient on income is the same for both individuals. We then have and so the aggregate demand is q 1 A = a 0 + a 1 p 1 +a 2 p 2 + cm A and q 1 B = b 0 + b 1 p 1 +b 2 p 2 + cm B Q 1 = (a 0 + b 0 ) + (a 1 + b 1 ) p 1 + (a 2 + b 2 ) p 2 + cm So the aggregate demand is dependent only on the prices and the aggregate income. In other words the distribution of income between the two individuals does not affect aggregate demand. The reason is simple: if we take money away from A and give it to B then A reduces his or her demand for the good while B increases it by exactly the same amount. Note that if the coefficients on income in the individual equations are different then the aggregate demand depends not only on the aggregate income but also on its distribution. This latter point is important as it shows that, except in rather special cases, changing the distribution of income in society, while keeping the aggregate income of society fixed, will change the aggregate demand for a good or a service. This means that changing the distribution of income in society will change the demand. An obvious example is the demand for food if we take money away from the rich and give it to the poor, the demand for food will rise because the rich will reduce less their consumption of food than the poor will increase their consumption. 17.3: Aggregating Buyer Surplus

5 You may be wondering whether our result about the buyer s surplus survives aggregation. If you recall well you will realise that we have already answered this question as far as a discrete good is concerned. Let us recall this point using the demand function above. We take a particular example. Suppose that A and B both can buy any amount that they wish at a price of 4. What are their individual demands and surpluses? Well A demands 2 units and has a surplus on the first unit of 6 and a surplus on the second of 1 (recall this his or her reservation prices are 10, 5 and 1) giving a total surplus of 7 at a price of 4. B demands either 1 or 2 units and his or her surplus is 4 on the first unit and 0 on the second (if bought, recall this his or her reservation prices are 8 and 4) giving a total surplus of 4 at a price of 4. The total surplus of the two individuals is 11. Let us now look at the surplus as measured with respect to the aggregate demand curve. Again take a price of 4. The aggregate demand curve is that of figure 17.3 and the surplus measured in the usual way the area between the price paid and the aggregate demand curve is illustrated in figure If we add up the areas it is equal to = 11. This is exactly equal to the aggregate surplus as measured above. Indeed when we think about it clearly must be so: we have a step at every reservation price and the difference between the reservation price and the price paid is the surplus or profit on that unit. If you know some mathematics you will realise that this must always be the case irrespective of the form of the demand curve. We are adding horizontally to get the aggregate demand curve and it must be the case that the areas also aggregate. Consider the linear demand curve example we presented graphically above. Take a price paid of 4. What is A s surplus? The area between the price paid of 4 and A s demand curve as given in figure This area is a triangle with base 6 and height 6 the surplus therefore is 18. As for B his or her surplus is the area between the price paid of 4 and B s demand curve as given in figure This area is a triangle with base 6 and height 3 the surplus is therefore 9. The total surplus is (18 + 9) = 27. Now consider the aggregate demand curve figure and work out the area between 4 and this demand curve as in figure

6 What is this area? Well, we can chop it up into two triangles formed by extending the first (upper) linear segment of the demand curve until it reaches a price of 4. The left hand triangle has a base of 6 and a height of 6 (is this familiar?) and the right hand triangle a base of 6 and height 3 (is this familiar?). The total area is thus ½ x 6 x 6 + ½ x 6 x 3 = 27 exactly as before. Indeed for the reasons that we have already stated this must always be the case. So we have the important result that: The surplus as measured from the aggregate demand curve in the usual way (by measuring the area between the price paid and the aggregate demand curve) is always equal to the aggregate surplus found by aggregating the individual surpluses. Or more simply, in the following shorthand: The aggregate of the surpluses is always equal to the surplus of the aggregate. This result is very important. What it means is that if all we are interested in is the aggregate surplus (and not in its distribution) then all we need to know is the aggregate demand curve we do not need to know the individual demand curves. 17.4: Aggregating Supply This section does for supply what section 17.2 did for demand. The methods are the same and the conclusions are the same. Again these conclusions are important. We start as in section 17.2 with a familiar example one for the supply for a discrete good. We have in fact already done this. You will recall that the supply function for a good that is discrete takes the form of a step function, with a step at every reservation price. You should be able to anticipate the results that follow. We work with a simple example. Assume that individual A would sell up to 3 units of the good and has reservation price 3, 4 and 12 for the 3 units. So his or her supply function is as in figure

7 For B assume that he or she would sell up to 2 units with reservation prices of 6 and 9 as in figure The aggregation process is simple if we remind ourselves that we should add up horizontally because the quantity supplied is on the horizontal axis and we want to find the aggregate supply at any given price. So the aggregation process is the following: for each price we find the supply of A and the supply of B and then add them together. For example, at a price of 7 A s supply is 2 and B s supply is 1 so the aggregate supply is 3. Proceeding in this way we get figure Another way of thinking about this is through reservation prices. We know that the supply curve for a discrete good is in the form of a step function with a step at every reservation price. Now we already know that A has reservation prices of 3, 4 and 12 and that B has reservation prices of 6 and 9. Taken together then (and put in order) the two individuals have reservation prices of 3, 4, 6, 9 and 12. Hence the aggregate function is as in figure You will notice that it has the same form as the individual functions in that they are step functions and so is the aggregate.

8 This is not necessarily the case, though there are other examples where the aggregate function has the same form as the individual functions. One example is when the individual supply functions all have the same intercept on the vertical axis. We will present this algebraically. Suppose A s supply function is q A = p 2 so that A s supply becomes zero at a price of 2. Suppose that B s supply function is q B = 2p 4 so that B s supply becomes zero also at a price of 2. Now find the aggregate. If Q denotes the aggregate supply then Q = q A + q B = (p 2) + (2p 4) = 3p 6. The aggregate supply function is Q = 3p 6. You will see that the aggregate supply becomes zero also a price of 2. This is a second example where the aggregate function has the same form as the individual functions. But this is not always the case. Consider the more general case of linear individual supply functions. We present this case graphically as the algebra is messy, while it is clear from the graphs what is happening. We start with A. His or her supply function is linear. The same is true for B. When we aggregate we have to be careful. Remember that we are adding up horizontally. Note that A does not start selling until the price is above 4 whereas B does not start selling until the price is above 2. Therefore when looking at the aggregate, when the price is between 2 and 4, only B is in the market and therefore the aggregate function in this price range is simply B s supply. For prices above 4 however both A and B are in the market. We thus get the aggregate supply of figure Note that above a price of 4, A s supply is linear in the price and so is B s so the aggregate demand curve must also be linear in the price.

9 Note the kink at the price of 4. This is the price at which A enters the market. You will note that, whereas the individual supply curves are linear the aggregate supply curve is piecewise linear it has a different form from the functions from which it was aggregated. This is almost certainly going to be the case. Note moreover that while the aggregate supply is a function of the price of the good it will, in general, also be a function of all the individual incomes. Only in very exceptional circumstances will aggregate supply be a function of the price of the good and aggregate income. To show this let us do a little algebra. Suppose there are two goods, good 1 and good 2, with prices p 1 and p 2, and two individuals A and B with incomes m A and m B, and we denote the supply for individual A for good 1 as q 1 A and so on, then, in general we have that the supplies are given by q 1 A = f 1 A (p 1, p 2, m A ) and q 1 B = f 1 B (p 1, p 2, m B ) for good 1 and similarly for good 2, where f 1 (.) and f 2 (.) are two functions whose form depends upon the preferences of the two individuals. The aggregate supply good 1 is therefore given by: Q 1 = q 1 A + q 1 B = f 1 (p 1, p 2, m A ) + f 2 (p 1, p 2, m B ) Only in very special circumstances can we write this as Q 1 = f 1 (p 1, p 2, m) where m = m A + m B is the aggregate income of the two individuals. One circumstance in which we can do this is when the individual functions are linear in the variables and the coefficient on income is the same for both individuals. We then have and so the aggregate supply is q 1 A = a 0 + a 1 p 1 +a 2 p 2 + cm A and q 1 B = b 0 + b 1 p 1 +b 2 p 2 + cm B Q 1 = (a 0 + b 0 ) + (a 1 + b 1 ) p 1 + (a 2 + b 2 ) p 2 + cm So the aggregate supply is dependent only on the prices and the aggregate income. In other words the distribution of income between the two individuals does not affect aggregate supply. The reason is simple: if we take money away from A and give it to B then A increases his or her supply of the good while B decreases it by exactly the same amount. Note that if the coefficients on income in the individual equations are different then the aggregate supply depends not only on the aggregate

10 income but also on its distribution. We get the result that the distribution of income in society may affect the aggregate supply. 17.5: Aggregating Seller Surplus This section does for supply what section 17.3 did for demand. The methods are the same and the conclusions are the same. Again these conclusions are important. You should be able to deduce by now that our result about the seller s surplus survives aggregation. If you recall well you will realise that we have already answered this question as far as a discrete good is concerned. Let us recall the story using the first supply function above. We take a particular example. Suppose that A and B both can sell any amount that they wish at a price of 8. What are their individual supplies and surpluses? Well A supplies 2 units and has a surplus on the first unit of 5 and a surplus on the second of 4 (recall this his or her reservation prices are 3, 4 and 12) giving a total surplus of 9 at a price of 8. B supplies 1 unit and his or her surplus is 2 ( recall his or her reservation prices are 6 and 9). The total surplus of the two individuals is 11. Let us now look at the surplus as measured with respect to the aggregate supply curve. Again take a price of 8. The aggregate supply curve is that of figure and the surplus measured in the usual way the area between the price paid and the aggregate supply curve is illustrated in figure If we add up the areas it is equal to = 11. This is exactly equal to the aggregate surplus as measured above. Indeed when we think about it clearly must be so: we have a step at every reservation price and the difference between the reservation price and the price received is the surplus or profit on that unit. If you know some mathematics you will realise that this must always be the case irrespective of the form of the supply curve. We are adding horizontally to get the aggregate supply curve and it must be the case that the areas also aggregate. Consider the linear supply curve example we presented graphically above. Take a price received of 8. What is A s surplus? The area between the price received of 8 and A s supply curve as given in figure This area is a triangle with base 12 and height 4 the surplus therefore is 24. As for B his or her surplus is the area between the price received of 8 and B s supply curve as given in figure This area is a triangle with base 12 and height 6 the surplus is therefore 36. The total surplus is ( ) = 60.

11 Now consider the aggregate supply curve figure and work out the area between 8 and this supply curve as in figure What is this area? Well, we can chop it up into two triangles formed by extending the first linear segment of the supply until it reaches a price of 8. The left hand triangle has a base of 12 and a height of 6 (is this familiar?) and the right hand triangle a base of 12 and height 4 (is this familiar?). The total area is thus ½ x 12 x 6 + ½ x 12 x 4 = 60 exactly as before. Indeed for the reasons that we have already stated this must always be the case. So we have the important result that: The surplus as measured from the aggregate supply curve in the usual way (by measuring the area between the price received and the aggregate supply curve) is always equal to the aggregate surplus found by aggregating the individual surpluses. Or more simply, in the following shorthand: The aggregate of the surpluses is always equal to the surplus of the aggregate. This result is very important. What it means is that if all we are interested in is the aggregate surplus (and not in its distribution) then all we need to know is the aggregate supply curve we do not need to know the individual supply curves. 17.6: Summary This has been an important chapter. In particular it allows us to extend our key results on surpluses to aggregate functions. In particular: The aggregate demand curve is the horizontal sum of the individual demand curves. The form of the aggregate demand curve may well be different from the form of the individual demand curves. The aggregate consumer surplus, defined as the area between the aggregate demand curve and the price paid, is always exactly equal to the sum of the individual surpluses. The aggregate supply curve is the horizontal sum of the individual supply curves. The form of the aggregate supply curve may well be different from the form of the individual supply curves.

12 The aggregate seller surplus, defined as the area between the aggregate supply curve and the price received, is always exactly equal to the sum of the individual surpluses.

13

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position Chapter 27: Taxation 27.1: Introduction We consider the effect of taxation on some good on the market for that good. We ask the questions: who pays the tax? what effect does it have on the equilibrium

More information

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 1: Consumer Surplus and the Demand Curve

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 1: Consumer Surplus and the Demand Curve chapter 6 A consumer s willingness to pay for a good is the maximum price at which he or she would buy that good. >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 1: Consumer Surplus and the Demand Curve The market

More information

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline Chapter 3 The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and roducer Surplus Chapter Objectives After reading this chapter you should be able to Understand that elasticity, the responsiveness of quantity to changes

More information

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity? Elasticity I. What is Elasticity? The purpose of this section is to develop some general rules about elasticity, which may them be applied to the four different specific types of elasticity discussed in

More information

Session 7 Bivariate Data and Analysis

Session 7 Bivariate Data and Analysis Session 7 Bivariate Data and Analysis Key Terms for This Session Previously Introduced mean standard deviation New in This Session association bivariate analysis contingency table co-variation least squares

More information

Module 49 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Module 49 Consumer and Producer Surplus What you will learn in this Module: The meaning of consumer surplus and its relationship to the demand curve The meaning of producer surplus and its relationship to the supply curve Module 49 Consumer

More information

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) (Refer Slide Time: 00:28) Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) We will continue our discussion

More information

5 Systems of Equations

5 Systems of Equations Systems of Equations Concepts: Solutions to Systems of Equations-Graphically and Algebraically Solving Systems - Substitution Method Solving Systems - Elimination Method Using -Dimensional Graphs to Approximate

More information

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Review of Fundamental Mathematics Review of Fundamental Mathematics As explained in the Preface and in Chapter 1 of your textbook, managerial economics applies microeconomic theory to business decision making. The decision-making tools

More information

Math 1526 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Math 1526 Consumer and Producer Surplus Math 156 Consumer and Producer Surplus Scenario: In the grocery store, I find that two-liter sodas are on sale for 89. This is good news for me, because I was prepared to pay $1.9 for them. The store manager

More information

Linear Programming. Solving LP Models Using MS Excel, 18

Linear Programming. Solving LP Models Using MS Excel, 18 SUPPLEMENT TO CHAPTER SIX Linear Programming SUPPLEMENT OUTLINE Introduction, 2 Linear Programming Models, 2 Model Formulation, 4 Graphical Linear Programming, 5 Outline of Graphical Procedure, 5 Plotting

More information

Economics. Worksheet 11.1. Circular Flow Simulation

Economics. Worksheet 11.1. Circular Flow Simulation Worksheet 11.1 Circular Flow Simulation Please note this is a class activity. Why not suggest it to your teacher? Objective: To understand how productive resources, goods and services and money flow from

More information

Solving Quadratic Equations

Solving Quadratic Equations 9.3 Solving Quadratic Equations by Using the Quadratic Formula 9.3 OBJECTIVES 1. Solve a quadratic equation by using the quadratic formula 2. Determine the nature of the solutions of a quadratic equation

More information

In this chapter, you will learn to use cost-volume-profit analysis.

In this chapter, you will learn to use cost-volume-profit analysis. 2.0 Chapter Introduction In this chapter, you will learn to use cost-volume-profit analysis. Assumptions. When you acquire supplies or services, you normally expect to pay a smaller price per unit as the

More information

Section 1.1 Linear Equations: Slope and Equations of Lines

Section 1.1 Linear Equations: Slope and Equations of Lines Section. Linear Equations: Slope and Equations of Lines Slope The measure of the steepness of a line is called the slope of the line. It is the amount of change in y, the rise, divided by the amount of

More information

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade chapter 6 >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade One of the nine core principles of economics we introduced in Chapter 1 is that markets

More information

Week 1: Functions and Equations

Week 1: Functions and Equations Week 1: Functions and Equations Goals: Review functions Introduce modeling using linear and quadratic functions Solving equations and systems Suggested Textbook Readings: Chapter 2: 2.1-2.2, and Chapter

More information

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r),

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Chapter 0 Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Section 0-: Overview We have already explored the basics of describing single variable data sets. However, when two quantitative variables

More information

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY EXERCISE 1 Firstly, we analyze the equilibrium under the monopoly. The monopolist chooses the quantity that maximizes its profits; in particular, chooses the

More information

5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents

5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents Section 5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents 1 5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents We now review how exponents can be used to describe not only powers (such as 5 2 and 2 3 ), but also roots

More information

5.4 Solving Percent Problems Using the Percent Equation

5.4 Solving Percent Problems Using the Percent Equation 5. Solving Percent Problems Using the Percent Equation In this section we will develop and use a more algebraic equation approach to solving percent equations. Recall the percent proportion from the last

More information

LINEAR INEQUALITIES. Mathematics is the art of saying many things in many different ways. MAXWELL

LINEAR INEQUALITIES. Mathematics is the art of saying many things in many different ways. MAXWELL Chapter 6 LINEAR INEQUALITIES 6.1 Introduction Mathematics is the art of saying many things in many different ways. MAXWELL In earlier classes, we have studied equations in one variable and two variables

More information

3.3. Solving Polynomial Equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

3.3. Solving Polynomial Equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes Solving Polynomial Equations 3.3 Introduction Linear and quadratic equations, dealt within Sections 3.1 and 3.2, are members of a class of equations, called polynomial equations. These have the general

More information

I. Introduction to Taxation

I. Introduction to Taxation University of Pacific-Economics 53 Lecture Notes #17 I. Introduction to Taxation Government plays an important role in most modern economies. In the United States, the role of the government extends from

More information

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1. MATH10212 Linear Algebra Textbook: D. Poole, Linear Algebra: A Modern Introduction. Thompson, 2006. ISBN 0-534-40596-7. Systems of Linear Equations Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column

More information

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r). Chapter 4 Put-Call Parity 1 Bull and Bear Financial analysts use words such as bull and bear to describe the trend in stock markets. Generally speaking, a bull market is characterized by rising prices.

More information

-2- Reason: This is harder. I'll give an argument in an Addendum to this handout.

-2- Reason: This is harder. I'll give an argument in an Addendum to this handout. LINES Slope The slope of a nonvertical line in a coordinate plane is defined as follows: Let P 1 (x 1, y 1 ) and P 2 (x 2, y 2 ) be any two points on the line. Then slope of the line = y 2 y 1 change in

More information

The Point-Slope Form

The Point-Slope Form 7. The Point-Slope Form 7. OBJECTIVES 1. Given a point and a slope, find the graph of a line. Given a point and the slope, find the equation of a line. Given two points, find the equation of a line y Slope

More information

Part 1 Expressions, Equations, and Inequalities: Simplifying and Solving

Part 1 Expressions, Equations, and Inequalities: Simplifying and Solving Section 7 Algebraic Manipulations and Solving Part 1 Expressions, Equations, and Inequalities: Simplifying and Solving Before launching into the mathematics, let s take a moment to talk about the words

More information

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance Chapter 11 International Economics II: International Finance The other major branch of international economics is international monetary economics, also known as international finance. Issues in international

More information

price quantity q The Supply Function price quantity q

price quantity q The Supply Function price quantity q Shown below is another demand function for price of a pizza p as a function of the quantity of pizzas sold per week. This function models the behavior of consumers with respect to price and quantity. 3

More information

Pre Test Chapter 3. 8.. DVD players and DVDs are: A. complementary goods. B. substitute goods. C. independent goods. D. inferior goods.

Pre Test Chapter 3. 8.. DVD players and DVDs are: A. complementary goods. B. substitute goods. C. independent goods. D. inferior goods. 1. Graphically, the market demand curve is: A. steeper than any individual demand curve that is part of it. B. greater than the sum of the individual demand curves. C. the horizontal sum of individual

More information

Pricing I: Linear Demand

Pricing I: Linear Demand Pricing I: Linear Demand This module covers the relationships between price and quantity, maximum willing to buy, maximum reservation price, profit maximizing price, and price elasticity, assuming a linear

More information

Playing with Numbers

Playing with Numbers PLAYING WITH NUMBERS 249 Playing with Numbers CHAPTER 16 16.1 Introduction You have studied various types of numbers such as natural numbers, whole numbers, integers and rational numbers. You have also

More information

For additional information, see the Math Notes boxes in Lesson B.1.3 and B.2.3.

For additional information, see the Math Notes boxes in Lesson B.1.3 and B.2.3. EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS B.1.1 B.1.6 In these sections, students generalize what they have learned about geometric sequences to investigate exponential functions. Students study exponential functions of the

More information

Supply and Demand. A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service.

Supply and Demand. A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. Supply and Demand A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. The definition of the good is a matter of judgement: Should different locations entail different goods (and

More information

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example A Detailed Price Discrimination Example Suppose that there are two different types of customers for a monopolist s product. Customers of type 1 have demand curves as follows. These demand curves include

More information

The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease

The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease The language of percent is frequently used to indicate the relative degree to which some quantity changes. So, we often speak of percent

More information

3.2. Solving quadratic equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style

3.2. Solving quadratic equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style Solving quadratic equations 3.2 Introduction A quadratic equation is one which can be written in the form ax 2 + bx + c = 0 where a, b and c are numbers and x is the unknown whose value(s) we wish to find.

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

Profit maximization in different market structures

Profit maximization in different market structures Profit maximization in different market structures In the cappuccino problem as well in your team project, demand is clearly downward sloping if the store wants to sell more drink, it has to lower the

More information

Logo Symmetry Learning Task. Unit 5

Logo Symmetry Learning Task. Unit 5 Logo Symmetry Learning Task Unit 5 Course Mathematics I: Algebra, Geometry, Statistics Overview The Logo Symmetry Learning Task explores graph symmetry and odd and even functions. Students are asked to

More information

One Period Binomial Model

One Period Binomial Model FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 One Period Binomial Model These notes consider the one period binomial model to exactly price an option. We will consider three different methods of pricing

More information

1) Write the following as an algebraic expression using x as the variable: Triple a number subtracted from the number

1) Write the following as an algebraic expression using x as the variable: Triple a number subtracted from the number 1) Write the following as an algebraic expression using x as the variable: Triple a number subtracted from the number A. 3(x - x) B. x 3 x C. 3x - x D. x - 3x 2) Write the following as an algebraic expression

More information

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet) DEREE COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS EC 1101 PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS II FALL SEMESTER 2002 M-W-F 13:00-13:50 Dr. Andreas Kontoleon Office hours: Contact: a.kontoleon@ucl.ac.uk Wednesdays 15:00-17:00 Study

More information

Linear Programming. March 14, 2014

Linear Programming. March 14, 2014 Linear Programming March 1, 01 Parts of this introduction to linear programming were adapted from Chapter 9 of Introduction to Algorithms, Second Edition, by Cormen, Leiserson, Rivest and Stein [1]. 1

More information

Minimax Strategies. Minimax Strategies. Zero Sum Games. Why Zero Sum Games? An Example. An Example

Minimax Strategies. Minimax Strategies. Zero Sum Games. Why Zero Sum Games? An Example. An Example Everyone who has studied a game like poker knows the importance of mixing strategies With a bad hand, you often fold But you must bluff sometimes Lectures in Microeconomics-Charles W Upton Zero Sum Games

More information

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS Sensitivity Analysis 3 We have already been introduced to sensitivity analysis in Chapter via the geometry of a simple example. We saw that the values of the decision variables and those of the slack and

More information

Physics Lab Report Guidelines

Physics Lab Report Guidelines Physics Lab Report Guidelines Summary The following is an outline of the requirements for a physics lab report. A. Experimental Description 1. Provide a statement of the physical theory or principle observed

More information

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS economicsentrance.weebly.com Basic Exercises Micro Economics AKG 09 Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS Budget Constraint... 4 Practice problems... 4 Answers... 4 Supply and Demand... 7 Practice Problems...

More information

Understanding Options: Calls and Puts

Understanding Options: Calls and Puts 2 Understanding Options: Calls and Puts Important: in their simplest forms, options trades sound like, and are, very high risk investments. If reading about options makes you think they are too risky for

More information

Let s explore the content and skills assessed by Heart of Algebra questions.

Let s explore the content and skills assessed by Heart of Algebra questions. Chapter 9 Heart of Algebra Heart of Algebra focuses on the mastery of linear equations, systems of linear equations, and linear functions. The ability to analyze and create linear equations, inequalities,

More information

Functions. MATH 160, Precalculus. J. Robert Buchanan. Fall 2011. Department of Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan Functions

Functions. MATH 160, Precalculus. J. Robert Buchanan. Fall 2011. Department of Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan Functions Functions MATH 160, Precalculus J. Robert Buchanan Department of Mathematics Fall 2011 Objectives In this lesson we will learn to: determine whether relations between variables are functions, use function

More information

Solving Systems of Two Equations Algebraically

Solving Systems of Two Equations Algebraically 8 MODULE 3. EQUATIONS 3b Solving Systems of Two Equations Algebraically Solving Systems by Substitution In this section we introduce an algebraic technique for solving systems of two equations in two unknowns

More information

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions Answers to Text Questions and Problems Chapter 22 Answers to Review Questions 3. In general, producers of durable goods are affected most by recessions while producers of nondurables (like food) and services

More information

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Name: While every attempt was made to be complete in the types of problems given below, we make no guarantees about the completeness of the problems. Specifically,

More information

Estimating the Average Value of a Function

Estimating the Average Value of a Function Estimating the Average Value of a Function Problem: Determine the average value of the function f(x) over the interval [a, b]. Strategy: Choose sample points a = x 0 < x 1 < x 2 < < x n 1 < x n = b and

More information

6.4 Normal Distribution

6.4 Normal Distribution Contents 6.4 Normal Distribution....................... 381 6.4.1 Characteristics of the Normal Distribution....... 381 6.4.2 The Standardized Normal Distribution......... 385 6.4.3 Meaning of Areas under

More information

2013 MBA Jump Start Program

2013 MBA Jump Start Program 2013 MBA Jump Start Program Module 2: Mathematics Thomas Gilbert Mathematics Module Algebra Review Calculus Permutations and Combinations [Online Appendix: Basic Mathematical Concepts] 2 1 Equation of

More information

Part 1: Background - Graphing

Part 1: Background - Graphing Department of Physics and Geology Graphing Astronomy 1401 Equipment Needed Qty Computer with Data Studio Software 1 1.1 Graphing Part 1: Background - Graphing In science it is very important to find and

More information

The Graphical Method: An Example

The Graphical Method: An Example The Graphical Method: An Example Consider the following linear program: Maximize 4x 1 +3x 2 Subject to: 2x 1 +3x 2 6 (1) 3x 1 +2x 2 3 (2) 2x 2 5 (3) 2x 1 +x 2 4 (4) x 1, x 2 0, where, for ease of reference,

More information

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus Who benefits from rent controls? Who loses with price controls? How do taxes and subsidies affect the economy? Some of these questions can be analyzed using the concepts

More information

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics. Page 1 1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics. 2. Markets and Competition a. Market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. P. 66. b. These individuals

More information

Graphical Integration Exercises Part Four: Reverse Graphical Integration

Graphical Integration Exercises Part Four: Reverse Graphical Integration D-4603 1 Graphical Integration Exercises Part Four: Reverse Graphical Integration Prepared for the MIT System Dynamics in Education Project Under the Supervision of Dr. Jay W. Forrester by Laughton Stanley

More information

Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts

Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts Matt Van Essen University of Alabama Van Essen (U of A) Basic Math Concepts 1 / 66 Basic Math Concepts In this lecture we will review some basic mathematical concepts

More information

7.7 Solving Rational Equations

7.7 Solving Rational Equations Section 7.7 Solving Rational Equations 7 7.7 Solving Rational Equations When simplifying comple fractions in the previous section, we saw that multiplying both numerator and denominator by the appropriate

More information

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium 3 Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium The price of vanilla is bouncing. A kilogram (2.2 pounds) of vanilla beans sold for $50 in 2000, but by 2003 the price had risen to $500 per kilogram. The price

More information

6 EXTENDING ALGEBRA. 6.0 Introduction. 6.1 The cubic equation. Objectives

6 EXTENDING ALGEBRA. 6.0 Introduction. 6.1 The cubic equation. Objectives 6 EXTENDING ALGEBRA Chapter 6 Extending Algebra Objectives After studying this chapter you should understand techniques whereby equations of cubic degree and higher can be solved; be able to factorise

More information

1 Mathematical Models of Cost, Revenue and Profit

1 Mathematical Models of Cost, Revenue and Profit Section 1.: Mathematical Modeling Math 14 Business Mathematics II Minh Kha Goals: to understand what a mathematical model is, and some of its examples in business. Definition 0.1. Mathematical Modeling

More information

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS Due the Week of June 23 Chapter 8 WRITE [4] Use the demand schedule that follows to calculate total revenue and marginal revenue at each quantity. Plot

More information

MODERN APPLICATIONS OF PYTHAGORAS S THEOREM

MODERN APPLICATIONS OF PYTHAGORAS S THEOREM UNIT SIX MODERN APPLICATIONS OF PYTHAGORAS S THEOREM Coordinate Systems 124 Distance Formula 127 Midpoint Formula 131 SUMMARY 134 Exercises 135 UNIT SIX: 124 COORDINATE GEOMETRY Geometry, as presented

More information

Equations, Inequalities & Partial Fractions

Equations, Inequalities & Partial Fractions Contents Equations, Inequalities & Partial Fractions.1 Solving Linear Equations 2.2 Solving Quadratic Equations 1. Solving Polynomial Equations 1.4 Solving Simultaneous Linear Equations 42.5 Solving Inequalities

More information

Correlation key concepts:

Correlation key concepts: CORRELATION Correlation key concepts: Types of correlation Methods of studying correlation a) Scatter diagram b) Karl pearson s coefficient of correlation c) Spearman s Rank correlation coefficient d)

More information

1 Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig

1 Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig Solving LPs: The Simplex Algorithm of George Dantzig. Simplex Pivoting: Dictionary Format We illustrate a general solution procedure, called the simplex algorithm, by implementing it on a very simple example.

More information

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor. ECON 3310 Homework #4 - Solutions 1: Suppose the following indicates how many units of output y you can produce per hour with different levels of labor input (given your current factory capacity): PART

More information

Numerical integration of a function known only through data points

Numerical integration of a function known only through data points Numerical integration of a function known only through data points Suppose you are working on a project to determine the total amount of some quantity based on measurements of a rate. For example, you

More information

EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS 8.1.1 8.1.6

EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS 8.1.1 8.1.6 EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS 8.1.1 8.1.6 In these sections, students generalize what they have learned about geometric sequences to investigate exponential functions. Students study exponential functions of the

More information

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Dan Collins The textbook defines a subspace of a vector space in Chapter 4, but it avoids ever discussing the notion of a quotient space. This is understandable

More information

Math 1B, lecture 5: area and volume

Math 1B, lecture 5: area and volume Math B, lecture 5: area and volume Nathan Pflueger 6 September 2 Introduction This lecture and the next will be concerned with the computation of areas of regions in the plane, and volumes of regions in

More information

3. Evaluate the objective function at each vertex. Put the vertices into a table: Vertex P=3x+2y (0, 0) 0 min (0, 5) 10 (15, 0) 45 (12, 2) 40 Max

3. Evaluate the objective function at each vertex. Put the vertices into a table: Vertex P=3x+2y (0, 0) 0 min (0, 5) 10 (15, 0) 45 (12, 2) 40 Max SOLUTION OF LINEAR PROGRAMMING PROBLEMS THEOREM 1 If a linear programming problem has a solution, then it must occur at a vertex, or corner point, of the feasible set, S, associated with the problem. Furthermore,

More information

Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors

Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors Fall 2005 Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors These notes were written by J. Peraire as a review of vectors for Dynamics 16.07. They have been adapted for Unified Engineering by R. Radovitzky. References [1] Feynmann,

More information

Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change

Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change 1 Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change Introduction This supplemental highlights how markets work and their impact on the allocation of resources. This feature will investigate

More information

Teaching and Learning Guide 3: Linear Equations Further Topics

Teaching and Learning Guide 3: Linear Equations Further Topics Guide 3: Linear Equations Further Topics Table of Contents Section 1: Introduction to the guide...3 Section : Solving simultaneous equations using graphs...4 1. The concept of solving simultaneous equations

More information

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Options These notes consider the way put and call options and the underlying can be combined to create hedges, spreads and combinations. We will consider the

More information

1 Error in Euler s Method

1 Error in Euler s Method 1 Error in Euler s Method Experience with Euler s 1 method raises some interesting questions about numerical approximations for the solutions of differential equations. 1. What determines the amount of

More information

Cumulative Diagrams: An Example

Cumulative Diagrams: An Example Cumulative Diagrams: An Example Consider Figure 1 in which the functions (t) and (t) denote, respectively, the demand rate and the service rate (or capacity ) over time at the runway system of an airport

More information

3.1. Solving linear equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style

3.1. Solving linear equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style Solving linear equations 3.1 Introduction Many problems in engineering reduce to the solution of an equation or a set of equations. An equation is a type of mathematical expression which contains one or

More information

Figure 1.1 Vector A and Vector F

Figure 1.1 Vector A and Vector F CHAPTER I VECTOR QUANTITIES Quantities are anything which can be measured, and stated with number. Quantities in physics are divided into two types; scalar and vector quantities. Scalar quantities have

More information

Preliminary Mathematics

Preliminary Mathematics Preliminary Mathematics The purpose of this document is to provide you with a refresher over some topics that will be essential for what we do in this class. We will begin with fractions, decimals, and

More information

Algebra II A Final Exam

Algebra II A Final Exam Algebra II A Final Exam Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. Evaluate the expression for the given value of the variable(s). 1. ; x = 4 a. 34 b.

More information

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only The Keynesian Cross Some instructors like to develop a more detailed macroeconomic model than is presented in the textbook. This supplemental material provides a concise description of the Keynesian-cross

More information

Algebra I Notes Relations and Functions Unit 03a

Algebra I Notes Relations and Functions Unit 03a OBJECTIVES: F.IF.A.1 Understand the concept of a function and use function notation. Understand that a function from one set (called the domain) to another set (called the range) assigns to each element

More information

Activity 6 Graphing Linear Equations

Activity 6 Graphing Linear Equations Activity 6 Graphing Linear Equations TEACHER NOTES Topic Area: Algebra NCTM Standard: Represent and analyze mathematical situations and structures using algebraic symbols Objective: The student will be

More information

Tastes and Indifference Curves

Tastes and Indifference Curves Chapter 4 Tastes and Indifference Curves Individuals try to do the best they can given their circumstances. 1 This was our starting point when we introduced the topic of microeconomics in Chapter 1, and

More information

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity Perfectly Competitive Markets It is essentially a market in which there is enough competition that it doesn t make sense to identify your rivals. There are so many competitors that you cannot single out

More information

Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section

Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section What is algebra? Operations with algebraic terms Mathematical properties of real numbers Order of operations What is Algebra? Algebra is

More information

5.3 The Cross Product in R 3

5.3 The Cross Product in R 3 53 The Cross Product in R 3 Definition 531 Let u = [u 1, u 2, u 3 ] and v = [v 1, v 2, v 3 ] Then the vector given by [u 2 v 3 u 3 v 2, u 3 v 1 u 1 v 3, u 1 v 2 u 2 v 1 ] is called the cross product (or

More information

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x 2 + + a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x 2 + + a 2n x n = b 2.

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x 2 + + a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x 2 + + a 2n x n = b 2. Chapter 1 LINEAR EQUATIONS 1.1 Introduction to linear equations A linear equation in n unknowns x 1, x,, x n is an equation of the form a 1 x 1 + a x + + a n x n = b, where a 1, a,..., a n, b are given

More information

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR EXERCISES 2. Draw the indifference curves for the following individuals preferences for two goods: hamburgers and beer. a. Al likes beer but hates hamburgers. He always prefers

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 9-1 Explain what relationships are shown by (a) the consumption schedule, (b) the saving schedule, (c) the investment-demand curve, and (d) the investment schedule.

More information