Education and Economic Growth

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Education and Economic Growth"

Transcription

1 214/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/15/REV. Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 213/4 Teaching and learning: Achieving quality for all Education and Economic Growth Amparo Castelló-Climent 213 This paper was commissioned by the Education for All Global Monitoring Report as background information to assist in drafting the 213/4 report. It has not been edited by the team. The views and opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the EFA Global Monitoring Report or to UNESCO. The papers can be cited with the following reference: Paper commissioned for the EFA Global Monitoring Report 213/4, Teaching and learning: Achieving quality for all For further information, please contact

2 Education and Economic Growth* Amparo Castelló-Climent University of Valencia March 213 Abstract Using the new data set by Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212), this paper reassesses the relationship between inequality in the distribution of education and economic growth. For a sample that covers 142 countries during the period , the system-gmm estimates show that an increase in.1 points in the Gini coefficient is associated with a.53 percentage-point reduction in the per capita GDP growth rates. The results also suggest that it is the distribution of education of the "parents" what has a greater influence on growth. When the age structure of the working-age population is accounted for, the negative effect of a more unequal distribution of education in the older generations is larger than the negative effect of a more unequal distribution of education in the younger groups. JEL classification: I25, O11, O5 Key words: Distribution of education, attainment levels, age structure, * Contact: Amparo Castelló-Climent, Institute for International Economics, Facultad de Economía, University of Valencia, Campus dels Tarongers s/n, Valencia, Spain. amparo.castello@uv.es.

3 1- Introduction Many studies that have analyzed the relationship between the distribution of education and economic growth have used data on human capital inequality measures by Castelló and Doménech (22), based on the educational attainment levels by Barro and Lee (21). However, recent studies have shown that the perpetual inventory method in Barro and Lee (21) suffers from several problems. The main drawback is that it utilizes very few census data points and depends crucially on enrollment rates, which are usually criticized for being overstated in developing countries. Cohen and Soto (27) and de la Fuente and Doménech (26) illustrate that Barro and Lee (21) data show implausible time series profiles for some countries. As Castelló and Doménech (22) utilizes the Barro and Lee s (21) data set, the inequality measures are subject to the same criticisms as the average years of schooling. To overcome these shortcomings, Barro and Lee (21) have compiled a new data set on educational attainments that uses more information from census data and a new methodology that makes use of disaggregated data by age groups. As a result, the new data set is less subject to measurement error than previous sources. The improved attainment levels are used by Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212) to update the indicators of human capital inequality. The new data set, that comprises the Gini coefficient and the distribution of education by quintiles, is available for 146 countries from 195 to 21 in a 5 year span and include a total of 1898 observations. The data set covers most of the countries in the world including data for 23 North America and Western European countries, 17 countries in Central and Eastern Europe, 5 countries in Central Asia, 21 countries in East Asia and the Pacific region, 25 countries in Latin America and the Caribbean, 8 countries in South and West Asia, 31 countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and 16 Arab States. Using the new data set on human capital inequality indicators, this paper reassesses the relationship between inequality in the distribution of education and economic growth. The results indicate the negative effect on growth of a more unequal distribution of education is quite robust. In a sample that includes 4 more countries and extends the period of analysis up to 21, as compared to the existing literature, the estimated coefficient of the Gini index is -.53, which is similar to previous findings. The system-gmm estimates suggest that a.1 point reduction in the Gini coefficient is associated with a.53 percentage-point increase per year in the growth rates of real per capita GDP. Considering that the average growth rate of the Sub-Saharan African region during this period is about.8 percentage points, the quantitative effect of a greater inequality in the distribution of education is economically meaningful. The paper also analyzes whether the effect on growth of the level and distribution of education depends on the age structure of the working-age population (25-64 years old). Interestingly, the findings reveal that the average years of schooling of the younger and older cohorts have similar effects on the growth rates. However, the influence of the distribution of education differs across age groups. The estimated coefficient of the human capital Gini coefficient of the older population (4-64 years old) is twice as high as the estimated coefficient of the Gini index in the younger age group (25-39 years old). This evidence is in line with some of the channels that suggest a negative influence of human capital inequality on economic growth. For instance, the demographic channels show that a more unequal distribution of education of the parents may influence future investment in human capital and growth by

4 increasing fertility rates (De la Croix and Doepke, 23) and by reducing life expectancy (Castelló-Climent and Doménech, 28). The paper is organized as follows. Next Section surveys the literature. Section 3 discusses the data and the econometric model to be estimated. Section 4 contains an illustration of the evolution of education over time for different regions. Results are displayed in Section 5. The analysis of the education by age groups is displayed in Section 6. Finally, Section 7 contains the conclusions reached. 2- Literature Review Human capital is a fundamental source of economic grow in most theoretical models (e.g. Lucas, 1988, Romer, 199). However, the effect of education on economic growth has been under debate in the empirical literature. Bils and Klenow (2) calibrate a model and find that most of the relationship between schooling and growth, found in Barro (1991), can be explained by a channel that goes from expected growth to schooling instead of from schooling to growth. Another challenging finding is that by Pritchett (21), who in a growth accounting regression shows that the impact of growth in educational capital on growth of per worker GDP is negative. According to Pritchett, explanations for the absence of positive returns in education at the macro level could be that educated individuals work in unproductive sectors, that the supply of educated labor could have been expanded whereas the demand had been stagnated or that the quality of schooling has been so low that it has not increased cognitive skills or productivity. Recent evidence, however, shows that previous findings were driven by low quality of education data. Krueger and Lindahl (21) show that the growth regressions reported by Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) and Pritchett (21) are influenced by measurement error. Cohen and Soto (27) and De la Fuente and Doménech (26) provide new data sets on educational attainments that overcome the shortcomings of previous sources, and provide evidence that the counterintuitive results on human capital and growth can be attributed to poor quality in the data. When the signal-to-noise ratio is increased in the data, the contribution of investment in education to productivity growth is relevant. The empirical evidence also shows that it is not only important that children attend school as many years as possible, but also how much do they learn while in school. Hanushek and Kimko (2) pointed out that the average years of education is an imperfect measure of human capital. When they use data on international student achievement tests, the findings reveal that cognitive skills rise substantially the explanatory power of human capital in growth regressions. Hanushek and Woessmann (212) develop a new data series on cognitive skills and confirm that differences in cognitive skills lead to economically significant differences in economic growth. Other strand of the literature indicates that inequality in the distribution of education is another relevant dimension to consider when analyzing the effect of human capital on economic growth. In a cross-section of 83 countries, Castelló and Doménech (22) show that, other things being equal, countries with greater inequality in the distribution of education in 196 had lower growth rates during the period

5 Nevertheless, cross-section estimators may be biased because of variables being omitted from the model, and because they do not properly address the treatment of some explanatory variables that, according to the theory, should be considered as endogenous. Both remarks appear to be extremely important in the relationship between income inequality and economic growth. For example, while cross-section regressions report that greater income inequality has a negative impact on the growth rates of per capita income (e.g. Alesina and Rodrik, 1994; Persson and Tabellini, 1994; Perotti, 1996), panel data models that control for country-specific effects suggest that the relationship between income inequality and economic growth is positive (Forbes 2). To analyze the robustness of the effect on growth of human capital inequality, Castelló-Climent (21a) estimates a dynamic panel data model and finds that both crosssection and panel data display a negative and significant effect of human capital inequality on economic growth. 1 Most of the empirical literature on the influence of inequality on growth has documented a reduced-form relationship in which an inequality variable (e.g. income, education, land) is added to the set of explanatory variables in a standard growth equation. However, estimating the reduced form of the model sheds no light on the underlying mechanism through which inequality influences investment and growth. In fact, theoretical arguments point to several competing channels, and estimating the reduced form does not yield any information regarding which mechanism is important or how it influences this link. In the case of the distribution of human capital, there are several channels that suggest a negative influence on growth of a more unequal distribution of education. Castelló-Climent and Doménech (28) develop a model that analyzes how human capital inequality may discourage growth by reducing life expectancy and investment in education, rather than by increasing fertility, as in De la Croix and Doepke (23) and Moav (25). Other papers show that restrictions in the credit market impede poor families to undertake profitable investment projects (e.g. Galor and Zeira, 1993; Piketty, 1997; Aghion and Bolton, 1997; Mookherjee and Ray, 23). Castelló-Climent (21b) analyzes the channels through which human capital inequality may influence growth and show that the demographic channels and the credit market imperfection approach are able to explain the entire impact of human capital inequality on economic growth. 3- Methodology and Data The model estimated in this paper is a broaden version of the neoclassical growth model that includes the convergence property, other initial conditions, and additional variables that determine the steady state. A general specification that represents this model can be written as follows: 1 Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212) suggest that while human capital inequality data might have enough signal in both cross-section and panel data models, the rather stability of the income Gini coefficient over time may be a potential explanation for the mixed evidence found in the literature that analyses the effect of income inequality on economic growth.

6 (ln y i,t -ln y i,t-τ )/τ = α ln y i,t-τ + β H i,t-τ + γ Gini i,t-τ h + X i,t-τ δ + u it where y i,t is the real GDP per capita in country i measured at year t, τ is the number of years of the whole period, H is an indicator of the initial level of human capital, proxied by the average years of schooling of the adult population, Gini h is the Gini coefficient of the distribution of education, X is a matrix including k explanatory variables, u it is the error term, and α, β, γ, and δ represent the parameters of interest that are estimated. In order to assess the relationship between the initial level of education and its effect on the long run growth rate, we first estimate a cross-section equation by OLS. In this equation we want to compute the effect of the average years of education and the Gini coefficient of education, measured in 1965, on the average growth rate over the period One of the main criticisms of this kind of regressions is that cross-section estimators may be biased due to omitted variables in the model. In particular these regressions fail to control for tastes, the level of technology, resource endowments, climate, institutions or any other variable specific to every country that may be an important determinant of the growth rates and may be correlated with the explanatory variables included in the estimated equation. Measuring these variables is troublesome because sometimes they are unobservable. However, if these variables are constant over time we can control for them including a country specific effect in the model. To do so we could detach the error term in (1) into three different components: u it = ξ t + ρ i + ε it where ξ t is a time specific effect, ρ i stands for specific characteristics of every country that are constant over time and ε it collects the error term that varies across countries and across time. Using (2) we could rewrite (1) as follows: ln yi,t = α ln yi,t-τ + β Hi,t-τ + γ Ginii,t-τh + Xi,t-τ δ + ξt + ρi + εit If we consider τ different from one, we have that α=τα+1, β_{i}=τβ_{i}, γ=τγ, δ=τδ, and ε_{i,t}=τε_{i,t}. In addition to omitted variables, cross-section regressions do not tackle the problem of endogeneity of some explanatory variables. We address all concerns by estimating equation (3) with the system GMM estimator, proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and 2 The real GDP per capita and the measures of education are available from 195 to 21. However, so that the estimates are as close as possible as the model estimated with the system GMM, which uses lagged values as instruments, we run the cross-section regresions from 1965 to 21.

7 Bond (1998). The idea of this estimator is to take first differences to eliminate the source of inconsistency, that is ρ_{i}, and use the levels of the explanatory variables lagged two and further periods as instruments, as long as the errors are not second order serially correlated and that the explanatory variables are weakly exogenous. The difference equations are combined with equations in levels, which are instrumented with the lagged first differences of the corresponding explanatory variables. In order to use these additional instruments, we need the identifying assumption that the first differences of the explanatory variables are not correlated with the specific effect, that is, although the specific effect may be correlated to the explanatory variables, the correlation is supposed to be constant over time. If the moment conditions are valid, Blundell and Bond (1998) show that in Monte Carlo simulations the system GMM estimator performs better than the first difference GMM estimator proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991). We can test the validity of the moment conditions by using the conventional test of overidentifying restrictions proposed by Sargan (1958) and Hansen (1982) and by testing the null hypothesis that the error term is not second order serially correlated. Furthermore, we will test the validity of the additional moment conditions associated with the level equation with the difference Hansen test. In this paper, the inequality in the distribution of education is measured by the education Gini coefficient and the distribution of education by quintiles. The Gini coefficient is an aggregate measure of inequality and can be defined from the Lorenz Curve diagram, which plots the cumulative education share of the total years of schooling attained by the bottom X percent of the population. For instance, if 2 percent of the population gets 2 percent of the total education, 4 percent of the population gets 4 percent of the education and so on, there is total equality. The line of equality, therefore, would be represented by the 45 degree line. Specifically, the Gini coefficient is defined as the ratio of the area that lies between the line of equality and the Lorenz curve, over the total area under the line of equality. If each individual had the same education, the Lorenz curve is equal to the equality line and the Gini coefficient is equal to zero. On the other extreme, if education is highly concentrated and one individual gets all education, the Lorenz curve will be equal to zero for all education percentiles and 1 for the 1 percentile. In this case, the Lorenz curve is equal to the total area below the equality line and the Gini coefficient is equal to one. As an illustration, Table 1 contains the distribution of education of Paraguay and Peru. In 1965, Paraguay and Peru had similar years of education, 3.37 and 3.5, respectively. However, the distribution of education was more unequal in Peru than in Paraguay. The Gini coefficient in Peru was.49 and in Paraguay was.34. The distribution of education by quintiles, that is, the share of education attained by the lowest 2, 4, 6 and 8 percent of the lowest educated individuals can be used to plot the Lorenz curve. As displayed in Figure 1, the Lorenz curve for Paraguay indicates that the share of education attained by the 2 percent of the population with the lowest education was zero. The 4 percent of the lowest educated population had percent of the education, the 6 percent of the population had 4.33 percent of the education, the 8 percent of the population had percent of the education, and the top 2 percent of the most educated people had 37.4 percent of the education. On the other hand, in spite of having similar average years of schooling, almost 4 percent of the population in Peru was illiterate, and the top 2 percent of the most educated individuals had a greater share of education than their counterparts in Paraguay (about 47 percent of the total education). As a result, the Lorenz curve of Peru is much further from the equality line than the Lorenz curve of

8 Paraguay. Thus, the higher Gini coefficient in Peru is the result of a larger area between the Lorenz curve and the equality line. There are several mathematical expressions to compute the Gini coefficient. We take the data from Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212), who use a standard formula to calculate the human capital Gini coefficient. The methodology can be defined as follows: Gini h = (1/(2H)) x i - x j n i n j where H are the average years of schooling in the population 25 years and above, i and j stand for different levels of education, x refers to the cumulative average years of schooling of each level of education and n are the share of population with a given level of education. They consider 4 levels of schooling: no schooling (), primary (1), secondary (2) and tertiary (3) education. Using the attainment levels by Barro and Lee (21), Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212) compute human capital inequality indicators for 146 countries from 195 to 21 in a five-year period span and include a total of 1898 observations. The sources of the other data used in the paper are as follows. The data on the average years of education come from the latest data set by Barro and Lee (21). This new version includes more countries and years, reduces some measurement errors and solves most of the shortcomings revealed by De la Fuente and Domenech (26) and Cohen and Soto (27). The data on real GDP per capita (lny), government spending (G/GDP), measured as government share of real GDP, and total trade (Trade), measured as exports plus imports to real GDP, are taken from the latest version of the Penn World Tables, PWT 7.1, by Heston, Summers and Aten (212). The inflation rate (Inflation), measured as the annual increment in the consumer prices, is taken from the World Development Indicators. 4- Evolution of Education over time Figure 2 displays the evolution of the average years of schooling of the population 25 years and above from 195 to 21 for different regions. 3 The figure illustrates that, despite the level of development, the average years of schooling show an increasing trend in all regions. With the exception of the regions with the lowest level of education, the relative position of each group of countries has not changed over a period of 6 years. North American and Western European countries had the largest level of education, with an average years of schooling of the total 3 Barro and Lee (21) also provide the attainment levels for the population 15 and above. Although in developing countries many people start working at early ages, the average years of schooling of the population 15 and above do not account for the population aged that complete secondary school, and the populaton aged 2-24 that complete university. Moreover, the educational attainment of the younger generation (e.g. between 15 and 24 years old) is more likely to be correlated with current income, which may exacerbate endogeneity problems in growth regressions.

9 population equal to 5.47 in 195 and 1.68 in 21. The relative position within this group of countries has also remained quite stable, with Portugal being the country with the lowest years of schooling at the beginning and at the end of the sample period (2.29 in 195 and 7.73 in 21) and the United States with the largest education level over the years (8.14 in 195 and in 21). In 21, this region is followed by Central and Eastern Europe with 1.53 years of education, Central Asia with 9.71 years, East Asia and the Pacific with 8.3 years, and Latin America and the Caribbean with 7.97 years. The most spectacular increment in the level of education has taken place in the Arab States. There are several examples that can illustrate the impressive performance in this region. For instance, Algeria has increased the average years of schooling from.9 in 195 to 7.61 in 21, Jordan from.94 to 8.65, and the United Arab Emirates from.66 to This striking numbers have changed the relative position in the group of countries at the bottom end of the distribution. Whereas the Arab States were the countries with the lowest years of schooling in 195, this group of countries overtook Sub-Saharan African region in the 197s, and South and West Asian countries in the 198s. In 21, Sub-Saharan African countries displayed the lowest years of schooling among all the regions. In spite of the high correlation between the average years of schooling and the distribution of education, the evolution of the Gini coefficient has been different to that of the years of schooling (Figure 3). For instance, North America and Western Europe is the group of countries with a more equalitarian distribution of education in 195. However, in the most recent years, this group of countries ranks number 3 in terms of equality. In 21, the countries with the greatest equality in the distribution of education are located in Central and Eastern Europe and Central Asia, with a Gini coefficient about.1. In fact, the reduction in education inequality in Central Asia is astonishing. In 195, this region ranked as the fourth region with the largest Gini coefficient (.58), whereas it is one of the regions with a more even distribution of education (.11) in 21. In the middle of the distribution we find the East Asia and the Pacific region and the Latin America and Caribbean countries, with Gini coefficients equal to.56 and.48 in 195, and.23 and.25 in 21, respectively. At the bottom of the distribution, the Arab States have reduced the Gini coefficient more than halve, changing from a value of.88 in 195 to.42 in 21. A large reduction in education inequality is also observed in Sub-Saharan Africa and South and West Asian countries. In both regions, the average Gini coefficient in 195 was about.8 and it reduced to about.45 in 21. The large reduction in human capital inequality, observed in the less developed economies, has mainly been due to a great effort to eradicate illiteracy rates over the years. As shown by Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212), the evolution of human capital inequality presents two stages. In the first stage, the variations in the human capital Gini coefficient are mostly determined by variations in the share of illiterates. In the more developed countries, however, the overall Gini coefficient is mainly driven by the Gini among the literates. 5- Education and Growth

10 In this Section we analyze the effect of education on economic growth. We first estimate equation 1 over a long time period in order to check whether the results in Castelló and Doménech (22) hold with a greater number of countries and an extended number of years. The cross-section regressions include a total of 121 countries over the period This specification allows us to test the effect of the initial level and distribution of education on economic growth in the long run. Thus, in spite of the shortcomings with the estimation of a cross-section equation, the long time period minimizes endogeneity concerns in this equation. In Table 2, the dependent variable is the growth rate of per capita GDP averaged over the period The explanatory variables include some initial conditions, such as the level of income and the level and distribution of education, measured in The share of government consumption over GDP, the ratio of exports plus imports divided by GDP, and the inflation rate are measured as an average over the whole period. The regression of the growth rate of GDP per capita on the initial level of education, proxied by the number of years of schooling, yields a coefficient of.4, with a standard error of.1 (column (1)). The result suggests that other things being equal, the countries whose adult population had a greater number of years of schooling in 1965, have experienced, on average, higher growth rates over the period The economic effect of education is also significant. The estimates imply that a one standard deviation increase in the average years of schooling in 1965 (2.33 years) would increase per capita GDP growth by about.9 percentage points per year. For example, if Central African Republic had increased the initial average years of education from.497 to the mean value for the Sub-Saharan African countries (1.32), then Central African Republic could have grown about.3 (.81*.4) percentage points faster per annum. Likewise, if in 1965 Haiti had increased its average years of education from.784 to the mean value for the Latin American and the Caribbean countries (3.621), then Haiti could have grown about.11 (2.837*.4) percentage points faster per annum. In column (2), we include the education Gini coefficient, instead of the average years of schooling, as the initial measure of schooling. The estimated coefficient is negative and statistically significant at the 1 per cent level, suggesting that the initial distribution of education is also an important predictor of future growth. To know whether the average years of schooling or the distribution of education is more important for growth is difficult to prove. The reason is that both measures are highly correlated and controlling for both variables generates a multicollinearity problem. The correlation between the average years of education and the Gini coefficient of education in 1965 for the 121 countries included in the regression is In fact, column (3) shows that the coefficient of the average years of education stops being statistically significant, and the significance of the Gini coefficient also reduces, when both indicators are included in the set of controls. As an alternative specification, in column (4) we proxy the average education level through the average years of secondary education in the adult population. The correlation among this variable and the Gini coefficient is also high (.65) but much lower than that with the total years of education, which minimizes collinearity concerns. The results indicate that both the level of education and its distribution are important determinants of growth. For example, the estimated coefficient of -.26 of the Gini coefficient 4 Although the data on educational variables are available for 146 countries, for many of these countries the data on GDP in only available since 199 onwards (e.g. Central and Eastern Europe).

11 implies that a one standard-deviation decrease in the education Gini in 1965 (.296) would lead to higher per capita growth rates by.8 percentage points per year. The economic impact is large, as the average growth rate for Sub-Saharan African region during this period was.8 percentage points. We can use this estimate to do quantitative comparisons. Keeping in mind that there are other variables that explain the differences in growth, we can find some examples of countries with similar initial level of development, similar average years of schooling but that differ in the initial distribution of education and the subsequent economic growth rates. We focus on pair of countries within regions to minimize differences in geography, climate, political institutions or cultural values. For example, both Pakistan and India had 1.1 average years of education among their adult population in Per capita income was also similar, $82.4 in Pakistan and $786.9 in India. However, inequality in the distribution of education was lower in India (.77) than in Pakistan (.88). The estimates suggest that if in 1965 Pakistan had had the same distribution of education as that in India, the average growth rate in Pakistan could have been.3 percentage points higher per year (.11*.26). Given that the average growth rates in India and Pakistan over the period were.33 and.23 respectively, the differences in the initial Gini coefficient could explain about one third of the actual difference in the growth rates. Another example could be that of Albania and Bulgaria, which had similar initial per capita income and similar years of education (5.54 years in Albania and 5.98 years in Bulgaria) but the Gini coefficient was twice as much in Albania (.4) than in Bulgaria (.19). The estimates suggest that had Albania similar Gini coefficient as that in Bulgaria, its average growth rate could have been.5 percentage points higher, which accounts for about 38 percent of the actual difference in their per capita income growth rates. Rwanda and Sierra Leone also had the same per capita income in 1965 ($65) and similar average years of education (.54 years in Rwanda and.53 years in Sierra Leone). The distribution of education, however, was different; the Gini coefficient was.89 in Rwanda and.95 in Sierra Leone. The estimates suggest that the difference in the initial distribution of education can account for the whole difference in the actual average growth rates in both countries, which was.12 and.1, respectively. Although the Gini coefficient has the advantage of summarizing the whole distribution of education in a single index, it does not provide any information on whether the different parts of the education distribution have similar effects on the growth rates. To get a greater insight on this regard, we test the effect on growth of the first, third and fifth quintiles in the distribution of education, and the ratio of the bottom to the top quintile. Column (5) shows the estimate for the first education quintile. Results suggest that the initial share of the education attained by the 2 percent of the population with the lowest education did not have any statistically significant effect on the subsequent growth rates. Instead, it is the education attained by the cumulative third quintile, and the top 2 per cent of the population that matter for growth. The estimated coefficients for both indicators are equal, with opposite sign, and almost similar to that of the Gini coefficient (columns (6) and (7)). While the results with the OLS estimator can give a good approximate of the long term effect of education on growth, one of the main criticisms of this kind of regressions is that they suffer from two inconsistency sources. On the one hand, cross-section estimations fail to control for specific characteristics of countries whose omission may bias the coefficient of the explanatory variables. On the other hand, they do not address properly the treatment of some explanatory variables that should be considered to be endogenous. As discussed in Section 3, we address

12 these concerns with the estimation of a dynamic panel data model with the system GMM estimator. The results of estimating equation (3) with the system GMM are reported in Table 3. 5 The regressions include 142 countries for the period ranging from 1965 to 21. The analysis updates previous work by Castelló-Climent (21b) by adding 4 more countries and extending the period up to 21. The first column analyzes the effect of the average years of education on the growth rate of real per capita GDP. Controlling for other determinants of growth, the results show that a better educated adult population has a positive and statistically significant effect on the subsequent growth rates. The estimated coefficient is positive and statistically significant at the 1 percent level. The estimate is also economically meaningful and consistent with the magnitude obtained with OLS. The system-gmm estimate is.5 with a standard error equal to.2. The coefficient suggests that if Thailand average years of schooling had been at the average of the East Asia and the Pacific region (7.88) instead of the actual 5.88 in year 25, it would have grown.1 percentage points faster per year (2*.5). Similarly, if Guatemala years of schooling had been equal to that at the average of the Latin America and the Caribbean region (7.47) instead of its 3.61 years in 25, it could have growth.19 percentage points faster per year. Many Sub-Saharan African countries have made a great effort in reducing illiteracy rates over the years. However, we still find countries in which the majority of the children do not have primary education. For example, in Niger, 8 percent of the adult population did not have formal education in 25. As a result, the average years of schooling was only 1.29 years. The estimates suggest that had Niger the same number of years as the average years of education in Sub-Saharan African countries (4.62), the growth rate in Niger could had been.17 percentage points higher per year. The estimates also corroborate the negative and statistically significant effect on growth of a more uneven distribution of education. Column (2) shows the estimated coefficient of the Gini index is negative and statistically significant at the 1 percent level. However, none coefficient is statistically significant once the average years of education and the Gini coefficient are included in the set of controls (column (3)), suggesting the collinearity problem between both variables is even higher in the panel data model than in the OLS estimates. Instead, in column (4) we proxy the average level of education by the average years of secondary education in the adult population. Results show the estimated coefficient of the Gini index is -.53, which is similar to the estimates with the system-gmm in smaller samples with fewer countries (e.g. Castelló-Climent, 21b), suggesting the quantitative effect is robust across samples. The estimate indicates the economic effect of a greater uneven distribution of education is important. For instance, both Liberia and Malawi had 3.4 average years of education in 25. However, the distribution of education was quite different; whereas the Gini 5 To avoid overfitting the model, the instruments used are the second lag of each explanatory variable in the difference equation, and the lagged first difference of the corresponding explanatory variable in the level equation. This set of instruments guarantees the number of instruments is lower than the number of countries. The AR(2), Hansen, and difference Hansen tests, reported at the bottom of the tables, suggest that the set of instruments is valid.

13 coefficient in Liberia was.65, in Malawi was.45. The estimate suggests that if Liberia had had greater equality in the distribution of education with a Gini coefficient similar to that of Malawi, it could have grown.11 percentage points faster per year (.2*.53). This accounts for about 48 percent (.11/.23) of the actual difference in the annual income growth rate between the two countries during the period Similarly, Togo and Tanzania also had the same number of years of education (4.8) in 25 but different inequality in the distribution of education. The Gini coefficient in Togo was.53 whereas that in Tanzania was.35. According to the estimates, the difference in the distribution of education could account for about 22 percent (.1/.45) of the actual difference in the actual growth rates. More examples include Mexico and Uruguay, with similar years of schooling in 25, 7.8 and 7.9 respectively, but different distribution of education. The Gini coefficient was.27 in Mexico and.19 in Uruguay. The estimates predict that the average growth rates in Mexico could have been.4 percentage points faster per year if Mexico had had the same distribution of education as that in Uruguay. Whereas OLS estimates suggest the middle and upper part of the education distribution is what matters for growth, the system GMM estimator indicates all parts are important. The coefficients of the first, third and fifth quintiles are all statistically significant. Moreover, the ratio between the education attained by the lowest and highest 2 percent of the population has a positive and significant effect on the growth rates. Distinguishing among different parts of the distribution is important since we can find countries with similar Gini coefficient but differences in the distribution of education by quintiles. For example, in 25 Brazil and El Salvador had similar years of education, 6.6 and 6.7 respectively. The Gini coefficient was also similar,.31 in Brazil and.34 in El Salvador. The cumulative third quintile was.37 and.36, respectively. However, the first quintile was zero in El Salvador and.34 in Brazil. As a result, the ratio between the bottom to the top education quintile was.1 in Brazil and zero in El Salvador. The estimates in column (9) suggests that had El Salvador had the same ratio as that in Brazil, the average growth rate in El Salvador could have been.6 percentage points faster per year. 6- Differences in the Age Structure of the Population Barro and Lee s (21) dataset provides the attainment levels for several age groups. This information is useful since the effect of the average attainment levels and the Gini coefficient could differ across age groups, as the younger generations are more educated than the oldest ones. Figure 4 reports the average years of education of several age groups (e.g , 25-39, 4-64 and years old). The figure illustrates that over a period of 6 years, the average years of education have increased in all generations. The average years of education for the population years old was 3.64 years in 195 and increased up to 8.86 years in 21. Similarly, the average years of education for the oldest age group (65-74) was 2.28 years in 195 and raised up to 5.55 years in 21. Given that the increment has been higher in the 6 The average annual growth rate for the period was.39 in Liberia and.62 in Malawi.

14 younger generations than in the older ones, in 21 the attainment levels of the younger generations in some regions are twice as high as those of the older age groups. For example, in South and West Asia region, the average years of education of the population years old was 8.26 years in 21, while that of the population years old was only 2.97 years. Figure 5 displays the Gini coefficient across age groups. The figure illustrates a huge reduction in human capital inequality in all age groups, specially in the younger generations. The overall Gini coefficient for the population reduced from.49 in 195 to.18 in 21. Despite the general reduction, enormous differences across regions still remain. For example, the Gini coefficient of the age group is greater in Sub-Saharan African region in 21 than in North America and Western European countries in 195. In fact, the Gini coefficient for the age group in Sub-Saharan African region in 21 is similar to that of the population aged years old in North America and Western European countries in 195. The different levels of education across age groups may have important connotations for economic growth. With the process of development, countries have experienced a demographic transition from high mortality and high fertility to low mortality and low fertility. Both, fertility and mortality rates determine the age structure of the population and this has implications for growth. The reason is that while persons in the working age are productive, children and the elderly are "dependant." Therefore, a lower dependent ratio would faster economic growth since it improves the ratio of productive workers in the population (Bloom et al., 23). To analyze the effect on growth of the human capital of different age groups, we split the population aged into two groups, the younger generations, aged 25-39, and the oldest generations, aged Table 4 displays the results. As the younger generations have more human capital, we could expect that a greater share of youngest in the working age population should have a beneficial effect on the growth rates. In column (1) we test the effect on growth of having a relative younger working-age population, proxied by the ratio between the population years old divided by the population aged 4-64 years old (Population WA Youth Ratio). Results indicate the coefficient of the youth ratio of the working age population is not statistically significant at the standard levels. Thus, a relative younger work force per se is not sufficient to guarantee higher growth rates, in order to be growth enhancing, the younger generations should be educated and efficiently allocated in the labor market. 7 We test this statement in column (2), in which we multiply the population youth ratio by the corresponding years of schooling of each age group. The results indicate that the weighted ratio of the average years of schooling is positive and statistically significant at the one percent level, indicating that a greater average years of schooling of the younger generation, relative to the years of schooling of the older group, is important for growth. According to the estimates, an increase in one year of schooling of the younger generation, relative to the older one, increases the subsequent growth rates by.1 percentage points. This coefficient is significant in a statistical sense but slightly small in quantitative terms. To disentangle the effect of each age group, in columns (3) and (4) we test the effect on growth of the years of schooling of each education group separately. The results show that, although the coefficient of the younger 7 If instead of the Population WA Youth Ratio, we control for the ratio between the working age population (25-64) to the total population, in line with Bloom et al. (27), the coefficient of the share of the working age population is positive and statistically significant at the one per cent level.

15 population is slightly higher in quantitative terms, the average years of schooling of both age groups matter for growth. We then analyze the effect on growth of the age structure of the Gini of education. The results are reported in Table 5. Unlike the average years of schooling, column (1) shows the weighted ratio of the Gini coefficient between age groups is negative and statistically significant at the 1 percent level. This results suggests that the distribution of education of the relative older generations has a greater effect on growth than the distribution of education at the younger ages. The results in columns (2) and (3) corroborate this finding. Although both coefficients are negative and statistically significant, the coefficient of the Gini index of the population aged 4-64 years old is more than twice as much as that of the population years older. This result is important because it suggests that a more unequal distribution of education of the current generation will have a negative effect not only on the economic growth rates in the next few years but also in the long run growth rates that will face the next generations. Thus, reducing inequality today will also reduce long term cost, in terms of future prosperity. For example, in 25, the Gini coefficient of the younger generations, aged years old, was similar in Bolivia than in Uruguay, with a value equal to.16 in both countries. However, the Gini coefficient of the older generation was.32 in Bolivia and.19 in Uruguay. The greater inequality in the distribution of education of the older age group implies that, other things being equal, if Bolivia had had a similar level of inequality in the distribution of education in the older age group as that in Uruguay, the annual growth rate in Bolivia could have been.19 (.145*.13) percentages points higher. Similarly, in spite of having a similar inequality in the distribution of education of the younger working age population, with a Gini₂₅ ₃₉^{h} equal to.24 in Cameroon and.26 in Lesotho, the inequality in the distribution of education of the population aged 4-64 years old was.43 in Cameroon and.27 in Lesotho. The results in column (3) suggests that had Cameroon the same inequality in the distribution of education of the older population as that in Lesotho, the per capita GDP growth rate in Cameroon could have been.23 percentage points higher. A plausible explanation for this finding is that the channels through which human capital inequality discourages economic growth take place in the long term. Mechanisms that point out different fertility patterns and life expectancy among individuals with different levels of education predict that the distribution of education of the parents is what matters for growth. In these models, parents with lower human capital choose to have a higher number of children and to provide them with less education, thereby limiting the number of skilled individuals in the future and leading to reduced average levels of human capital in the economy and lower growth rates (e.g., De la Croix and Doepke 23, Moav 25)). Castelló-Climent and Doménech (28) also show that when parents' education influences their children's life expectancy, as has been shown by empirical evidence (e.g., Case et al. 22, Currie and Moretti 23), the initial distribution of education, through its impact on life expectancy, has powerful effects on a country s average rate of investment in human capital. Likewise, under imperfect credit markets and indivisibilities in the accumulation of human capital, Galor and Zeira (1993) show that the greater the share of the population credit constrained, the lower the average human capital in the economy. In this model, wealth transmission from parents to children depends on the parents human capital. As a result, the initial distribution of wealth is mainly driven by the initial distribution of human capital. In all the models, the crucial distribution of human capital is that of the parents. Thus, the distribution of education that should matter for growth is that of the previous generations, in line with the empirical findings.

16 In fact, Castelló-Climent (21) shows that demographic channels and, to a lower extent, the credit market imperfection approach, are able to explain the entire impact of human capital inequality on economic growth. Using more countries and a longer time period, we confirm this finding in columns (4) and (6). The evidence indicates that once the life expectancy and the fertility rates are included in the set of controls, the estimated coefficient of the Gini index stops being statistically significant. 7- Conclusion This paper shows the distribution of education is an important determinant of economic growth. The paper uses new indicators of education to reassess the relationship between human capital and growth for a broader number of countries and a longer time period, as compared to previous studies. The paper uses updated data sets on average years of education by Barro and Lee (21), which reduces measurement errors and solves some of the shortcomings revealed by De la Fuente and Domenech (26) and Cohen and Soto (27), and indicators of the inequality in the distribution of education by Castelló-Climent and Doménech (212). The new datasets improve the quality of the data as well as its coverage, including 146 countries from 195 to 21. The paper reveals that inequality in the distribution of education is an important determinant of economic growth. Keeping the level of education constant, a more unequal distribution of education has detrimental effects on the subsequent growth rates. When analyzing the distribution of education by age groups, the results indicate that a more unequal distribution of education today has long run costs. Unlike the effect of the average years of education, the negative effect of a more unequal distribution of education in the working age population is higher in the older generations than in the younger ones. This result suggests that it is the distribution of education of the "parents", rather than the distribution of education of the youngest, what has a greater influence on the growth rates. Many developing countries have made a great effort in reducing illiteracy rates and improving the education of the new generations. However, in 21 there were countries in which more than 5 percent of the population were still illiterate. The results in this paper indicate that increasing the level of education of the majority of the population can improve not only the standard of living of millions of people, but also the economic performance of a country in the coming years, as well as in future generations. References Alesina, A. and Rodrik, D. (1994). ``Distributive politics and economic growth", Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 19, pp Arellano, M. and S. R. Bond (1991). "Some Test of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and and Application to Employment Equations". Review of Economic Studies, 58 (2),

Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles

Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles Working Paper Nº 12/ 28 Madrid, March 2014 Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles Amparo Castelló-Climent Rafael Doménech 12/28 Working Papers Madrid, March 2014 Human Capital

More information

The Contribution of Human capital to European Economic Growth: An empirical exploration from a panel data

The Contribution of Human capital to European Economic Growth: An empirical exploration from a panel data The Contribution of Human capital to European Economic Growth: An empirical exploration from a panel data Menbere Workie Tiruneh 1 Marek Radvansky 2 Abstract The paper empirically investigates the extent

More information

IV. DEMOGRAPHIC PROFILE OF THE OLDER POPULATION

IV. DEMOGRAPHIC PROFILE OF THE OLDER POPULATION World Population Ageing 195-25 IV. DEMOGRAPHIC PROFILE OF THE OLDER POPULATION A. AGE COMPOSITION Older populations themselves are ageing A notable aspect of the global ageing process is the progressive

More information

Chapter 1. The Development Gap

Chapter 1. The Development Gap Chapter 1 The Development Gap STORIES OF CATCH-UP AND DECLINE The development gap emerged because some countries developed earlier than others. In historical perspective the Industrial Revolution : The

More information

Youth bulges and youth unemployment Youth bulges are not a major factor explaining current levels of youth unemployment

Youth bulges and youth unemployment Youth bulges are not a major factor explaining current levels of youth unemployment David Lam University of Michigan, USA, and IZA, Germany Youth bulges and youth unemployment Youth bulges are not a major factor explaining current levels of youth unemployment Keywords: Youth labor market,

More information

DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC DETERMINANTS OF SCHOOL ATTENDANCE: AN ANALYSIS OF HOUSEHOLD SURVEY DATA

DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC DETERMINANTS OF SCHOOL ATTENDANCE: AN ANALYSIS OF HOUSEHOLD SURVEY DATA BACKGROUND PAPER FOR FIXING THE BROKEN PROMISE OF EDUCATION FOR ALL DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC DETERMINANTS OF SCHOOL ATTENDANCE: AN ANALYSIS OF HOUSEHOLD SURVEY DATA By Hiroyuki Hattori, UNICEF This

More information

Growth Is Good for the Poor

Growth Is Good for the Poor Forthcoming: Journal of Economic Growth Growth Is Good for the Poor David Dollar Aart Kraay Development Research Group The World Bank First Draft: March 2000 This Draft: March 2002 Abstract: Average incomes

More information

Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment

Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment BACKGROUND RESEARCH PAPER David Lam and Murray Leibbrandt Submitted to the High Level Panel on the Post-2015 Development Agenda This paper

More information

Finance, Inequality and the Poor

Finance, Inequality and the Poor Finance, Inequality and the Poor Thorsten Beck The World Bank Asli Demirgüç-Kunt The World Bank Ross Levine* Brown University and the National Bureau of Economic Research January 26, 2007 Abstract: Financial

More information

How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth?

How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth? WP/11/12 How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth? Ari Aisen and Francisco Jose Veiga 2010 International Monetary Fund WP/11/12 IMF Working Paper Middle East and Central Asia Department How

More information

A TEACHER FOR EVERY CHILD: Projecting Global Teacher Needs from 2015 to 2030

A TEACHER FOR EVERY CHILD: Projecting Global Teacher Needs from 2015 to 2030 A TEACHER FOR EVERY CHILD: Projecting Global Teacher Needs from 2015 to 2030 UIS FACT SHEET OCTOBER 2013, No.27 According to new global projections from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics, chronic shortages

More information

The recent decline in income inequality in Brazil: magnitude, determinants and consequences. Ricardo Paes de Barros (IPEA)

The recent decline in income inequality in Brazil: magnitude, determinants and consequences. Ricardo Paes de Barros (IPEA) The recent decline in income inequality in Brazil: magnitude, determinants and consequences Ricardo Paes de Barros (IPEA) Cuidad de Guatemala, July 2007 1. Magnitude 0.610 Evolution of inequality in per

More information

Social protection and poverty reduction

Social protection and poverty reduction Social protection and poverty reduction Despite the positive economic growth path projected for Africa, the possibility of further global shocks coupled with persistent risks for households make proactive

More information

III. CHANGING BALANCE BETWEEN AGE GROUPS

III. CHANGING BALANCE BETWEEN AGE GROUPS Population Ageing 195-25 III. CHANGING BALANCE BETWEEN AGE GROUPS A. BROAD AGE GROUPS The young-old balance is shifting throughout the world The increasing proportions of aged persons have been accompanied,

More information

Part 1 RECENT STATISTICS AND TREND ANALYSIS OF ILLICIT DRUG MARKETS A. EXTENT OF ILLICIT DRUG USE AND HEALTH CONSEQUENCES

Part 1 RECENT STATISTICS AND TREND ANALYSIS OF ILLICIT DRUG MARKETS A. EXTENT OF ILLICIT DRUG USE AND HEALTH CONSEQUENCES References to Chile Part 1 RECENT STATISTICS AND TREND ANALYSIS OF ILLICIT DRUG MARKETS A. EXTENT OF ILLICIT DRUG USE AND HEALTH CONSEQUENCES El panorama mundial Cocaína In 2010, the regions with a high

More information

Only by high growth rates sustained for long periods of time.

Only by high growth rates sustained for long periods of time. Chapter 1 IntroductionandGrowthFacts 1.1 Introduction In 2000, GDP per capita in the United States was $32500 (valued at 1995 $ prices). This high income level reflects a high standard of living. In contrast,

More information

Insurance and the Macroeconomic Environment

Insurance and the Macroeconomic Environment Insurance and the Macroeconomic Environment Casper Christophersen and Petr Jakubik 1 Abstract Insurance companies play an important role in the financial sector and the availability of insurance products

More information

Infrastructure and Growth in Africa

Infrastructure and Growth in Africa WORKING PAPER 3 Infrastructure and Growth in Africa César Calderón JANUARY 2008 2009 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 USA

More information

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009 The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice Raj Chetty Harvard Univ. Adam Szeidl UC-Berkeley July 2009 Introduction How does homeownership affect financial portfolios? Linkages between housing and financial

More information

Chapter 6. Inequality Measures

Chapter 6. Inequality Measures Chapter 6. Inequality Measures Summary Inequality is a broader concept than poverty in that it is defined over the entire population, and does not only focus on the poor. The simplest measurement of inequality

More information

research brief A Profile of the Middle Class in Latin American Countries 2001 2011 by Leopoldo Tornarolli

research brief A Profile of the Middle Class in Latin American Countries 2001 2011 by Leopoldo Tornarolli research brief The International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth is jointly supported by the United Nations Development Programme and the Government of Brazil. August/2014no. 47 A Profile of the Middle

More information

MASTER THESIS: THE EFFECT OF EDUCATION ON ECONOMIC GROWTH

MASTER THESIS: THE EFFECT OF EDUCATION ON ECONOMIC GROWTH MASTER THESIS: THE EFFECT OF EDUCATION ON ECONOMIC GROWTH ALFREDO ALARCON YANEZ 1. Introduction Much has been written in the economic literature about the theoretical and empirical effects of schooling

More information

How To Calculate The Lorenz Curve

How To Calculate The Lorenz Curve FACT SHEET 1. Overview 1.1 Developed by an Italian statistician Corrado in the 1910s, is commonly used to indicate income inequality in a society. is a number which has a value between zero and one. As

More information

Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance

Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance Chapter II Coverage and Type of Health Insurance The U.S. social security system is based mainly on the private sector; the state s responsibility is restricted to the care of the most vulnerable groups,

More information

An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world *

An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world * An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world * The World Bank has been regularly monitoring the progress of developing countries against absolute poverty. Drawing

More information

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation Mary Campbell, Robert Haveman, Gary Sandefur, and Barbara Wolfe Mary Campbell is an assistant professor of sociology at the University

More information

WORLD POPULATION IN 2300

WORLD POPULATION IN 2300 E c o n o m i c & DRAFT S o c i a l A f f a i r s WORLD POPULATION IN 2300 Highlights United Nations ESA/P/WP.187 9 December 2003 DRAFT Department of Economic and Social Affairs Population Division WORLD

More information

Tracking positive and negative effects of inequality on long-run growth

Tracking positive and negative effects of inequality on long-run growth Institut de Recerca en Economia Aplicada Regional i Pública Research Institute of Applied Economics Document de Treball 2014/01, 30 pàg. Working Paper 2014/01, 30 pag. Grup de Recerca Anàlisi Quantitativa

More information

FDI performance and potential rankings. Astrit Sulstarova Division on Investment and Enterprise UNCTAD

FDI performance and potential rankings. Astrit Sulstarova Division on Investment and Enterprise UNCTAD FDI performance and potential rankings Astrit Sulstarova Division on Investment and Enterprise UNCTAD FDI perfomance index The Inward FDI Performance Index ranks countries by the FDI they receive relative

More information

THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH, 1980 99

THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH, 1980 99 THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH, 1980 99 Julio H. Cole Since 1986, a group of researchers associated with the Fraser Institute have focused on the definition and measurement

More information

2015 Growth in data center employment continues but the workforce is changing

2015 Growth in data center employment continues but the workforce is changing Published in Conjunction with MARKET BRIEFING GLOBAL DATA CENTER EMPLOYMENT 2015 2015 Growth in data center employment continues but the workforce is changing Globally, the number of people working in

More information

Article: Main results from the Wealth and Assets Survey: July 2012 to June 2014

Article: Main results from the Wealth and Assets Survey: July 2012 to June 2014 Article: Main results from the Wealth and Assets Survey: July 2012 to June 2014 Coverage: GB Date: 18 December 2015 Geographical Area: Region Theme: Economy Main points In July 2012 to June 2014: aggregate

More information

The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case

The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case By Atila Kilic (2012) Abstract In 2010, C. Romer and D. Romer developed a cutting-edge method to measure tax multipliers

More information

Dynamic medium term Granger causality between growth and poverty

Dynamic medium term Granger causality between growth and poverty Dynamic medium term Granger causality between growth and poverty Salvador Pérez-Moreno Universidad de Málaga and Diana Weinhold LSE Draft, October 2012 Abstract This paper examines the causal relationship

More information

Investment in developing countries' food and agriculture: Assessing agricultural capital stocks and their impact on productivity

Investment in developing countries' food and agriculture: Assessing agricultural capital stocks and their impact on productivity Investment in developing countries' food and agriculture: Assessing agricultural capital stocks and their impact on productivity Gustavo Anriquez (FAO), Hartwig de Haen, Oleg Nivyevskiy & Stephan von Cramon

More information

NET INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION

NET INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION II. NET INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION A. GLOBAL TRENDS During the period 195-21, the developed regions experienced population gains from positive net international migration while the developing regions were

More information

Higher Education and Economic Growth in Africa

Higher Education and Economic Growth in Africa Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 42, No. 3, 509 529, April 2006 Higher Education and Economic Growth in Africa KWABENA GYIMAH-BREMPONG*, OLIVER PADDISON**, & WORKIE MITIKU{ *National Science Foundation,

More information

Summary. Accessibility and utilisation of health services in Ghana 245

Summary. Accessibility and utilisation of health services in Ghana 245 Summary The thesis examines the factors that impact on access and utilisation of health services in Ghana. The utilisation behaviour of residents of a typical urban and a typical rural district are used

More information

Sierra Leone. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Sierra Leone. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Sierra Leone Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

WORLD. Geographic Trend Report for GMAT Examinees

WORLD. Geographic Trend Report for GMAT Examinees 2011 WORLD Geographic Trend Report for GMAT Examinees WORLD Geographic Trend Report for GMAT Examinees The World Geographic Trend Report for GMAT Examinees identifies mobility trends among GMAT examinees

More information

Beef Demand: What is Driving the Market?

Beef Demand: What is Driving the Market? Beef Demand: What is Driving the Market? Ronald W. Ward Food and Economics Department University of Florida Demand is a term we here everyday. We know it is important but at the same time hard to explain.

More information

Does Education Matter for Economic Growth?

Does Education Matter for Economic Growth? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7089 Does Education Matter for Economic Growth? Michael S. Delgado Daniel J. Henderson Christopher F. Parmeter December 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

GDP Estimation Results For Developing Countries

GDP Estimation Results For Developing Countries Debt and Economic Growth in Developing and Industrial Countries Alfredo Schclarek This draft: December 15, 2004 I want to thank Anders Danielson, Marcelo Delajara, Steven Durlauf, David Edgerton and Luis

More information

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA Abstract THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA Dorina CLICHICI 44 Tatiana COLESNICOVA 45 The purpose of this research is to estimate the impact of several

More information

Association Between Variables

Association Between Variables Contents 11 Association Between Variables 767 11.1 Introduction............................ 767 11.1.1 Measure of Association................. 768 11.1.2 Chapter Summary.................... 769 11.2 Chi

More information

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence Jan Tin Commerce Department Abstract This study takes a closer look at the relationship between money demand and the life-cycle motive using panel

More information

2. Germany. (a) Past trends

2. Germany. (a) Past trends 2. Germany (a) Past trends While the total fertility rate increased steadily from 2.1 to 2.4 children per woman between 15-155 and 1-15, Germany experienced a continuous decline afterwards, to 1. children

More information

INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH*

INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH* NERO Conference Paris, 22 June 2015 INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH* Federico Cingano, ELS Employment Analysis Division *Source: OECD (2015) In It Together: Why less inequality benefits

More information

Review of knowledge capital and growth

Review of knowledge capital and growth Annex A Review of knowledge capital and growth This annex provides a more technical overview of the estimates of growth models that are relied upon in the text. It also describes the various tests used

More information

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market form Michael Jetter May 23, 2014 Abstract This paper unites theories about growth effects from various trade characteristics, proposing the market

More information

Child Marriage and Education: A Major Challenge Minh Cong Nguyen and Quentin Wodon i

Child Marriage and Education: A Major Challenge Minh Cong Nguyen and Quentin Wodon i Child Marriage and Education: A Major Challenge Minh Cong Nguyen and Quentin Wodon i Why Does Child Marriage Matter? The issue of child marriage is getting renewed attention among policy makers. This is

More information

Comparing Levels of Development

Comparing Levels of Development 2 Comparing Levels of Development Countries are unequally endowed with natural capital. For example, some benefit from fertile agricultural soils, while others have to put a lot of effort into artificial

More information

THE EFFECT OF CRIME VICTIMIZATION ON ATTITUDES TOWARDS CRIMINAL JUSTICE IN LATIN AMERICA

THE EFFECT OF CRIME VICTIMIZATION ON ATTITUDES TOWARDS CRIMINAL JUSTICE IN LATIN AMERICA THE EFFECT OF CRIME VICTIMIZATION ON ATTITUDES TOWARDS CRIMINAL JUSTICE IN LATIN AMERICA Gabriel Demombynes Draft of May 2009 ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects victimization on criminal justice

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Mozambique

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Mozambique Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Mozambique Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of Romania

Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of Romania Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of EVA MILITARU, CRISTINA STROE Social Indicators and Standard of Living Department National Scientific Research Institute for Labour and

More information

The big pay turnaround: Eurozone recovering, emerging markets falter in 2015

The big pay turnaround: Eurozone recovering, emerging markets falter in 2015 The big pay turnaround: Eurozone recovering, emerging markets falter in 2015 Global salary rises up compared to last year But workers in key emerging markets will experience real wage cuts Increase in

More information

World Population Growth

World Population Growth 3 World Population Growth Why is world population growing faster than ever before? Population dynamics are one of the key factors to consider when thinking about development. In the past years the world

More information

Executive summary. Global Wage Report 2014 / 15 Wages and income inequality

Executive summary. Global Wage Report 2014 / 15 Wages and income inequality Executive summary Global Wage Report 2014 / 15 Wages and income inequality Global Wage Report 2014/15 Wages and income inequality Executive summary INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE GENEVA Copyright International

More information

Gender Equality and Economic Development

Gender Equality and Economic Development Gender Equality and Economic Development The Role for Information and Communication Technologies Derek H. C. Chen * The Knowledge for Development Program The World Bank Washington DC 20433 Abstract This

More information

Determinants of Economic Growth in a Panel of Countries

Determinants of Economic Growth in a Panel of Countries ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 4, 231 274 (2003) Determinants of Economic Growth in a Panel of Countries Robert J. Barro Growth rates vary enormously across countries over long periods of time. The reason

More information

The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe

The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe Olivier Blanchard October 2001 Let me start by sketching a toy model of immigration. Think of all the capital as being in the West (Western Europe).

More information

Micro and macroeconomic determinants of net interest margin in the Albanian banking system (2002-2014)

Micro and macroeconomic determinants of net interest margin in the Albanian banking system (2002-2014) Micro and macroeconomic determinants of net interest margin in the Albanian banking system (2002-2014) Eralda Leka, Monetary Policy Department, Meri Papavangjeli, Research Department, Bank of Albania*

More information

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program International Comparison Program [03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing Global Office 3 rd Technical Advisory Group Meeting June 10-11, 2010 Paris, France

More information

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach Paid and Unpaid Work inequalities 1 Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

More information

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons Fiscal Studies (1997) vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 93 30 Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons JOHN CREEDY * Abstract his paper examines the relationship between the cross-sectional and lifetime

More information

Inequality in G20 countries: Causes, impacts, and policy responses*

Inequality in G20 countries: Causes, impacts, and policy responses* Inequality in G20 countries: Causes, impacts, and policy responses* International Labour Organization Korea Institute for International Economic Policy G20 Employment Working Group 23-25 July 2015 Cappadocia,

More information

Global Policy Model. A low-carbon, high growth policy scenario for the world economy

Global Policy Model. A low-carbon, high growth policy scenario for the world economy Development Policy and Analysis Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs Global Policy Model A low-carbon, high growth policy scenario for the world economy United Nations New York, Extract from

More information

How To Understand The Relationship Between Economic Development And Growth

How To Understand The Relationship Between Economic Development And Growth Andrea F. Presbitero E-mail: a.presbitero@univpm.it Pagina web: www.dea.unian.it/presbitero/ Dipartimento di Economia Università Politecnica delle Marche Credito, Finanza e Sviluppo nei PVS Financial Development

More information

Progress and prospects

Progress and prospects Ending CHILD MARRIAGE Progress and prospects UNICEF/BANA213-182/Kiron The current situation Worldwide, more than 7 million women alive today were married before their 18th birthday. More than one in three

More information

TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK: THE 2013 REVISION - MIGRANTS BY AGE AND SEX

TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK: THE 2013 REVISION - MIGRANTS BY AGE AND SEX E c o n o m i c & S o c i a l A f f a i r s TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK: THE 2013 REVISION - MIGRANTS BY AGE AND SEX CD-ROM DOCUMENTATION United Nations POP/DB/MIG/Stock/Rev.2013/Age December

More information

New South Wales State and Regional Population Projections 2001-2051. 2004 Release TRANSPORT AND POPULATION DATA CENTRE

New South Wales State and Regional Population Projections 2001-2051. 2004 Release TRANSPORT AND POPULATION DATA CENTRE New South Wales State and Regional Population Projections 21-251 251 24 Release TRANSPORT AND POPULATION DATA CENTRE THE TRANSPORT AND POPULATION DATA CENTRE (TPDC) The TPDC is located in the NSW Department

More information

F. MORTALITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

F. MORTALITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES F. MORTALITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Ian TimFus reviewed existing evidence on mortality trends in sub-saharan Africa, a region characterized by the highest mortality levels in the world. There were several

More information

Does Political Instability Lead to Higher Inflation? A Panel Data Analysis

Does Political Instability Lead to Higher Inflation? A Panel Data Analysis WP/05/49 Does Political Instability Lead to Higher Inflation? A Panel Data Analysis Ari Aisen and Francisco José Veiga 2005 International Monetary Fund WP/05/49 IMF Working Paper Monetary and Financial

More information

Tanzania (United Republic of)

Tanzania (United Republic of) Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Tanzania (United Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for

More information

Does pay inequality within a team affect performance? Tomas Dvorak*

Does pay inequality within a team affect performance? Tomas Dvorak* Does pay inequality within a team affect performance? Tomas Dvorak* The title should concisely express what the paper is about. It can also be used to capture the reader's attention. The Introduction should

More information

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1 Solución del Examen Tipo: 1 Universidad Carlos III de Madrid ECONOMETRICS Academic year 2009/10 FINAL EXAM May 17, 2010 DURATION: 2 HOURS 1. Assume that model (III) verifies the assumptions of the classical

More information

El Salvador. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

El Salvador. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report El Salvador Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

GLOBAL. 2014 Country Well-Being Rankings. D Social (% thriving) E Financial (% thriving) F Community (% thriving) G Physical (% thriving)

GLOBAL. 2014 Country Well-Being Rankings. D Social (% thriving) E Financial (% thriving) F Community (% thriving) G Physical (% thriving) 0 0 GLOBAL 0 Country Rankings 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 : >0.0% 0.% 0.0% 0.% 0.0% 0.% 0.0% 0.0% A Country s global rank B in three or more elements of well-being C (% thriving) D (% thriving) E

More information

Brazil. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Brazil. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Brazil Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Burkina Faso

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Burkina Faso Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Burkina Faso Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Financial Development, Inequality and Poverty: Some International Evidence. Sami Ben Naceur and RuiXin Zhang

Financial Development, Inequality and Poverty: Some International Evidence. Sami Ben Naceur and RuiXin Zhang WP/16/32 Financial Development, Inequality and Poverty: Some International Evidence Sami Ben Naceur and RuiXin Zhang IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published

More information

Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say?

Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say? Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say? Abhijit V. Banerjee and Esther Duflo June 2003 Abstract This paper describes the correlations between inequality and the growth rates in crosscountry data.

More information

CONVERGENCE OF INCOME ACROSS PENNSYLVANIA COUNTIES

CONVERGENCE OF INCOME ACROSS PENNSYLVANIA COUNTIES CONVERGENCE OF INCOME ACROSS PENNSYLVANIA COUNTIES David A. Latzko Pennsylvania State University, York Campus ABSTRACT The neoclassical growth model implies that if two economies have the same preferences

More information

Introduction to the Economic Growth course

Introduction to the Economic Growth course Economic Growth Lecture Note 1. 03.02.2011. Christian Groth Introduction to the Economic Growth course 1 Economic growth theory Economic growth theory is the study of what factors and mechanisms determine

More information

External Debt and Growth

External Debt and Growth External Debt and Growth Catherine Pattillo, Hélène Poirson and Luca Ricci Reasonable levels of external debt that help finance productive investment may be expected to enhance growth, but beyond certain

More information

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2009(No.22) * Municipal Corruption Victimization 1

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2009(No.22) * Municipal Corruption Victimization 1 This is the third paper (I0803, I0813) in the AmericasBarometer Insight Series to analyze the sources of corruption victimization, focusing on another question included in the 2008 round of the Latin American

More information

Income inequalities in Italy: trend over time

Income inequalities in Italy: trend over time Income inequalities in Italy: trend over time Loris Vergolini Descriptive evidence In this note we aim to deepen the OECD (2011) results that highlight a critical situation for Italy, providing the image

More information

Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness

Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness Chapter 5. Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness Summary There are four main reasons why measures of poverty may not be robust. Sampling error occurs because measures of poverty are based on sample

More information

NERI Quarterly Economic Facts Summer 2012. 4 Distribution of Income and Wealth

NERI Quarterly Economic Facts Summer 2012. 4 Distribution of Income and Wealth 4 Distribution of Income and Wealth 53 54 Indicator 4.1 Income per capita in the EU Indicator defined National income (GDP) in per capita (per head of population) terms expressed in Euro and adjusted for

More information

Countries Ranked by Per Capita Income A. IBRD Only 1 Category iv (over $7,185)

Countries Ranked by Per Capita Income A. IBRD Only 1 Category iv (over $7,185) Page 1 of 5 Note: This OP 3.10, Annex C replaces the version dated September 2013. The revised terms are effective for all loans that are approved on or after July 1, 2014. Countries Ranked by Per Capita

More information

The Effect of Mergers & Acquisitions and Greenfield FDI on Income Inequality

The Effect of Mergers & Acquisitions and Greenfield FDI on Income Inequality Zhuang and Griffith, International Journal of Applied Economics, March 2013, 10(1), 29-38 29 The Effect of Mergers & Acquisitions and Greenfield FDI on Income Inequality Hong Zhuang* and David Griffith*

More information

Thailand. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Thailand. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Thailand Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Obtaining Finance in Latin America and the Caribbean 1

Obtaining Finance in Latin America and the Caribbean 1 Obtaining Finance in Latin America and the Caribbean 1 World Bank Group latin America and the Caribbean Series Note No. REV. 8/14 Basic Definitions Countries surveyed in and how they are grouped for analysis:

More information

The Impact of Surplus Liquidity

The Impact of Surplus Liquidity The Impact of Surplus Liquidity Garreth Rule CCBS PFTAC Course on Monetary Transmission Channels, Liquidity Conditions, and Determinants of Inflation Central Bank of Solomon Islands 18 23 July 2012 The

More information

Population below the poverty line Rural % Population below $1 a day % Urban % Urban % Survey year. National %

Population below the poverty line Rural % Population below $1 a day % Urban % Urban % Survey year. National % 2.7 International the the Afghanistan.................... Albania 2002 29.6 19.8 25.4...... 2002 a

More information

Human Capital and Productivity

Human Capital and Productivity Human Capital and Productivity Angel de la Fuente January 2011 Barcelona Economics Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 530 Human capital and productivity Angel de la Fuente* Instituto de Análisis Económico

More information

The Impact of Alternative Grade Configurations on Student Outcomes through Middle and High School *

The Impact of Alternative Grade Configurations on Student Outcomes through Middle and High School * The Impact of Alternative Grade Configurations on Student Outcomes through Middle and High School * Guido Schwerdt Harvard University, Ifo Institute for Economic Research and CESifo Martin R. West Harvard

More information

2015 Global Emotions

2015 Global Emotions 2015 Global Emotions 1 Gallup s Positive and Negative Experience Indexes measure life s intangibles the feelings and emotions that traditional economic indicators such as GDP were never intended to capture.

More information

Volume and Quality of Infrastructure and the Distribution of Income: An Empirical Investigation

Volume and Quality of Infrastructure and the Distribution of Income: An Empirical Investigation Inter-American Development Bank Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo (BID) Research department Departamento de investigación Working Paper #450 Volume and Quality of Infrastructure and the Distribution of

More information