The Federal Communications Commission acknowledges four national mobile wireless

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Federal Communications Commission acknowledges four national mobile wireless"

Transcription

1 Claire Vetter- ASSC Paper Market Power and Duopoly despite Regulation An Analysis of the Market Structure and Economic Conditions of the National Mobile Wireless Telecommunications Market The Federal Communications Commission acknowledges four national mobile wireless corporations in its 15 th Annual Mobile Wireless Competition Report; Verizon Wireless, AT&T, Sprint Nextel, and T-Mobile (Report 2011, p.7). The market structure and conditions produced by the activity of these four firms is the subject and scope of this paper. This paper seeks to assess the general tendency of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market toward a particular market structure, monopoly, based on the market activity up to the time of writing, as well as provide a critique of the economics literature in the scope of the subject. After analyzing the market conditions as best indicated by the data provided by the Federal Communications Commission s 15 th Annual Mobile Wireless Competition Report, it is apparent that market power is present to an extent within this market, and with the passage of time has not become primarily concentrated in one firm, but in two. It is evident that this market has not trended toward monopoly, but oligopoly at least, and duopoly at best, thus exposing weaknesses in arguments and analysis within the economics literature. The possible trend of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market toward a monopolistic market structure is a reflection of the American telecommunications industry s past, which on average has been more monopolistic than competitive. In 1907, Theodore Vail, president of American Telephone and Telegraph Company, perfectly captured the market structure of the telephone industry through his popular advertising slogan, One System, One Policy, Universal Service (Mueller 1997, p.4). What began as a patent based monopoly on

2 telephony in 1877, the Bell Telephone Company, later renamed AT&T, dominated an industry commonly characterized by its monopolistic market structure and the government regulation that aided in creating it (King 2011, p.42). Since the United States entered World War I in 1917, the American telephone industry has been subject to and heavily influenced by regulation, and the government of the United States has influenced the extent of competition present within this market. As a part of its national mobilization in 1917, the United States government nationalized the telephone industry, and allowed AT&T to emerge as a regulated monopoly (King 2011, p.45). The government sought to provide the benefits of a universal service provider, while avoiding the abuses of unregulated monopolists (King 2011, p.46). In order to accomplish its regulatory objectives, the government established the Federal Communications Commission through the Telecommunications Act of 1934 and intended it to regulate common carrier communications and broadcasting (King 2011, p.46). The Telecommunications Act of 1934 also gave the FCC jurisdiction over radio spectrum and the power to regulate access to this spectrum (King 2011, pp.49-50). The effects of this jurisdiction are especially pertinent to the national mobile wireless telecommunications market. By the end of World War II in 1945, individual households and many public places had access to a unified telephone service controlled and provided by a regulated monopoly (King 2011, 48). AT&T s regulated monopoly and its goal of universal service played a prominent role in American life until it came to an end in 1984, when the government broke-up AT&T as a result of a seven year anti-trust case filed by the U.S. Department of Justice (Viscusi et al. 2005, p.540). The DOJ accused AT&T of violating 2 of the Sherman Act for attempting to monopolize the telecommunications industry, by utilizing its dominant position in three

3 components of the industry: local exchange, long distance, and terminal equipment (Viscusi et al p.550). The ruling of this case required that AT&T operate exclusively in competitive markets (Viscusi et al. 2005, p.540). Although the government brought an end to AT&T s regulated monopoly, AT&T remained under government regulation, as the FCC feared the anticompetitive consequences that would result from an unconstrained, dominant firm (Viscusi et al. 2005, p.541). Since the telephone industry was highly concentrated, the United States government could not fully deregulate AT&T and continued to regulate its rates and oversee its market activity (Viscusi et al. 2005, p.541). 1 Technological innovation in the 1990s required revisions to the Telecommunications Act of 1934, which took their form in the Telecommunications Act of Under this new telecommunications act, the United States government made the FCC the key arbiter of competition and primary regulatory body of the telecommunications industry (Viscusi et al. 2005, p. 545). Today, in the scope of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market, the goal of the FCC is to promote access to services, providing consumers the ability to choose among multiple reliable and affordable services in a pro-competitive and universal access environment (FCC 2012). Along with promoting competition, the FCC also regulates the use of electromagnetic spectrum and is responsible for licensing the use of spectrum to commercial and non-commercial users (FCC 2012). A historical examination of the American telecommunications industry displays and explains the unique tension created by regulatory and free market forces that is present in the market under consideration. While the government cannot coerce its citizens to subscribe to one 1 For further reading and analysis on the economic effects of the break-up of AT&T and the impact of government regulation after the break-up, read W. Kip Viscusi, Joseph E. Harrington, Jr. and John M. Vernon s book Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. Their retrospective analysis of this event demonstrates that regulation after the breakup was unnecessary (2005, p.543).

4 firm s services or place a limit on the number of subscribers to one firm, it has the power to regulate and determine what firms acquire necessary factors of production and approve or decline mergers and acquisitions. The national mobile wireless telecommunications market is not under government control to an absolute extent, but the regulatory measures in place distort expected market outcomes that would occur under free market conditions. This paper therefore examines the national mobile wireless telecommunications market and its structure in light of its industry s regulatory history and the extent of regulation currently in place. The FCC seeks to create and enhance competition within the national mobile wireless telecommunications market through regulation, but it is evident that market power and duopoly have emerged over time, despite the regulatory forces in place. According to David L. Kaserman and John W. Mayo, the most significant factor in defining monopoly is a firm s ability to charge a monopoly price, which is a direct product of a firm possessing significant market power (1995, p. 98). The extent of market power, along with the number of firms that possess market power in a particular market, defines the market s structure. They note that a monopoly is the possession of market power by a single firm (1995, p. 98). Kaserman and Mayo define market power as the ability of a firm to raise the price of its product above the marginal cost without losing so many sales that the above- marginal-cost price is unprofitable, and acknowledge that a firm acquiring market power to this extent requires both a large market share and the presence of significant barriers to entry (1995, p.98). Determining the extent of market power, according to these two criteria, and the number of firms that possess this market power is the standard by which this paper will define the market structure of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market and critique the arguments of the current economics literature.

5 Fritz Machlup also includes the possession of market power in his definitions of oligopoly and duopoly. In The Economics of Sellers Competition, he writes: Thus sellers who are not monopolists in the sense of this model analysis nevertheless have monopoly power. The market position of an oligopolist as well as some of his business practices may be called monopolistic; and we may speak of the degree of monopoly that is expressed in the pricing and selling policies of the oligopolist. (Machlup 1952, p. 350) It is evident that an oligopoly market structure shares the characteristic of market power with a monopoly market structure. However, an oligopoly contrasts with a monopoly in the number of sellers and the attitude of the sellers. According to Machlup, an oligopoly has few sellers (meaning more than two) and the sellers within the oligopoly possess the consciousness of possible reactions of rivals (1952, p. 351). This entails that each member of the oligopoly is aware of the actions of other members and acts based on this knowledge. Machlup notes this contrasts with a monopoly because the seller in a monopoly believes that he does not have to care about what other sellers might do in reaction to what he does because what they sell is too different from what he sells (1952, p. 351). Finally, a duopoly is a market in which only two firms offer a good or service (Machlup 1952, p. 371). These two firms possess a degree of control over the price of their product, and therefore possess market power to an extent (Machlup 1952, p. 377). Based on these definitions of monopoly, oligopoly, and duopoly, a determination of the market structure that this market has trended toward up to this point depends on the presence of market power and the number of sellers which possess it. The economics literature contains certain limitations when applied to the analysis of this potential economic trend. Since the probability of this market trending toward monopoly has become most apparent from 2000 to 2010, the economics literature is limited in the number of articles available that analyze this particular market and the extent to which they do so.

6 However, after surveying the literature, two opposing perspectives emerge that directly apply to the condition of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market and its market structure in the scope of this particular trend. 2 Each of the perspectives includes the extent to which government regulation aids in defining the market structure. The first perspective that emerges in the economics literature postulates the market structure of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market in the absence of government regulation. As best exemplified by Gerald R. Faulhaber and Christiaan Hogendorn in their article, The Market Structure of Broadband Telecommunications, this perspective argues that the national mobile wireless telecommunications market is not trending toward a natural monopoly under free market conditions. Rather, in the complete absence of government regulation, this market would be competitive 3 in nature due to a growth in demand over time of this market s service. Robert W. Crandall in his article, The Remedy for the Bottleneck Monopoly in Telecom: Isolate it, Share, or Ignore it?, agrees that regulation is not necessary to generate competition and that competition will develop over time as this industry grows through innovation and development (2005). While Faulhaber and Hogendorn primarily focus on the broadband telecommunications market, the extent of consumer demand and government regulation present within this market parallels the wireless telecommunications market and makes their analysis valid and applicable. The broadband market, like the national mobile 2 A third perspective is present in the literature that argues for government induced anticompetitive market structures in the regional mobile wireless telecommunications market and the spectrum market. Philip M. Parker and Lars-Hendrick Röller in their article Collusive Conduct in Duopolies: Multimarket Contact and Cross- Ownership in the Mobile Telephone Industry, analyze the creation of a monopoly followed by a duopoly market structure in the regional mobile wireless telecommunications market in the early 1980s through government regulation. They argue that government regulation induced a collusive duopoly and lead to noncompetitive pricing in this market (Parker and Röller 1997, p. 321). Eli Noam, in an article titled Spectrum Auctions: Yesterday s Heresy, Today s Orthodoxy, Tomorrow s Anarchism. Taking the Next Step to Open Spectrum Acquisition, discusses the anti-competitive effects of governmentally regulated spectrum acquisition, and posits the possibility of a government induced oligopoly in this market (1998, pp ). 3 The terms competitive and competition within this paper refer to rivalrous competition and not the neoclassical perfect competition model.

7 wireless service market, also utilizes spectrum to provide service to consumers. In commenting on the nature of the broadband telecommunications market structure, Faulhaber and Hogendorn write: [D]uring the period of growth, it is likely to appear that the market is characterized by natural monopoly, and that some form of government intervention is needed. Indeed, if demand growth caps at, say, 140% of today's demand level, then this may well be the case. If, however, demand continues to grow, eventually approaching or exceeding that realized by cable TV today, then the market is likely to evolve to a more competitive outcome, provided government intervention at an earlier stage does not preclude the market from functioning. This suggests that some patience and regulatory forbearance may be required before concluding that broadband infrastructure is a natural monopoly. (2000, p. 323) As evidenced in this passage, Faulhaber and Hogendorn argue that a market which possesses a high level of demand and is capable of future growth is more likely to result in a competitive, rather than a monopolistic, outcome. They therefore argue that under free market conditions and the absence of regulation, this type of market, which is characteristic of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market, would be competitive in nature, rendering government regulation unnecessary. The inverse of this first perspective is the argument presented by Peter Cramton, Evan Kwerel, Gregory Rosston, and Adrzej Skzypacz in their article Using Spectrum Auctions to Enhance Competition in Wireless Services. Throughout this article, the authors argue that under free market conditions, monopolistic characteristics would emerge without the government creating competition and competitive economic conditions through regulation. Government regulation is necessary to enhance and maintain a competitive market, and a possible consequence of the absence of government regulation would be monopoly. In order to properly address the problem of monopoly, the authors argue that regulating spectrum markets through

8 instruments such as set-asides 4, bidding credits, spectrum caps, and antitrust and merger review policy will efficiently enhance competition (Cramton et al. 2011, p.168). They assert the dangers of a regulation free spectrum market by acknowledging a potential market failure when allocating spectrum to the highest bidder. The authors write, [P]art of the willingness to pay for the incumbent in the auction comes from the value of deterring new entry, which is bad for overall efficiency for the standard market power reasons Competition policy seeks to address this potential market failure by encouraging competition in the provision of wireless services (Cramton et al. 2011, p. 169). As evidenced in this quotation, the authors argue that a free market, one devoid of regulation, would produce anti-competitive behavior, and the presence of market power is a negative consequence rendering competition policy a necessity to encourage a competive economic atmosphere in the spectrum market. Moreover, the authors allude to the possibility of natural monopoly specifically when they posit the possibility of a firm earning enough profits to bid for and consequently obtain two identical licenses that would secure monopoly power in the market (Cramton et al. 2011, p. 172). After noting this example, the authors immediately outline the inefficiency and detrimental consequences produced by this degree of market power, thus further building their case for the necessity of regulation in order ensure a competitive market (Cramton et al. 2011, p. 173). These authors formulate a contrary argument to the first perspective introduced by crediting regulation with creating competition, not the market itself. A general assumption present in the literature in regard to a monopoly market structure is the postulation that competition is optimal and efficient, so a natural monopoly is economically 4 Ian Ayres and Peter Cramton further discuss how these instruments enhance competition in the spectrum market in their article, Deficit Reduction Through Diversity: How Affirmative Action at the FCC Increased Auction Competition.

9 inefficient because it is not competitive in nature. Both perspectives presented support this supposition, which is the first weakness in their arguments. The presence of natural monopoly demonstrates economic efficiency according to David L. Kaserman and John W. Mayo, and does not eliminate competition. In Government and Business: The Economics of Antitrust and Regulation, Kaserman and Mayo write, The provision of total market supply by a single firm, however, is not undesirable in this case an industry is said to constitute a natural monopoly if, for the industry output level that satisfies total market demand, the product can be produced most efficiently by a single firm (Kaserman and Mayo 1995, p.415). This quotation demonstrates that natural monopolies are economically efficient, as they can satisfy total market demand at the lowest cost. Moreover, Kaserman and Mayo note that natural monopolies do not contain significant barriers to entry, and all firms have access to the same demand and production technology (1995, p.429). Therefore, natural monopolies do not eliminate competition and are not a source of economic inefficiency, revealing the first weakness in both of the presented arguments. The strengths and weaknesses of these two perspectives in the economics literature are further revealed through an analysis of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market conditions as best presented by the Federal Communication Commission s 15 th Annual Mobile Wireless Competition Report. The data presented in the Report aids in assessing the validity of these two arguments and the credibility of their accompanying analysis. An analysis of the data reveals the presence of market power according to the criteria presented by David L. Kaserman and John W. Mayo and appears to be concentrated in two firms: Verizon Wireless and AT&T. Gerald R. Faulhaber and Christiaan Hogendorn s argument for competition in the absence of government regulation due to an increase in demand over time is valid to an extent

10 when applied to the conditions of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market up to this point. The extent of demand that exists in the market validates Faulhaber and Hogendorn s argument that the demand for this service will grow over time. As evident in Figure 1, the number of mobile wireless subscribers and connections has grown consistently from 2001 to Furthermore, Figure 2 shows that the number of subscribers has grown in all four of the nationwide firms and in each of the regional firms listed. The evident growth in demand of national mobile wireless services over two years justifies the apparent growth and possibility of growth over time that these authors posit. Mobile Wireless Subscribers and Connections Year Mobile Wireless Connections Mobile Telephone Subscribers NRUF (millions) Total Net Adds CTIA (millions) Total Net Adds Form 477* (millions) Total Net Adds n/a Figure 1 Source: Report 2011, p. 9. Mobile Internet Access Subscribers Form 477 (millions) Total Net Adds

11 Top 14 Facilities Based Mobile Wireless Service Providers by Subscribers (based on publicly-available subscriber counts, in thousands) Service Provider Year-End 2008 Year-End 2009 Year-End AT&T 77,009 85,120 95,536 2 Verizon Wireless 72,056 91,249 94,135 3 Sprint Nextel 48,338 48,133 49,910 4 T-Mobile 32,758 33,790 33,734 5 MetroPCS 5,367 6,640 8,155 6 US Cellular 6,196 6,141 6,072 7 Leap 3,845 4,954 5,518 8 Clearwire ,345 9 América Móvil/Claro Cellular South Cincinnati Bell Wireless Ntelos Pocket Comm SouthernLINC * 220 Figure 2 Source: Report 2011, p. 34. However, this data also challenges Gerald R. Faulhaber and Christiaan Hogendorn s argument that this growth in demand will result in a competitive outcome. While growth in demand is not concentrated in one firm, thereby precluding the emergence of a possible monopoly during this time, growth in demand appears to be concentrated in two firms. AT&T and Verizon Wireless possess the largest increase in subscribers and the largest number of subscribers after this two year period. Moreover, both of these firms possess the largest share of subscribers as evident in Figure 3. Although this set of data is from the end of 2009, it is implicit from the growth in the number of subscribers experienced by both of these firms in 2010 that the share of subscribers either remained the same or increased for both of these firms. Since growth in demand is most apparent and to the greatest extent in the service provided by two firms, Verizon Wireless and AT&T, rather than in many firms, it is evident that a growth in

12 demand has not produced greater competition among firms, but has strengthened and contributed to the market share of two firms. While it is evident that Faulhaber and Hogendorn s argument is correct in asserting this growth in demand has not contributed to the development of a natural monopoly in this particular market, a growth in demand did not necessarily provide a more competitive outcome. Service Provider Share of Subscribers and Revenues (Year-End 2009) Percent of Percent of Revenues Year End 2009 Subscribers (%) (%) Verizon Wireless AT&T Sprint Nextel T-Mobile Metro PCS US Cellular Leap Wireless Other Figure 3 Source: Report 2011, p.35. Furthermore, it is evident that as demand, displayed through an increase in the number of mobile connections and subscribers, has increased over time, market concentration has also increased, further displaying the weak applicability of Faulhaber and Hogendorn s analysis to the market conditions under consideration. As displayed in Figure 4, the average Herfindahl- Hirschman index, which measures market concentration, experienced evident growth from 2003 to 2010, and in 2008 to 2010, reached its highest levels. Moreover, the index classifies these levels as portraying high concentration. Rather than a more competitive outcome which a lower market concentration would reflect, the Herfindahl-Hirschman index displays that a positive relationship exists between market concentration and an increase in demand. This exposes the weakness in the Faulhaber and Hogendorn s argument as it does not support the positive correlation they postulate between demand and greater competition. This market concentration is most evident in the share of revenues earned by each of the nationwide service providers.

13 Average Herfindahl-Hirschman Index Figure 4 Source: Report 2011, p.17. Despite the growth of demand experienced across all firms, both Verizon Wireless and AT&T possessed the greatest share of revenues, according to Figure 3. The percentage of subscribers and revenue shared by Verizon Wireless and AT&T is significantly higher than the two other members of the national market, Sprint Nextel and T-Mobile, and displays that both of these firms possess the greatest market share in the national mobile wireless telecommunications market. Individually, Verizon Wireless and AT&T generated approximately the same percentage of revenue, around 30%, but together, Verizon Wireless and AT&T generated 64.52% of this market s revenues in This degree of market share among both firms satisfies Kaserman and Mayo s first criterion for market power. Rather than trending toward more competition or monopoly, a propensity toward market power by two firms displays that this market has most likely trended toward duopoly, rather than the competitive outcome that

14 Faulhaber and Hogendon posit. With demand increasing over time, along with market concentration and market power, the first perspective among the economics literature does not hold true with the passage of time. Therefore, the considered market conditions do not justify the competitive outcome argument, even despite the presence of regulation meant to enhance competition. The arguments presented by the second group of economics literature also contain weaknesses when applying their perspective to the considered market conditions of the national mobile wireless telecommunications market. These authors argue that government regulation is necessary to maintain a competitive market. However, it is apparent that market power is emerging despite the regulation that is in place. Although the Federal Communications Commission seeks to promote competition, and support the nation s economy by ensuring an appropriate competitive framework, through regulatory measures, an extent of market power is evident both in the high market share concentration of Verizon Wireless and AT&T, and in the presence of barriers to entry within the national mobile wireless telecommunications market (FCC 2012). The presence of barriers to entry satisfies Kaserman and Mayo s second criterion for market power and therefore qualifies this market structure as trending toward something other than competitive. The Federal Communication Commission defines barriers to entry within the mobile wireless services industry as access to spectrum, tower sitting policies, large sunk costs for network deployment, and the magnitude of marketing and advertising expenditures on brands and services (Seeks Comment 2011, p. 5). Amidst these four barriers to entry, the magnitude of advertising expenditures and spectrum acquisition are the most empirically evident barriers and most clearly display the trend toward oligopoly or possible duopoly.

15 First, the extent of money spent on advertising by these four firms, and the reason for doing so, displays the oligopolistic consciousness of other firms as rival firms that Kaserman and Mayo describe. This supports a possible oligopolistic market structure for the national mobile wireless telecommunications market. According to the Report, Sprint Nextel increased its ad spending by 30% in 2009 to $1.23 billion dollars in order to continue its bid to restore its brand (Report 2011 p.86). An increase in Sprint Nextel s advertising expenditure reflects the rivalry it experienced with other firms since this was necessary to increase consumer demand for its services in lieu of AT&T and Verizon Wireless s much greater advertising expenditures. In 2009, Verizon Wireless and AT&T were the second and fourth largest advertisers in the United States, respectively, and spent $2.2 billion, and $1.904 billion on advertising (Report 2011 p. 85). This is almost double what Sprint Nextel spent on advertising, despite its 30% increase in expenditure. Great expenditure on advertising reflects the significance of advertisement and marketing within this industry. The rivalry that exists among these four firms is evident in the extent of expenditure on advertising that is necessary to effectively compete, and characterizes this market as trending toward oligopoly. Furthermore, an analysis of this market displays that advertising expenditure is a plausible barrier to entry, as the extent of advertising expenditure in addition to capital expenditure exhibits the great financial requirements a firm would have to meet in order to enter this market and effectively compete with this market s four current members. According to the Federal Communications Commission, the requirements for entry into the national mobile wireless telecommunications market include raising financial capital, acquiring the necessary spectrum rights, deploying the mobile wireless network, and acquiring a customer base (Report 2011, p.55). Moreover, the Report notes that acquiring new technology and upgrading the

16 existing network infrastructure requires significant capital expenditure (Report 2011, p.55). While the Report does not provide precise monetary values for these various entry requirements, it is evident from the annual capital expenditures of the four firms within the market that the extent of financial capital necessary to successfully enter and effectively compete is substantial. As displayed in Figure 5, Verizon Wireless spent about $6.5 billion in capital expenditures in 2005 and about $7 billion in While Sprint Nextel spent significantly less than Verizon Wireless, about $1 billion in 2009, it is evident that it did not earn the same extent of profit or experience the same increase in subscribers as Verizon Wireless in that year. In 2009, Verizon Wireless earned $16.34 per subscriber, per month in profit, and Sprint Nextel earned $7.03 per subscriber, per month (Report 2011, p.135). Moreover, Verizon Wireless experienced an increase of 19.1 million subscribers from year end of 2008 to year end of 2009, while Sprint Nextel experienced a decrease of 205,000 subscribers over the same time period (Report 2011, p.34). Clearly, a positive correlation exists between capital expenditure and profitability, and capital expenditure and the number of subscribers. Even if a new firm was able to match Sprint Nextel s capital expenditure, it still would be unable to effectively compete with Verizon Wireless, a leader in the market. This demonstrates the significant capital requirements a firm would have to meet aside from advertising expenditure in order to enter the market.

17 Capital Expenditures ($ Million) Capital Expenditures by Service Provider Verizon Wireless AT&T Sprint Nextel T-Mobile Figure 5 Source: Report 2011, p.132. While one may argue that it is possible for a new firm to acquire the necessary financial capital in order to enter this market, it would be a challenge to acquire this magnitude of capital and spend an additional significant amount advertising its service. Since advertising is a significant component of this market due to the extent of rivalry, the magnitude of advertising expenditure a firm must incur in addition to substantial capital expenditure may deter entry. Acquiring the magnitude of financial capital that would allow for this extent of capital and advertising expenditure is not directly feasible for a new firm and is therefore a plausible barrier to entry. Furthermore, the economics literature acknowledges advertising as a barrier to entry due to its influence in earning profit and creating customer loyalty. In their article Advertising

18 Market Structure and Performance, William S. Comanor and Thomas A. Wilson conclude based on their empirical findings that industries with high advertising outlays earn profit at a rate which exceeds other industries by nearly four percentage points (1967, p.437). They assert that this differential represents a 50 percent increase in profit rates which is accounted for by the barriers to entry advertising expenditures create (Comanor and Wilson 1967, p.437). F.M. Scherer and David Ross further address the impact of advertising on entry in their book Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. They cite a study conducted by Robert Smiley which surveyed 293 product managers about possible strategies for deterring entry. The survey found that 32% of respondents cited advertisement to cement customer loyalty as one of the most commonly used strategies (Scherer and Ross 1990, p. 392). 5 As evidenced by the economics literature, advertising expenditure creates a plausible barrier to entry as it is positively correlated with a firm s ability to earn profit and acquire a loyal customer base. In this particular market, this plausible barrier to entry further reflects the presence of market power and the dominance of Verizon Wireless and AT&T through their extent of expenditure relative to the other two firms in their market, thus supporting the trend toward possible duopoly. Spectrum acquisition also creates a blatant barrier to entry and further displays the duopolistic tendencies of this market and presence of market power, despite the regulation that is in place. This further weakens the second argument presented by the economics literature that regulation enhances competition and is necessary to prevent market power and guard against its negative effects. Spectrum is the government-controlled airwaves that companies license to transmit wireless signals (Ovide 2011). Access to spectrum through a government license provided by the Federal Communications Commission is the prerequisite for providing mobile 5 These arguments have been contested by Richard Schmalensee in his article Brand Loyalty and Barriers to Entry.

19 wireless services and entering this market (Report 2011, p. 157). Moreover, the United States government controls the amount of spectrum that is available and decides when a greater supply of spectrum is necessary for promoting competition and innovation (Report 2011, p.157). Finally, the extent of a firm s access to spectrum determines the scope of a carrier s coverage, service quality, and data connection speed (Ovide 2011). A firm s ability to compete in this industry is dependent to an extent on what spectrum and the amount of spectrum it acquires. Spectrum acquisition is therefore a barrier to entry within this market. Analyzing the extent of current spectrum possession and acquisition among firms displays the double standard that is present in regulating this industry because when the government asserts its control over who acquires spectrum, and what amount they possess, it is explicitly evident that Verizon Wireless and AT&T control a majority of the cellular spectrum in this market. The Federal Communications Commission acknowledges this in the Report when they write, Most of the spectrum below 1 GHz suitable for the provision of mobile broadband is held by the two largest mobile wireless service providers. Verizon Wireless and AT&T together hold approximately 90 percent of Cellular spectrum based on megahertz-pops (MHz-POPs), which was the first band to be licensed for commercial mobile services and has the most extensive network build out. (2011, p. 19) Although other firms that provide cellular service possess spectrum on other wavelengths, the fact that two firms own 90% of the cellular spectrum which has the most network build out clearly displays that regulating this industry through controlling who acquires spectrum has not increased competition as defined by the second group of economics literature. Rather, it has created market power, especially among the two firms.

20 Moreover, in the absence of regulation, these two firms would possess an even greater share of spectrum as AT&T expected to merge with T-Mobile in March of 2011, eliminating one competitor in the national mobile wireless telecommunications market (Ovide, 2011). Although the Federal Communications Commission has not approved this acquisition, perhaps in an attempt to prevent a duopoly or monopoly, the presence of market power through spectrum ownership and the barrier to entry it creates displays that regulation does not enhance competition as the second group of literature argues (Mallor et al. 2012). Rather than market power becoming increasingly concentrated in one firm, as the second group of authors predict will happen in the absence of regulation, its concentration is increasingly in two despite the regulation, therefore displaying the weakness in the authors argument when applied to this market. With the presence of market power through the possession of a large market share by AT&T and Verizon Wireless, and barriers to entry through advertising expenditure and spectrum acquisition, it is evident that up to this point, the national mobile wireless telecommunications market has not been trending toward a more competitive market structure or monopoly, despite what the economics literature suggests. Rather, this market has trended toward duopoly, as two firms, AT&T and Verizon Wireless, exhibit evidence of possessing market power according to the criteria of David L. Kaserman and John W. Mayo. Unhampered or deregulated conditions would make this duopoly possible to an absolute extent, but the regulation and control by the Federal Communications Commission maintained a more oligopolistic outcome as it sought to preserve the presence of four firms, Verizon Wireless, AT&T, Sprint Nextel, and T-Mobile, within the market. Despite the regulatory controls it enforces, the government of the United States, acting through the Federal Communications Commission, cannot prevent the presence of

21 market power within the national mobile wireless telecommunications market and could not prevent its trend toward duopoly. This trend within the national mobile wireless telecommunications market is a testament to the power of the free market and reflects a force that the government can attempt to influence and distort, as it has throughout history, but ultimately cannot bring under its control.

22 References Ayres, Ian, and Peter Cramton Deficit Reduction Through Diversity: How Affirmative Action at the FCC Increased Auction Competition. Stanford Law Review 48: Accessed September 25, Comanor, William S., and Thomas A. Wilson Advertising Market Structure and Performance. The Review of Economics and Statistics 49: Accessed February 1, Cramton, Peter, Evan Kwerel, Gregory Rosston, and Andrzej Skrzypacz Using Spectrum Auctions to Enhance Competition in Wireless Services. Journal of Law and Economics 54: Accessed September 25, Crandall, Robert W The Remedy for the Bottleneck Monopoly. The University of Chicago Law Review 72: Accessed September 13, Faulhaber, Gerald R., and Christiaan Hogendorn The Market Structure of Broadband Telecommunications. The Journal of Industrial Economics 48: Accessed September, Federal Communications Commission What We Do. Kaserman, David L., and John W. Mayo Government and Business: The Economics of Antitrust and Regulation. Philadelphia: Harcourt Brace College Publishers.

23 King, John Leslie Mobile Communication and Socio-Technical Change. In Mobile Communication: Dimensions of Social Policy, edited by James E. Katz, New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers. Machlup, Fritz The Economics of Sellers Competition: Model Analysis of Sellers Conduct. Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press. Mallor, Jane P., A. James Barnes, Thomas Bowers, and Arlen W. Langvardt The Clayton Act, the Robinson-Patman Act, and Antitrust Exemptions and Immunities. Chapter 50 from Business Law: The Ethical, Global, and E-Commerce Environment. Columbus: Mcgraw-Hill College. Mueller, Milton L. Jr., Universal Service. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Noam, Eli Spectrum Auctions: Yesterday s Heresy, Today s Orthodoxy, Tomorrow s Anachronism. Taking the Next Step to Open Spectrum Access. Journal of Law and Economics 41: Accessed September 25, Ovide, Shira AT&T/T-Mobile Deal: Explaining Wireless Spectrum. The Wall Street Journal, March 21. Accessed September 27,

24 Parker, Philip M., and Lars-Hendrik Röller Collusive Conduct in Duopolies: Multimarket Contact and Cross-Ownership in the Mobile Telephone Industry. The RAND Journal of Economics 28: Accessed September 25, Scherer, F.M., and David Ross Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company. Schmalensee, Richard Brand Loyalty and Barriers to Entry. Southern Economic Journal 40: Accessed February 1, Viscusi, Kip W., Joseph E. Harrington, Jr., and John M. Vernon Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Wireless Telecommunications Bureau Wireless Telecommunications Bureau Seeks Comment on the State of Mobile Wireless Competition. Federal Communications Commission. Public Notice. Wireless Telecommunications Bureau Mobile Wireless Competition Report (15thAnnual). Federal Communications Commission.

25 25

REMONOPOLIZING LOCAL TELEPHONE MARKETS: IS WIRELESS NEXT?

REMONOPOLIZING LOCAL TELEPHONE MARKETS: IS WIRELESS NEXT? REMONOPOLIZING LOCAL TELEPHONE MARKETS: IS WIRELESS NEXT? Mark Cooper July 2004 FEDERAL AND STATE ANTITRUST OFFICIALS SHOULD SAY NO TO THE CINGULAR- AT&T WIRELESS MERGER The exit of AT&T Communications,

More information

National Carriers - Advantages and Disadvantages

National Carriers - Advantages and Disadvantages Kaetzer Mastin 1 The National Market for Cellular Phone Service Tim Kaetzer and Dana Mastin Econ 200 Fall 2004 The national cellular market is undoubtedly one of the nation s most expansive markets. In

More information

Spectrum Policy and the Evolution of the Wireless Internet: Some Thoughts on Where Economists Agree and Disagree Smith School Working Paper Series

Spectrum Policy and the Evolution of the Wireless Internet: Some Thoughts on Where Economists Agree and Disagree Smith School Working Paper Series Spectrum Policy and the Evolution of the Wireless Internet: Some Thoughts on Where Economists Agree and Disagree Smith School Working Paper Series November 2013 25 March 2013 Working Paper 13-03 Robert

More information

AT&T: A Natural Monopoly Worth Preserving or Destroying?

AT&T: A Natural Monopoly Worth Preserving or Destroying? AT&T: A Natural Monopoly Worth Preserving or Destroying? The saga of the rise and fall of AT&T in America is a story of ever adjusting social and political attitudes toward the economic and social benefits

More information

Economics Chapter 7 Review

Economics Chapter 7 Review Name: Class: Date: ID: A Economics Chapter 7 Review Matching a. perfect competition e. imperfect competition b. efficiency f. price and output c. start-up costs g. technological barrier d. commodity h.

More information

INTRODUCTION OLIGOPOLY CHARACTERISTICS OF MARKET STRUCTURES DEGREES OF POWER DETERMINANTS OF MARKET POWER

INTRODUCTION OLIGOPOLY CHARACTERISTICS OF MARKET STRUCTURES DEGREES OF POWER DETERMINANTS OF MARKET POWER INTRODUCTION Questions examined in this chapter include: What determines how much market power a firm has? How do firms in an oligopoly set prices and output? What problems does an oligopoly have in maintaining

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Chap 13 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly These questions may include topics that were not covered in class and may not be on the exam. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes

More information

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy After reading Chapter 7, MONOPOLY, OLIGOPOLY AND STRATEGY, you should be able to: Define the characteristics of Monopoly and Oligopoly, and explain why the are

More information

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly WSG10 7/7/03 4:24 PM Page 145 10 Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly OVERVIEW An oligopoly is an industry comprising a few firms. A duopoly, which is a special case of oligopoly, is an industry consisting

More information

Kelly Cameron +1(301) 768-7263 kcameron@camerontelecomlaw.com +216 95 320 650. 26 janvier 2015

Kelly Cameron +1(301) 768-7263 kcameron@camerontelecomlaw.com +216 95 320 650. 26 janvier 2015 TUNISIA BUSINESS REFORM AND COMPETITIVENESS PROJECT Workshop sur le Service Universel L Expérience Américaine Kelly Cameron +1(301) 768-7263 kcameron@camerontelecomlaw.com +216 95 320 650 26 janvier 2015

More information

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1 Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1 Key Terms perfect competition: a market structure in which a large number of firms all produce the same product and no single seller controls supply or prices commodity:

More information

MONOPOLIES HOW ARE MONOPOLIES ACHIEVED?

MONOPOLIES HOW ARE MONOPOLIES ACHIEVED? Monopoly 18 The public, policy-makers, and economists are concerned with the power that monopoly industries have. In this chapter I discuss how monopolies behave and the case against monopolies. The case

More information

Chart 1. Telecommunications employment, 1990 2005

Chart 1. Telecommunications employment, 1990 2005 Cutting the cord: telecommunications employment shifts toward wireless The telecommunications industry employment rapidly grew in the late 1990s into early 2001; ever-changing technology, advances in wireless

More information

1 of 14 11/5/2013 4:33 PM

1 of 14 11/5/2013 4:33 PM 1 of 14 11/5/2013 4:33 PM Market power is A characteristic of all market structures. The ability to alter the market price of a product. Most common for competitive firms. Enjoyed by all firms at high

More information

Economists Statement on Network Neutrality Policy

Economists Statement on Network Neutrality Policy J O I N T C E N T E R AEI-BROOKINGS JOINT CENTER FOR REGULATORY STUDIES Economists Statement on Network Neutrality Policy William J. Baumol, Martin Cave, Peter Cramton, Robert Hahn, Thomas W. Hazlett,

More information

What Is a Barrier to Entry?

What Is a Barrier to Entry? WHEN ARE SUNK COSTS BARRIERS TO ENTRY? ENTRY BARRIERS IN ECONOMIC AND ANTITRUST ANALYSIS What Is a Barrier to Entry? By R. PRESTON MCAFEE, HUGO M. MIALON, AND MICHAEL A. WILLIAMS* Discussants: Steve Berry,

More information

Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17

Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17 Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17 Multiple Choice Questions 1. The kinked-demand curve model of oligopoly: A. assumes a firm's rivals will ignore a price cut but match a price increase. B. embodies the possibility

More information

Wireless Telecommunication Industry Overview

Wireless Telecommunication Industry Overview Wireless Telecommunication Industry Overview Columbia Graduate Consulting Club February 13, 2012 Pablo Prieto-Muñoz COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY Civil Engineering and Engineering Mechanics Global mobile phone subscribers

More information

U.S. Competition Policy ITU. John Alden Freedom Technologies, Inc. November 20, 2002 Geneva, Switzerland

U.S. Competition Policy ITU. John Alden Freedom Technologies, Inc. November 20, 2002 Geneva, Switzerland U.S. Competition Policy ITU John Alden Freedom Technologies, Inc. November 20, 2002 Geneva, Switzerland The United States Basic Facts Population: 287.9 million (2002 estimate) Area: 3.54 million square

More information

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE Statement of JOEL I. KLEIN Assistant Attorney General Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice Before the House Committee on the Judiciary Concerning Consolidation in the Telecommunications

More information

Models of Imperfect Competition

Models of Imperfect Competition Models of Imperfect Competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Models of Imperfect Competition So far, we have discussed two forms of market competition that are difficult to observe in practice Perfect

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) The four-firm concentration ratio equals the percentage of the value of accounted for by the four

More information

Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures. Perfect competition is a in which a large number of all produce.

Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures. Perfect competition is a in which a large number of all produce. Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures Perfect competition is a in which a large number of all produce. There are Four Conditions for Perfect Competition: 1. 2. 3. 4. Barriers to Entry Factors that make

More information

English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE

English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE For Official Use DAF/COMP/WD(2012)78 DAF/COMP/WD(2012)78 For Official Use Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 08-Oct-2012

More information

MERGER GUIDELINES COMPETITION COMMISSION OF PAKISTAN

MERGER GUIDELINES COMPETITION COMMISSION OF PAKISTAN MERGER GUIDELINES COMPETITION COMMISSION OF PAKISTAN I. INTRODUCTION... 2 II. OVERVIEW... 3 III. MARKET SHARE AND CONCENTRATION LEVELS... 4 1. Market share levels... 6 2. HHI levels... 6 IV. POSSIBLE ANTI-COMPETITIVE

More information

An Oligopoly Analysis of AT&T s Performance in the Wireline Long- Distance Markets After Divestiture

An Oligopoly Analysis of AT&T s Performance in the Wireline Long- Distance Markets After Divestiture An Oligopoly Analysis of AT&T s Performance in the Wireline Long- Distance Markets After Divestiture Paul W. MacAvoy* Having been present at the creation of divestiture, as the next witness for the defense

More information

Imperfect Competition. Oligopoly. Types of Imperfectly Competitive Markets. Imperfect Competition. Markets With Only a Few Sellers

Imperfect Competition. Oligopoly. Types of Imperfectly Competitive Markets. Imperfect Competition. Markets With Only a Few Sellers Imperfect Competition Oligopoly Chapter 16 Imperfect competition refers to those market structures that fall between perfect competition and pure monopoly. Copyright 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.

More information

Qihoo v. Tencent: economic analysis of the first Chinese Supreme Court decision under Anti-Monopoly Law

Qihoo v. Tencent: economic analysis of the first Chinese Supreme Court decision under Anti-Monopoly Law February 2015 Qihoo v. Tencent: economic analysis of the first Chinese Supreme Court decision under Anti-Monopoly Law The October 16, 2014 Chinese Supreme People s Court (SPC) decision on Qihoo 360 v.

More information

Tech Briefing 2001 A Free-Market Guide to Navigating Tech Issues in the 107th Congress

Tech Briefing 2001 A Free-Market Guide to Navigating Tech Issues in the 107th Congress Tech Briefing 2001 A Free-Market Guide to Navigating Tech Issues in the 107th Congress Telecommunications and Media Mergers by James Gattuso TELECOMMUNICATIONS AND MEDIA MERGERS 8 Over the past two years,

More information

Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic Chapter 17 Copyright 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to: Permissions Department, Harcourt College

More information

Market Failure. presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell esewell@uncc.edu

Market Failure. presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell esewell@uncc.edu Market Failure presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell esewell@uncc.edu In general, a system of competitive markets will produce a socially optimal allocation of resources. What does this mean? When does a market

More information

Chapter 16 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

Chapter 16 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly Chapter 16 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly Market Structure Market structure refers to the physical characteristics of the market within which firms interact It is determined by the number of firms

More information

Introduction to microeconomics

Introduction to microeconomics RELEVANT TO ACCA QUALIFICATION PAPER F1 / FOUNDATIONS IN ACCOUNTANCY PAPER FAB Introduction to microeconomics The new Paper F1/FAB, Accountant in Business carried over many subjects from its Paper F1 predecessor,

More information

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of ) ) CenturyLink s Petition for Forbearance ) WC Docket No. 14-9 Pursuant to 47 U.S.C. 160(c) from ) Dominant Carrier

More information

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition Chapter Summary Now that you understand the model of a perfectly competitive market, this chapter complicates

More information

Telephone Service: A Natural Monopoly?

Telephone Service: A Natural Monopoly? Box 6-2 continued By June 2003, this had grown to 88 percent. A recent study indicates that the introduction of satellite TV led to substantial gains for consumers. However, ongoing antitrust oversight

More information

LECTURE #15: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 17

LECTURE #15: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 17 LECTURE #15: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 17 I. IMPORTANT DEFINITIONS A. Oligopoly: a market structure with a few sellers offering similar or identical products. B. Game Theory: the study of how people behave

More information

Annex 8. Market Failure in Broadcasting

Annex 8. Market Failure in Broadcasting Annex 8 Market Failure in Broadcasting 202 Review of the Future Funding of the BBC Market Failure in the Broadcasting Industry An efficient broadcasting market? Economic efficiency is a situation in which

More information

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade I. Introduction to Strategic Trade Policy If much of world trade is in differentiated products (ie manufactures) characterized by increasing returns to scale,

More information

Private Sector Investment and Employment Impacts of Reassigning Spectrum to Mobile Broadband in the United States

Private Sector Investment and Employment Impacts of Reassigning Spectrum to Mobile Broadband in the United States Private Sector Investment and Employment Impacts of Reassigning Spectrum to Mobile Broadband in the United States Authors: David W. Sosa, Ph.D. 415-263-2217 dsosa@analysisgroup.com Marc Van Audenrode,

More information

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives 4-63. Market Structures

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives 4-63. Market Structures 1. Supply and Demand: Introduction 3 2. Supply and Demand: Consumer Demand 33 3. Supply and Demand: Company Analysis 43 4. Market Structures 63 5. Key Formulas 81 2014 Allen Resources, Inc. All rights

More information

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q).

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q). A monopolist s marginal revenue is always less than or equal to the price of the good. Marginal revenue is the amount of revenue the firm receives for each additional unit of output. It is the difference

More information

Issue Brief: How to Deal with Data Caps, Sponsored Data and Zero- Rating

Issue Brief: How to Deal with Data Caps, Sponsored Data and Zero- Rating Issue Brief: How to Deal with Data Caps, Sponsored Data and Zero- Rating Matt Wood Free Press The FCC adopted its landmark Open Internet Order nearly a year ago. In this the agency made the correct decision

More information

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE CHAPTER SUMMARY This chapter presents an economic analysis of market structure. It starts with perfect competition as a benchmark. Potential barriers to entry, that might limit

More information

The Merger of Digicel & Claro is likely to hurt Mobile Phone Customers

The Merger of Digicel & Claro is likely to hurt Mobile Phone Customers The Merger of Digicel & Claro is likely to hurt Mobile Phone Customers David Miller 1 Executive Director, Fair Trading Commission (FTC) January 17, 2012 Ladies and Gentlemen, a pleasant good afternoon.

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. MBA 640 Survey of Microeconomics Fall 2006, Quiz 6 Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) A monopoly is best defined as a firm that

More information

Chapter 6 Lecture. Market Structures

Chapter 6 Lecture. Market Structures Chapter 6 Lecture Market Structures Market Structures Two basic types of markets (1) Highly competitive markets Example is the jeans market A large selection of producers & high demand (2) Imperfectly

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Offer similar or identical products Interdependent. How people behave in strategic situations

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Offer similar or identical products Interdependent. How people behave in strategic situations Oligopoly PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1 Oligopoly Only a few sellers Oligopoly Offer similar or identical products Interdependent Game theory How people

More information

Defining Relevant Markets for Leased Lines: the Interface with Local Loop Unbundling

Defining Relevant Markets for Leased Lines: the Interface with Local Loop Unbundling Defining Relevant Markets for Leased Lines: the Interface with Local Loop Unbundling Professor Howard Williams University of Strathclyde Glasgow GI 5QE Paper presented to the EC Sector Inquiry on the Competitive

More information

CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION

CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION Chapter in a Nutshell Now that we understand the characteristics of different market structures, we ask the question

More information

Healthy Competition. Anna Hamburg-Gal Student Fellow, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies

Healthy Competition. Anna Hamburg-Gal Student Fellow, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies Healthy Competition Anna Hamburg-Gal Student Fellow, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies On Nov 7, 2009, the House of Representatives approved a health care bill, the Affordable Health Care for America

More information

A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market

A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market Thomas CORTADE LASER-CREDEN, University of Montpellier Abstract: This paper looks at a new body of literature that deals with two-sided

More information

Internet Telephones: Hanging up on Regulation?

Internet Telephones: Hanging up on Regulation? J O I N T C E N T E R AEI-BROOKINGS JOINT CENTER FOR REGULATORY STUDIES Internet Telephones: Hanging up on Regulation? Robert W. Crandall, Robert W. Hahn, Robert E. Litan, and Scott Wallsten * Regulatory

More information

Real Competition? Proposed Deregulation of Local Telephone Service in Illinois

Real Competition? Proposed Deregulation of Local Telephone Service in Illinois Real Competition? Proposed Deregulation of Local Telephone Service in Illinois Introduction Shirley T. Chiu Student Fellow, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies Loyola University Chicago School of

More information

How To Review Chapter 364 Of The Florida State Constitution

How To Review Chapter 364 Of The Florida State Constitution The Florida Senate Interim Report 2011-108 October 2010 Committee on Communications, Energy, and Public Utilities REVIEW CHAPTER 364, FLORIDA STATUTES, RELATING TO TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMPANIES TO IDENTIFY

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Economics 103 Spring 2012: Multiple choice review questions for final exam. Exam will cover chapters on perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition and oligopoly up to the Nash equilibrium

More information

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 14 - Monopoly Fall 2010 Herriges (ISU) Ch. 14 Monopoly Fall 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 Monopolies What Monopolies Do 2 Profit Maximization for the Monopolist 3

More information

Delta College Frequently Asked Questions About The FCC Broadcast Spectrum Incentive Auction

Delta College Frequently Asked Questions About The FCC Broadcast Spectrum Incentive Auction Delta College Frequently Asked Questions About The FCC Broadcast Spectrum Incentive Auction 1. What is spectrum? The term spectrum refers to the frequencies over which signals can be transmitted for a

More information

Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic Competition In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: How is similar to perfect? How is it similar to monopoly? How do ally competitive firms choose price and? Do they earn economic profit? In what

More information

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7. 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7. 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table. AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table. a. Fill in the table by calculating total revenue and marginal revenue at each price.

More information

1 Annex 11: Market failure in broadcasting

1 Annex 11: Market failure in broadcasting 1 Annex 11: Market failure in broadcasting 1.1 This annex builds on work done by Ofcom regarding market failure in a number of previous projects. In particular, we discussed the types of market failure

More information

Regulatory Reclassification of Broadband Internet Access Service is the Unsurprising Result of ISPs Inexplicable Challenges to FCC Authority

Regulatory Reclassification of Broadband Internet Access Service is the Unsurprising Result of ISPs Inexplicable Challenges to FCC Authority Regulatory Reclassification of Broadband Internet Access Service is the Unsurprising Result of ISPs Inexplicable Challenges to FCC Authority An Open Internet has long been a bipartisan goal in the United

More information

Review of recent CCSA experiences in the Telecommunications Sector Kazan, Russia. Selelo Ramohlola & Tapera Muzata 31 March 3 April 2015

Review of recent CCSA experiences in the Telecommunications Sector Kazan, Russia. Selelo Ramohlola & Tapera Muzata 31 March 3 April 2015 Review of recent CCSA experiences in the Telecommunications Sector Kazan, Russia Selelo Ramohlola & Tapera Muzata 31 March 3 April 2015 Outline of Presentation Opening remarks Introduction & background

More information

Click to edit Master title style

Click to edit Master title style Click to edit Master title style BASIC PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS FOR COMPETITION LAW Lino Briguglio University of Malta Economic principles.1 Competition as a desirable condition In mainstream Microeconomics,

More information

Telecommunications Regulation. PAKISTAN Rizvi, Isa, Afridi & Angell

Telecommunications Regulation. PAKISTAN Rizvi, Isa, Afridi & Angell Telecommunications Regulation PAKISTAN Rizvi, Isa, Afridi & Angell CONTACT INFORMATION Ahsan Zahir Rizvi Rizvi, Isa, Afridi & Angell D-67 Block 4, Clifton Karachi Pakistan 009221-5865198 arizvi@riaalaw.com

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry 14.23 Government Regulation of Industry Class 8: Franchise Bidding and CATV MIT & University of Cambridge 1 Outline Why regulate utilities? Franchising benefits Contractual problems CATV (community-antenna

More information

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024 Business Brief Consolidation Index: Critical Success Factors for Industry Consolidation 1 ESMT No. BB-107-002 ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT ISSN 1866 4024 2 Business Brief Consolidation

More information

Position Statement on Cable Television Regulation in Maine. Submitted by New England Cable and Telecommunications Association ( NECTA ) June 2009

Position Statement on Cable Television Regulation in Maine. Submitted by New England Cable and Telecommunications Association ( NECTA ) June 2009 Position Statement on Cable Television Regulation in Maine Submitted by New England Cable and Telecommunications Association ( NECTA ) June 2009 NECTA is a nonprofit corporation and trade association that

More information

The key elements of GSL V s strategy are (see Item 1. Business of the Crown Castle 10-K for further discussion):

The key elements of GSL V s strategy are (see Item 1. Business of the Crown Castle 10-K for further discussion): Management s Discussion and Analysis of Financial Condition and Results of Operations The following management s discussion and analysis ( MD&A ) of the combined financial condition and results of operations

More information

Mortgages and Forced Programming in the MVPD Market

Mortgages and Forced Programming in the MVPD Market Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of ) ) MM Docket 07-269 Annual Assessment of the Status of ) Competition in the Market for the ) Delivery of Video Programming

More information

LESSONS LEARNED FROM FTC INVESTIGATIONS AND CHALLENGES OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER TRANSACTIONS

LESSONS LEARNED FROM FTC INVESTIGATIONS AND CHALLENGES OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER TRANSACTIONS LESSONS LEARNED FROM FTC INVESTIGATIONS AND CHALLENGES OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER TRANSACTIONS February 26, 2014 Gregory L. Baker, Pamela Jones Harbour, Jonathan L. Lewis, Lee H. Simowitz. Agenda Introductions

More information

Remarks on Broadband Competition and Access Regulation

Remarks on Broadband Competition and Access Regulation Remarks on Broadband Competition and Access Regulation Marius Schwartz* FCC Workshop on Economic Issues in Broadband Competition Washington, DC October 9, 2009 * Professor of Economics, Georgetown University,

More information

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000. PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000. PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam. , Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam. SIGNED: PRINT NAME: Econ 201 Final Exam 1. For a profit-maximizing monopolist, a. MR

More information

Quality of Customer Service report

Quality of Customer Service report Quality of Customer Service report Prepared for: Ofcom Published: December Contents Section Page Introduction... 2 Executive summary... 6 Overview of sectors... 11 Landline sector... 24 Broadband sector...

More information

BEFORE THE PENNSYLVANIA SENATE CONSUMER PROTECTION AND PROFESSIONAL LICENSURE AND COMMUNICATIONS AND HIGH TECHNOLOGY COMMITTEES

BEFORE THE PENNSYLVANIA SENATE CONSUMER PROTECTION AND PROFESSIONAL LICENSURE AND COMMUNICATIONS AND HIGH TECHNOLOGY COMMITTEES BEFORE THE PENNSYLVANIA SENATE CONSUMER PROTECTION AND PROFESSIONAL LICENSURE AND COMMUNICATIONS AND HIGH TECHNOLOGY COMMITTEES Testimony of SONNY POPOWSKY CONSUMER ADVOCATE OF PENNSYLVANIA Regarding Local

More information

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14 ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14 MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) An oligopoly firm is similar to a monopolistically competitive

More information

Masters in Engineering and Management of Technology Masters in engineering Design Introduction to Entrepreneurship and New Venture Creation

Masters in Engineering and Management of Technology Masters in engineering Design Introduction to Entrepreneurship and New Venture Creation Masters in Engineering and Management of Technology Masters in engineering Design Introduction to Entrepreneurship and New Venture Creation Rui Baptista The Structural Analysis of Industries What is Strategy?

More information

BEFORE THE FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION. Washington, D.C. 20554

BEFORE THE FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION. Washington, D.C. 20554 BEFORE THE FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of THE PROVISION OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS SERVICE VIA "CABLE INTERNET" UNITED STATES INTERNET INDUSTRY ASSOCIATION ("USIIA"),

More information

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases Business Ethics Concepts & Cases Manuel G. Velasquez Chapter Four Ethics in the Marketplace Definition of Market A forum in which people come together to exchange ownership of goods; a place where goods

More information

Bandwidth for the People

Bandwidth for the People J O I N T C E N T E R AEI-BROOKINGS JOINT CENTER FOR REGULATORY STUDIES Bandwidth for the People Robert W. Crandall, Robert W. Hahn, Robert E. Litan, and Scott Wallsten * Regulatory Analysis 04-01 May

More information

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 1 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing In this section we consider how firms compete when there are few sellers an oligopolistic market (from the Greek). Small

More information

FCC Adopts Controversial Net Neutrality Rules Governing Broadband Internet Access Services

FCC Adopts Controversial Net Neutrality Rules Governing Broadband Internet Access Services January 2011 FCC Adopts Controversial Net Neutrality Rules Governing Broadband Internet Access Services BY CARL W. NORTHROP, MICHAEL LAZARUS & DAVID DARWIN The Federal Communications Commission (the FCC

More information

CARLETON UNIVERSITY. Department of Economics ECON 4302. Competition and Regulatory Policy

CARLETON UNIVERSITY. Department of Economics ECON 4302. Competition and Regulatory Policy CARLETON UNIVERSITY Department of Economics ECON 4302 Competition and Regulatory Policy Instructor: D.G. McFetridge Fall Term 2011 Office: A806 Loeb Building Phone: 613-520-2600 ext. 3748 E-mail: donald_mcfetridge@carleton.ca

More information

Analyzing Telecommunications Market Competition: Foundations for Best Practices. By Janice Hauge and Mark Jamison *

Analyzing Telecommunications Market Competition: Foundations for Best Practices. By Janice Hauge and Mark Jamison * Analyzing Telecommunications Market Competition: Foundations for Best Practices By Janice Hauge and Mark Jamison * Public Utility Research Center University of Florida Gainesville, Florida 29 October 2009

More information

Broadcasting and Telecom Regulatory Policy CRTC 2014-576

Broadcasting and Telecom Regulatory Policy CRTC 2014-576 Broadcasting and Telecom Regulatory Policy CRTC 2014-576 PDF version Route reference: 2014-190 Additional references: 2014-190-1, 2014-190-2, 2014-190-3, and 2014-190-4 Ottawa, 6 November 2014 File number:

More information

Global Forum on Competition

Global Forum on Competition Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF/WD(2005)3 DAF/COMP/GF/WD(2005)3 Unclassified Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 12-Jan-2005 English

More information

Questions for the Record from Chairman John Thune To Mr. Scott Bergmann

Questions for the Record from Chairman John Thune To Mr. Scott Bergmann Questions for the Record from Chairman John Thune To Mr. Scott Bergmann Question 1. Based on studies submitted by the FCC, the GAO Report concluded that many lowincome households would choose to subscribe

More information

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matters of ) ) Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet ) GN Docket No. 14-28 ) Preserving the Open Internet ) GN Docket No.

More information

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: Why do monopolies arise? Why is MR < P for a monopolist? How do monopolies choose their P and Q? How do monopolies affect society s well-being?

More information

Remarks of Gigi B. Sohn Counselor to the Chairman Before the ECTA Regulatory Conference 2015 Brussels, Belgium November 17, 2015

Remarks of Gigi B. Sohn Counselor to the Chairman Before the ECTA Regulatory Conference 2015 Brussels, Belgium November 17, 2015 Remarks of Gigi B. Sohn Counselor to the Chairman Before the ECTA Regulatory Conference 2015 Brussels, Belgium November 17, 2015 Good morning. Thank you Hubertus von Roenne for that lovely introduction.

More information

Electronic Commerce and Competition (October 2000)

Electronic Commerce and Competition (October 2000) Office of Economic Competition Electronic Commerce and Competition (October 2000) 1. Introduction The competition policy approach towards electronic commerce - as the market is in continuous change - is

More information

Financial Stages of a Farmer s Life: Effects on Credit Analysis Measures

Financial Stages of a Farmer s Life: Effects on Credit Analysis Measures Financial Stages of a Farmer s Life: Effects on Credit Analysis Measures By Paul N. Ellinger, Freddie L. Barnard, and Christine Wilson Abstract Farm financial performance measures are evaluated for producers

More information

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 15 - Oligopoly Fall 2010 Herriges (ISU) Ch. 15 Oligopoly Fall 2010 1 / 25 Outline 1 Understanding Oligopolies 2 Game Theory Overcoming the Prisoner s Dilemma

More information

FTTx Roll-out: A Commercial Perspective beyond Technology

FTTx Roll-out: A Commercial Perspective beyond Technology Opinion Paper FTTx Roll-out: A Commercial Perspective beyond Technology 2010 / 11 We make ICT strategies work Table of Contents 1 Motivation...3 2 Roll-out Levers...4 2.1 Demand Drivers...4 2.2 Competitive

More information

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry 14.23 Government Regulation of Industry Class 1 MIT & University of Cambridge 1 Outline Definitions Course Outline Introduction to Social Cost Benefit Analysis Economic Regulation in Practice Costs and

More information

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) Chapter Summary Now that you understand the model of a perfectly competitive market, this chapter complicates the

More information

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES (Bench Opinion) OCTOBER TERM 2004 1 NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus constitutes

More information

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of ) ) Petition of Union Electric Company ) WC Docket No. 13-307 D/B/A Ameren Missouri for Declaratory ) Ruling Concerning

More information

Universal Service in the United States

Universal Service in the United States Universal Service in the United States Dr. Krishna Jayakar Co-Director, Institute for Information Policy Co-Editor, Journal of Information Policy Penn State University January 17, 2016 A summary One of

More information