Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data"

Transcription

1 Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data Dennis Novy y University of Warwick April 2008 Abstract Barriers to international trade are known to be large. But have they become smaller over time? Building on the gravity framework by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), I derive an analytical solution for time-varying and observable multilateral resistance variables. This solution gives rise to a micro-founded gravity equation from which bilateral trade costs can be directly inferred. This approach is easy to implement and obviates the need to impose arbitrary trade cost functions. As an illustration, I show that U.S. trade costs with major trading partners declined on average by about 40 percent between 970 and 2000, with Mexico and Canada experiencing the biggest reductions. JEL classi cation: F0, F5 Keywords: Trade Costs, Gravity, Multilateral Resistance I am grateful to participants at the 2007 NBER Summer Institute (International Trade and Investment), in particular James Harrigan, David Hummels, Nuno Limão and Peter Neary. I am also grateful to Iwan Barankay, Je rey Bergstrand, Natalie Chen, Alejandro Cuñat, Robert Feenstra, David Jacks, Chris Meissner, Niko Wolf, Adrian Wood, seminar participants at Oxford University and at the European Trade Study Group. y Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, United Kingdom. d.novy@warwick.ac.uk and /faculty/novy/

2 Introduction Barriers to international trade are large and of considerable interest to policymakers. The tool that economists use most frequently to calculate the magnitude of trade barriers is the gravity equation. The typical gravity equation relates two countries bilateral trade ows to their economic size and to various bilateral trade barriers such as distance, linguistic di erences, tari s and exchange rate volatility. It is the aim of most empirical gravity work to identify and measure such bilateral trade barriers. However, in order to infer such bilateral trade barriers, researchers must also account for countries average trade barriers. In an important and highly in uential paper, James Anderson and Eric van Wincoop (2003) demonstrate that it is not only bilateral trade barriers but also multilateral trade barriers that determine the trade ows between two countries. For example, trade between the U.S. and Canada is not only in uenced by the U.S.-Canadian trade barrier. If U.S. trade barriers go down with all countries in the world except for Canada, then some U.S. trade will be diverted away from Canada although the bilateral U.S.-Canadian barrier itself has not changed. What matters therefore is the bilateral relative to the multilateral trade barrier. The purpose of this paper is to develop a methodology for measuring bilateral trade barriers. The contribution of the paper is twofold. First, building on the gravity model by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) I derive an analytical solution for time-varying multilateral trade barriers, or multilateral resistance variables, that only depends on observable trade data. These multilateral trade barriers have been acknowledged for some time, for example by Anderson (979), Bergstrand (985) and Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), but so far it has been either impossible or very cumbersome to solve for them. Second, with the solution for multilateral resistance variables at hand, I am able to derive a theoretically consistent gravity equation that implies a micro-founded trade cost measure. This trade cost measure controls for multilateral resistance and can be directly computed from observable trade data without imposing a trade cost function that is assumed to rely on distance or other trade cost proxies. Generalizing the approach by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), who only consider cross-sectional data, the trade cost measure is able to capture how trade costs change over time and can therefore be used with time series and panel data. Another advantage of the trade cost measure is that it captures a wide range of trade cost components including those that are not typically considered in standard gravity regressions. For example, the measure can capture informational trade costs as identi ed by Portes and Rey (2005) as well as hidden transaction costs due to poor security as

3 identi ed by Anderson and Marcouiller (2002). As an illustration I compute U.S. bilateral trade costs with a number of major trading partners. Over the period U.S. trade costs declined by about 40 percent, consistent with improvements in transportation and communication technology and the formation of free trade agreements such at NAFTA. In addition, I show that if multilateral resistance variables are misspeci ed as constants, trade cost estimates are likely to be biased because they will fail to account for secular trends in multilateral resistance. The paper is organized as follows. Building on the model by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) I show in Section 2 how multilateral resistance variables can be expressed as a function of observable trade data. I also show how this expression can in turn be used to derive the micro-founded measure of bilateral trade costs. As an illustration Section 3 presents U.S. bilateral trade costs for a number of major trading partners. In Section 4 I provide a brief discussion of the results before concluding in Section 5. 2 International Trade with Trade Costs 2. The Anderson and van Wincoop Gravity Model Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) develop a multi-country general equilibrium model of international trade. Each country is endowed with a single good that is di erentiated from those produced by other countries. Optimizing individual consumers enjoy consuming a large variety of domestic and foreign goods. Their preferences are assumed to be identical across countries and are captured by constant elasticity of substitution utility. As the key element in their model, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) introduce exogenous bilateral trade costs. When a good is shipped from country i to j, bilateral variable transportation costs and other variable trade barriers drive up the cost of each unit shipped. 2 As a result of trade costs, goods prices can di er across countries. Specifically, if p i is the net supply price of the good originating in country i, then p ij = p i t ij is the price of this good faced by consumers in country j, where t ij is the gross bilateral trade cost factor (one plus the tari equivalent). Based on this framework Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) derive a micro-founded Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) refer to regions instead of countries but this is irrelevant for the subsequent analysis. 2 Modeling trade costs in this way is well established in the literature. It is consistent with the iceberg formulation of trade costs that portrays trade costs as if an iceberg were shipped across the ocean and partly melted in transit (e.g., Samuelson, 954 and Krugman, 980). 2

4 gravity equation with trade costs: x ij = y iy j y W tij i P j () where x ij denotes nominal exports from i to j, y i is nominal income of country i and y W is world income de ned as y W P j y j. > is the elasticity of substitution across goods. i and P j are country i s and country j s price indices. The gravity equation implies that all else being equal, bigger countries trade more with each other. Bilateral trade costs t ij decrease bilateral trade but they have to be measured against the price indices i and P j. Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) call these price indices multilateral resistance variables because they include trade costs with all other partners and can be interpreted as average trade costs. Their exact expressions are P i = X j j = X i P j j t ij 8i (2) i i t ij 8j (3) where j is the world income share of country j de ned as j y j =y W. i is the outward multilateral resistance variable as it includes bilateral trade costs t ij summed over and weighted by all destination countries j, whereas P j is the inward multilateral resistance variable as it includes bilateral trade costs t ij summed over and weighted by all origin countries i. Thus, an important insight from gravity equation () is that bilateral trade ows do not only depend on the bilateral trade barrier but also on the multilateral trade barriers of the two countries involved. What matters is the relative trade barrier. 2.2 The Link between Multilateral Resistance and Intranational Trade It has been a problem in the literature to nd appropriate expressions for the multilateral resistance variables in equations (2) and (3). Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) point out that in general i and P j should not be interpreted as consumer price indices. For example, a home bias in preferences would yield the same gravity equation as () and the same expressions for i and P j as in equations (2) and (3). But then i and P j would include the nonpecuniary home bias and could therefore no longer be regarded as consumer price indices. 3

5 Instead, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) assume that bilateral trade costs are a function of two particular trade cost proxies - a border barrier and geographical distance. In particular, they assume the trade cost function t ij = b ij d ij where b ij is a borderrelated indicator variable, d ij is bilateral distance and is the distance elasticity. In addition, they simplify the model by assuming that bilateral trade costs are symmetric (i.e., t ij = t ji ). Under the symmetry assumption it follows that outward and inward multilateral resistance are the same (i.e., i = P i ). Thus, conditioning on these additional assumptions, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) nd an implicit solution for multilateral resistance based on (2) and (3). But there are a number of drawbacks associated with the additional assumptions. 3 First, the chosen trade cost function might be misspeci ed. Its functional form might be incorrect and it might omit important trade cost determinants such as tari s. Second, bilateral trade costs might be asymmetric, for example if one country imposes higher tari s than the other. Moreover, in practice trade barriers are time-varying, for example when countries phase out tari s. Time-invariant trade cost proxies such as distance are therefore hardly useful in capturing trade cost changes over time. In what follows, I propose a method that helps to overcome these drawbacks by deriving an analytical solution for multilateral resistance variables. This method does not rely on any particular trade cost function and it does not impose trade cost symmetry. Instead, trade costs are inferred from time-varying trade data that are readily observable. Intuitively, our method makes use of the insight that a change in bilateral trade barriers does not only a ect international trade but also intranational trade. For example, suppose that country i s trade barriers with all other countries increase. In that case, some of the goods that i used to ship to foreign countries are now consumed domestically, i.e., intranationally. It is therefore not only the extent of international trade that depends on trade barriers with the rest of the world but also the extent of intranational trade. It turns out that there is a direct relationship between a country s multilateral resistance and its intranational trade ows. This can be seen formally by using gravity equation () to nd an expression for country i s intranational trade x ii = y iy i y W tii i P i (4) where t ii represents intranational trade costs, for example domestic transportation costs. Equation (4) can be solved for the product of outward and inward multilateral resistance 3 Anderson and van Wincoop (2003, p. 80) provide a brief discussion on this point. 4

6 as i P i = xii =y ( ) i tii (5) y i =y W For example, suppose two countries i and j face the same domestic trade costs t ii = t jj and are of the same size y i = y j but country i is a more closed economy, that is, x ii > x jj. It follows directly from (5) that multilateral resistance is higher for country i ( i P i > j P j ). Expression (5) implies that for given t ii it is easy to measure the change in multilateral resistance over time as P i does not depend on time-invariant trade cost proxies such as distance. Multilateral resistance can also be thought of in terms of trade diversion and trade creation. For given output y i and y W and given domestic trade costs t ii, trade diversion from one bilateral trading partner to another does not a ect domestic trade x ii and therefore neither multilateral resistance. However, trade creation implies a drop in domestic trade and therefore a drop in multilateral resistance. 2.3 A Micro-Founded Measure of Trade Costs The explicit solution for the multilateral resistance variables can be exploited to solve the general equilibrium model for bilateral trade costs. Gravity equation () contains the product of outward multilateral resistance of one country and inward multilateral resistance of another country, i P j, whereas equation (5) provides a solution for i P i. It is therefore useful to multiply gravity equation () by the corresponding gravity equation for trade ows in the opposite direction, x ji, to obtain a bidirectional gravity equation that contains both countries outward and inward multilateral resistance variables: x ij x ji = 2 yi y j tij t ji y W i P i j P j Substituting the solution from equation (5) yields tii t jj x ij x ji = x ii x jj (6) t ij t ji The size variable in gravity equation (6) is not total income y i y j as in traditional gravity equations but intranational trade x ii x jj. Intranational trade does not only control for the countries economic size, but according to equation (5) it is also directly linked to 5

7 multilateral resistance. (6) can be rearranged as t ij t ji t ii t jj = xii x jj x ij x ji (7) As shipping costs between i and j can be asymmetric (t ij 6= t ji ) and as domestic trade costs can di er across countries (t ii 6= t jj ), it is useful to take the geometric mean of the barriers in both directions. It is also useful to deduct one to get an expression for the tari equivalent. I denote the resulting micro-founded trade cost measure as ij : tij t ji ij t ii t jj 2 xii x jj = x ij x ji 2( ) (8) ij measures bilateral trade costs t ij t ji relative to domestic trade costs t ii t jj. It therefore does not impose frictionless domestic trade and captures what makes international trade more costly over and above domestic trade. 4 The intuition behind ij is straightforward. If bilateral trade ows x ij x ji increase relative to domestic trade ows x ii x jj, it must have become easier for the two countries to trade with each other. This is captured by a decrease in ij, and vice versa. The measure can thus be interpreted as a gravity residual that comprises trade costs comprehensively de ned. This includes trade cost elements which can be observed directly, e.g., transportation costs and tari s, as well as trade cost elements that are unobservable such as informational barriers. The implied bilateral trade costs ij can be directly computed from observable trade data. Since these vary over time, trade costs ij can be computed not only for crosssectional data but also for time series and panel data. This is an advantage over the procedure adopted by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) who only use cross-sectional data. It is important to stress that the trade cost measure ij is consistent with trade imbalances. As can be readily seen from gravity equation (), all else being equal asymmetric bilateral trade costs (t ij 6= t ji ) imply unbalanced bilateral trade ows (x ij 6= x ji ). ij indicates the geometric average of bilateral trade barriers in both directions. 5 But it is 4 ij can also be interpreted as a measure of the international component of trade costs net of distribution trade costs in the destination country. Formally, suppose total gross shipping costs t ij can be decomposed into gross shipping costs up to the border of j, denoted by t ij, times the gross shipping costs within j, denoted by t jj, where t jj is the same for all origins of shipment. It follows t ij = t ij t jj and t ji = t ji t ii so that ij = p t ij t ji. 5 This interpretation follows Anderson and van Wincoop (2003, p. 75). 6

8 not possible to infer the extent of the asymmetry from ij. 3 Illustration 3. U.S. Trade Costs As an illustration of trade costs ij given in (8), I compute U.S. bilateral trade costs for a number of major trading partners. I focus on how these bilateral trade costs have evolved over time. Due to market clearing intranational trade x ii can be rewritten as total income minus total exports, x ii = y i x i. 6 Total exports x i are de ned as the sum of all exports from country i, x i P j6=i x ij. All trade data are taken from the IMF Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS) and denominated in U.S. dollars. GDP data are not suitable as y i because they are based on value added, whereas the trade data are reported as gross shipments. data. 7 In addition, GDP data include services that are not covered by the trade To get the shipment counterpart of GDP excluding services I follow Shang-Jin Wei (996) in constructing y i as total goods production based on the OECD s Structural Analysis (STAN) database. 8 The production data are converted into U.S. dollars by the period average exchange rate taken from the IMF International Financial Statistics (IFS). I consider annual data for In order to remain as close to existing trade cost measures as possible, I follow Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) in setting = 8 for the elasticity of substitution. 9 Figure illustrates U.S. bilateral trade costs with its two biggest trading partners, Canada and Mexico. U.S. trade costs fell dramatically with Mexico (from 96 to 33 percent) and also with Canada (from 50 to 25 percent). The U.S. experienced clear downward trends in trade costs with both its neighbors already prior to the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA, e ective from 994), the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement (CUSFTA, e ective from 989) and unilateral Mexican trade liberalization (from 985). Table reports the levels and the percentage decline in U.S. bilateral trade costs between 970 and 2000 with its six biggest export markets as of In descending order these are Canada, Mexico, Japan, the UK, Germany and Korea. 0 The decline 6 See equation (8) in Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). 7 Anderson (979) acknowledges nontradable services and models the spending on tradables as y i, where is the fraction of total income spent on tradables. But y i would still be based on value added. 8 Wei (996) uses production data for agriculture, mining and total manufacturing. 9 See Section 4 for a discussion of. 0 These six countries are those for which the 2000 share of U.S. exports exceeded 3 percent. Between 7

9 00% 80% U.S. Canada CUSFTA NAFTA 00% 80% U.S. Mexico Unilateral Mexican trade liberalization NAFTA Tariff equivalent τ 60% 40% Tariff equivalent τ 60% 40% 20% 20% Figure : U.S. bilateral trade costs with Canada and Mexico. has been most dramatic with Mexico and Canada and has been sizeable with Korea, the UK, Germany and Japan. The trade-weighted average of U.S. trade costs declined by 44 percent between 970 and 2000, corresponding to an annualized decline of :9 percent per year. Its 2000 level stands at 42 percent. It is important to stress that the trade cost measure ij does not only capture trade costs in the narrow sense of transportation costs and tari s. ij also comprises trade cost components such as language barriers and currency barriers. In their survey on trade costs, Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) show that such non-tari barriers are substantial. The magnitudes of the bilateral trade costs in Table are entirely consistent with previous cross-sectional evidence. But the main advantage of ij over previous trade cost measures is that ij can be easily tracked over time. For the year 993 only, Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) report a 46 percent tari equivalent of overall U.S.-Canadian trade costs, compared to 3:2 percent in Figure. 2 The reason why the number reported by Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) is somewhat higher is that they use GDP data as opposed to production data to compute trade costs. In fact, when using GDP data I obtain U.S.-Canadian trade costs of 47:4 percent for 993, almost exactly the number reported 970 and 2000 their combined share of U.S. exports uctuated between 43 and 58 percent. x = 0:09 is the solution to 42 = 74 ( + x) Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) calculate the tari equivalent as the trade-weighted average barrier for trade between U.S. states and Canadian provinces relative to the trade-weighted average barrier for trade within the United States and Canada, using a trade cost function that includes a border-related dummy variable and distance. 8

10 Table : U.S. Bilateral Trade Costs Tari equivalent Partner country Percentage change Canada Germany Japan Korea Mexico UK Plain average Trade-weighted average All numbers are in percent and rounded o to integers. Countries listed are the six biggest U.S. export markets as of Computations based on (8). by Anderson and van Wincoop (2004). 3 But GDP data tend to overstate the extent of intranational trade and thus the level of trade costs because they include services. 4 I therefore follow Wei (996) in using merchandise production data to match the trade data more accurately. Furthermore, Eaton and Kortum (2002) report bilateral tari equivalents based on data for 9 OECD countries in 990. For countries that are miles apart, an elasticity of substitution of = 8 implies a trade cost range of percent, consistent with the magnitudes in Table. But an advantage of ij is that it can be easily computed for speci c country pairs. In summary, Figure and Table demonstrate that trade costs are large but generally experienced a substantial decline between 970 and They exhibit considerable heterogeneity across country pairs that would be masked by a one- ts-all measure of trade costs. 5 3 For = 5 and = 0 Anderson and van Wincoop (2004, Table 7) report 993 U.S.-Canadian trade cost tari equivalents of 9 and 35 percent, respectively. The corresponding numbers based on (8) are 97 and 35 percent when using GDP data and 6 and 24 percent when using production data. See Section 4 for a discussion of. 4 Speci cally, intranational trade is given by x ii = y i x i. As GDP data include services and as the service share of GDP has continually grown, the use of GDP data for y i overstates x ii compared to the use of production data despite the fact that imported intermediate goods are included in the trade data (see Helliwell, 2005). Novy (2008) develops a trade cost model with nontradable goods, showing that only the tradable part of output enters the model s micro-founded gravity equation. 5 For a comparison of the period to the period , see Jacks, Meissner and Novy (2008). 9

11 3.2 What Happens When Multilateral Resistance is Misspeci- ed? I now demonstrate why estimated changes in trade costs over time can be biased if they ignore the fact that multilateral trade barriers change over time. Take the trade cost measure from (8) xii x jj ij = x ij x ji 2( ) and substitute expression (4) for x ii and x jj to arrive at ij = y i y j =y W 2 x ij x ji! 2( ) i P i j P j t ii t jj 2 (9) The variables in the second pair of parentheses of (9) are frequently ignored or misspeci ed in standard gravity equations, that is, the multilateral resistance variables and domestic trade costs are not properly taken into account. But an analytical solution for these terms follows directly from equation (5) as i P i t ii 2 xii =y 2( ) i = i (0) y i =y W where i is de ned as the geometric average of country i s outward and inward multilateral trade barriers normalized by domestic trade costs. Note that i can be computed directly from the data without imposing a trade cost function that includes distance or other trade cost proxies. Equation (9) can then be rewritten as ij = y i y j =y W 2 x ij x ji! 2( ) i j () Equation () is now used to examine the consequences of two types of misspeci cation. The rst misspeci cation is to completely ignore the multilateral resistance variables and domestic trade costs. The second misspeci cation is to regard multilateral resistance variables and domestic trade costs as constants, for example in the form of time-invariant country xed e ects. The rst type of misspeci cation is to implicitly assume i = j =. 6 As i is 6 i = P i = t ii = i = holds in a frictionless equilibrium. See Anderson and van Wincoop (2003, p. 76). 0

12 generally greater than unity, the assumption of i = j = leads to an underestimation of bilateral trade costs ij according to equation (). Intuitively, bilateral trade ows are determined by bilateral relative to multilateral barriers. If one underestimates the level of a country s multilateral barriers, one will also underestimate the level of its bilateral barriers. As to the second type of misspeci cation, incorrectly specifying multilateral resistance variables and domestic trade costs as constants is equivalent to assuming i = i and j = j. As one can see from (), in that case changes in multilateral resistance variables and domestic trade costs will not be re ected by bilateral trade costs. This implies that if the multilateral resistance variables relative to domestic trade costs follow a secular trend, then the resulting estimated trend of bilateral trade costs will be biased. Figure 2 illustrates the second mistake. The left-hand side panels plot i for the U.S., Canada and Korea, computed on the basis of (0). 7 The right-hand side panels plot the correct trade costs based on time-varying multilateral resistance variables as well as the incorrect trade costs based on constant multilateral resistance variables. 8 Both the U.S. and the Canadian s happen to be fairly stable over time. 9 This means that for those two countries multilateral resistance and domestic trade costs changed at a roughly equal rate. As a result, there is hardly a di erence between the correct and incorrect trade costs in the right-hand side panels. But Korean multilateral resistance declined markedly over time relative to domestic trade costs such that the misspeci ed U.S.-Korean trade costs would fail to re ect their actual decline. In fact, the misspeci ed measure reports a decline in trade costs from 07 to only 98 percent between 970 and 2000, whereas actual trade costs declined from 07 to 70 percent (see Table ). Ignoring the fact that Korean multilateral resistance dropped over time relative to domestic trade costs thus leads to a miscalculation of the time trend by almost 30 percentage points. Korea serves as a clear example of a country that has experienced a striking drop in general trade costs and thus a striking drop in its multilateral resistance. Although the decrease in multilateral resistance might not 7 Annual world income y W is constructed as the combined production data of Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, the UK and the U.S. 8 In this example the multilateral resistance variables are held constant at their 970 levels but this particular normalization is irrelevant for the argument. 9 i represents multilateral resistance relative to domestic trade costs (i.e. t ii ), whereas Anderson and van Wincoop (2004, Table 8) normalize trade costs within Maryland to zero (i.e. t ii = ) and report multilateral resistance relative to this trade barrier within Maryland. They therefore obtain multilateral resistance variables for U.S. states and Canadian provinces that are higher than those reported for the U.S. and Canada in Figure 2.

13 Multilateral resistance Φ Canada U.S. U.S. Canada Tariff equivalent τ 00% 80% 60% 40% 20% U.S. Canada Φ s correct Φ s time invariant Multilateral resistance Φ Korea U.S. U.S. Korea Tariff equivalent τ 00% 80% 60% 40% 20% U.S. Korea Φ s time invariant Φ s correct Figure 2: Multilateral resistance variables and U.S. bilateral trade costs based on correct time-varying and incorrect time-invariant multilateral resistance variables. be as strong for other countries, in general the bias is likely to go in the direction of underestimating the decline in trade costs. 4 Discussion The trade cost measure in (8) captures what makes international trade more costly over and above domestic trade. It is a comprehensive measure that captures a wide range of trade cost components such as transportation costs and tari s, but also components that are not directly observable such as the costs associated with language barriers and red tape. It should therefore be regarded as an upper bound. Instead, direct measures of speci c trade cost components can be seen as a lower bound of trade costs, for example international transportation costs provided by Hummels (2007) relative to domestic 2

14 transportation costs. The precise level of trade costs depends of course on the elasticity of substitution. Table and Figures and 2 are based on = 8, which is in the middle of the common empirical range of 5 to 0, as surveyed by Anderson and van Wincoop (2004). For = 8 the trade-weighted average of U.S. bilateral trade costs in Table falls from 74 to 42 percent, a decline of 44 percent. It follows from equation (8) that a higher value of would lead to lower trade cost levels. Higher elasticities of substitution mean that goods are not as di erentiated so that consumers are more price-sensitive. In the case of a higher elasticity of substitution, a given observed level of domestic to bilateral trade therefore implies that bilateral and domestic trade costs are not too di erent so that ij is not as high. It turns out that although the elasticity of substitution a ects the level of ij, it hardly a ects the change of ij over time. For example, in the case of = 0 the tradeweighted average falls from 54 to 3 percent, a similar decline of 42 percent. In the case of = 5 the trade-weighted average falls from 67 to 87 percent, a decline of 48 percent. Following the approach of Feenstra (994), Broda and Weinstein (2006) estimate elasticities of substitution based on demand and supply relationships for disaggregated U.S. imports. When comparing the period with , they nd that the median elasticity fell marginally but the di erence is not signi cant for all levels of disaggregation. Nevertheless, this result might suggest that trade costs could have declined slightly less than indicated in Table but quantitatively, this e ect is unlikely to be large. Novy (2008) develops a general equilibrium model of trade that incorporates trade costs as well as the fact that some goods are nontradable. However, he nds that estimated trade costs are barely a ected when the share of nontradable goods is allowed to vary over time. 5 Conclusion This paper develops a measure of international trade costs without imposing any trade cost function that uses distance, borders barriers or other trade cost proxies. Building on the gravity model by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), I show how intranational trade ows can be used to express multilateral resistance terms as a function of observable trade data. Given this expression for time-varying multilateral resistance terms, I am able to derive a micro-founded gravity equation from which international trade costs can be directly computed for speci c country pairs. This trade cost measure is valid for both cross-sectional and time series data. 3

15 As an illustration I compute U.S. bilateral trade costs for a number of major trading partners. I nd that the trade-weighted average of these trade costs declined by about 40 percent between 970 and The decline of U.S. trade costs has been particularly strong with its neighbors Mexico and Canada. I also show that if multilateral resistance variables are misspeci ed as constants, bilateral trade cost estimates will fail to capture the decline in multilateral resistance and thus understate the true fall in trade costs over time. 4

16 References Anderson, J., 979. A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation. American Economic Review 69, pp Anderson, J., Marcouiller, D., Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics 84, pp Anderson, J., van Wincoop, E., Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle. American Economic Review 93, pp Anderson, J., van Wincoop, E., Trade Costs. Journal of Economic Literature 42, pp Bergstrand, J., 985. The Gravity Equation in International Trade. Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 67, pp Broda, C., Weinstein, D., Globalization and the Gains from Variety. Quarterly Journal of Economics 2, pp Eaton, J., Kortum, S., Technology, Geography and Trade. Econometrica 70, pp Feenstra, R., 994. New Product Varieties and the Measurement of International Prices. American Economic Review 84, pp Helliwell, J., Borders, Common Currencies, Trade, and Welfare: What Can We Learn from the Evidence? Bank of Canada Review, Spring, pp Hummels, D., Transportation Costs and International Trade in the Second Era of Globalization. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, pp Jacks, D., Meissner, C., Novy, D., Trade Costs, American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings, forthcoming. Krugman, P., 980. Scale Economies, Product Di erentiation and the Pattern of Trade. American Economic Review 70, pp Novy, D., Is the Iceberg Melting Less Quickly? International Trade Costs after World War II. Mimeo, University of Warwick. 5

17 Portes, R., Rey, H., The Determinants of Cross-Border Equity Flows. Journal of International Economics 65, pp Samuelson, P., 954. The Transfer Problem and Transport Costs: Analysis of E ects of Trade Impediments. Economic Journal 64, pp Wei, S., 996. Intra-National versus International Trade: How Stubborn are Nations in Global Integration? NBER Working Paper #553. 6

Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data

Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data Dennis Novy y University of Warwick July 2011 Abstract Barriers to international trade are known to be large but due to data limitations

More information

Trade Costs, 1870 2000

Trade Costs, 1870 2000 American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2008, 98:2, 529 534 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.98.2.529 Trade Costs, 1870 2000 By David S. Jacks, Christopher M. Meissner, and Dennis

More information

National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop*

National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop* National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop* Revised: December 18, 2000. Comments Welcome Andrew K. Rose Eric van Wincoop Haas

More information

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Wyatt Brooks University of Notre Dame Pau Pujolas McMaster University February, 2015 Abstract In this paper we use production and trade data to measure gains from

More information

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics 414.3 Homework #1 Homework #1 1. In 1900 GDP per capita in Japan (measured in 2000 dollars) was $1,433. In 2000 it was $26,375. (a) Calculate the growth rate of income per capita in Japan over this century. (b) Now suppose

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper 19810 http://www.nber.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper 19810 http://www.nber. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding Working Paper 980 http://www.nber.org/papers/w980 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Nominal, Real and PPP GDP

Nominal, Real and PPP GDP Nominal, Real and PPP GDP It is crucial in economics to distinguish nominal and real values. This is also the case for GDP. While nominal GDP is easier to understand, real GDP is more important and used

More information

Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized products with different specifications

Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized products with different specifications Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized products with different specifications James Laurenceson & Kam Ki Tang*, Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized

More information

1 Present and Future Value

1 Present and Future Value Lecture 8: Asset Markets c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline:. Present and Future Value 2. Bonds 3. Taxes 4. Applications Present and Future Value In the discussion of the two-period model with borrowing and

More information

HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED?

HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED? HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED? by Charles I. Plosser * William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration University of Rochester Shadow Open Market Committee Meeting September 26-27,

More information

WORKING PAPER NO. 12-20 DO FALLING ICEBERG COSTS EXPLAIN RECENT U.S. EXPORT GROWTH? George Alessandria Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

WORKING PAPER NO. 12-20 DO FALLING ICEBERG COSTS EXPLAIN RECENT U.S. EXPORT GROWTH? George Alessandria Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia WORKING PAPER NO. 12-20 DO FALLING ICEBERG COSTS EXPLAIN RECENT U.S. EXPORT GROWTH? George Alessandria Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Horag Choi Monash University July 2012 Supersedes Working Paper

More information

The newest buzzword in the popular business. Has Globalization Created a Borderless World? Janet Ceglowski*

The newest buzzword in the popular business. Has Globalization Created a Borderless World? Janet Ceglowski* Has Globalization Created a Borderless World? * The newest buzzword in the popular business press is globalization, a word that evokes images of a world in which goods, services, capital, and information

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 69 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi 1 Kobe University Received 1 April 2003; accepted

More information

A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar

A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar Janone Ong, Financial Markets Department A new Canadian-dollar effective exchange rate index (CERI) has been created to replace the C 6 index

More information

Journal of International Economics

Journal of International Economics Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 185 201 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of International Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jie Trade booms, trade busts,

More information

Chapter 12. National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Chapter 12. National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Chapter 12 National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Preview National income accounts measures of national income measures of value of production measures

More information

U.S. International Business Travel: Its Impact on U.S. Merchandise Exports. by Maksim Belenkiy and David Riker

U.S. International Business Travel: Its Impact on U.S. Merchandise Exports. by Maksim Belenkiy and David Riker U.S. International Business Travel: Its Impact on U.S. Merchandise Exports by Maksim Belenkiy and David Riker Office of Competition and Economic Analysis November 2012 Manufacturing and Services Economics

More information

Mapping Global Value Chains

Mapping Global Value Chains Mapping Global Value Chains Koen De Backer Sébastien Miroudot OECD Final WIOD Conference: Causes and Consequences of Globalization Groningen, The Netherlands, April 24-26, 2012. Why focusing on GVCs? A

More information

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Paul Krugman JPE,1991 March 4, 2010 Paul Krugman (JPE,1991) Increasing Returns March 4, 2010 1 / 18 Introduction Krugman claims that the study of economic outcomes

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

The Gravity Equation and the Interdependency of Trade Costs and International Trade

The Gravity Equation and the Interdependency of Trade Costs and International Trade The Gravity Equation and the Interdependency of Trade Costs and International Trade Doctoral Dissertation Stephan Rudolph Faculty of Business Management and Economics Technische Universität Dresden Referees:

More information

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Dennis Leech Economics Department and Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy University of Warwick d.leech@warwick.ac.uk Published

More information

EXTERNAL DEBT AND LIABILITIES OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES. Mark Rider. Research Discussion Paper 9405. November 1994. Economic Research Department

EXTERNAL DEBT AND LIABILITIES OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES. Mark Rider. Research Discussion Paper 9405. November 1994. Economic Research Department EXTERNAL DEBT AND LIABILITIES OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES Mark Rider Research Discussion Paper 9405 November 1994 Economic Research Department Reserve Bank of Australia I would like to thank Sally Banguis

More information

WORKING PAPER NO. 05-24 VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION AND THE BORDER EFFECT PUZZLE. Kei-MuYi Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

WORKING PAPER NO. 05-24 VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION AND THE BORDER EFFECT PUZZLE. Kei-MuYi Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia WORKING PAPER NO. 05-24 VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION AND THE BORDER EFFECT PUZZLE Kei-MuYi Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia This version: October 2005 Vertical Specialization and the Border Effect Puzzle

More information

Testing Theories of Policy-Making: Educational Funding MICAH MCFADDEN

Testing Theories of Policy-Making: Educational Funding MICAH MCFADDEN MICAH MCFADDEN This paper was written for Dr.Tures Politics of Developed Systems course. Policy-making is an essential part of every government. Each government must enact policies based on their own philosophies,

More information

CEP Work on Economics of Brexit

CEP Work on Economics of Brexit CEP Work on Economics of Brexit Professor John Van Reenen, Director Swati Dhingra, Gianmarco Ottaviano, Tom Sampson & Jonathan Wadsworth NIESR Conference, May 27 th 2016 How will Brexit effect economy?

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

A Simple Explanation for the Border Effect

A Simple Explanation for the Border Effect A Simple Explanation for the Border Effect Kei-Mu Yi 1 January 2003 This version: November 2003 1 PRELIMINARY. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective

More information

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada Bank of Canada The objective of monetary policy may be gleaned from to preamble to the Bank of Canada Act of 1935 which says, regulate credit and currency in the best interests of the economic life of

More information

Narcissa Balta and Juan Delgado

Narcissa Balta and Juan Delgado Home Bias and Market Integration in the EU Narcissa Balta and Juan Delgado Home bias and market integration in the EU Narcissa Balta and Juan Delgado This version: June 2007 Abstract: The Single Market

More information

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance Chapter 11 International Economics II: International Finance The other major branch of international economics is international monetary economics, also known as international finance. Issues in international

More information

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing. Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of International Consumption Risk Sharing. Ergys Islamaj June 2014 Abstract This paper investigates how output volatility and productivity correlations

More information

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product Macroeconomics Topic 1: Define and calculate GDP. Understand the difference between real and nominal variables (e.g., GDP, wages, interest rates) and know how to construct a price index. Reference: Gregory

More information

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D.

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D. Risk Management PERSPECTIVES April 2003 Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium Expectations for the long-run equity risk premium play an important role in asset allocation decisions

More information

ANALYSIS OF SCOTLAND S PAST AND FUTURE FISCAL POSITION

ANALYSIS OF SCOTLAND S PAST AND FUTURE FISCAL POSITION CPPR Briefing Note ANALYSIS OF SCOTLAND S PAST AND FUTURE FISCAL POSITION Incorporating: GERS 2014 and the 2014 UK Budget Main authors: John McLaren & Jo Armstrong Editorial role: Ken Gibb March 2014 Executive

More information

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D) ECO 352 Spring 2010 No. 14 Mar. 25 OLIGOPOLY TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D) Example using numbers from Precept Week 7 slides, pp. 2, 3. Ingredients: Industry with inverse

More information

Accounting for international trade

Accounting for international trade Accounting for international trade Serge Shikher y Department of Economics Boston University August 24, 2005 Abstract We develop a model to account for the volume and pattern of international trade. The

More information

Market Size, Competition and the Product Mix of Exporters

Market Size, Competition and the Product Mix of Exporters Market Size, Competition and the Product Mix of Exporters Thierry Mayer, Marc J. Melitz and Gianmarco I. P. Ottaviano Discussion by Stephen J. Redding 1 Introduction Very much enjoyed reading this paper

More information

The Economic Importance of the Country of Origin Principle in the Proposed Services Directive. Final report

The Economic Importance of the Country of Origin Principle in the Proposed Services Directive. Final report The Economic Importance of the Country of Origin Principle in the Proposed Services Final report Table of Contents Preface... 3 Executive summary... 4 Chapter 1 The economic importance of the Country of

More information

A new ranking of the world s most innovative countries: Notes on methodology. An Economist Intelligence Unit report Sponsored by Cisco

A new ranking of the world s most innovative countries: Notes on methodology. An Economist Intelligence Unit report Sponsored by Cisco A new ranking of the world s An Economist Intelligence Unit report Sponsored by Cisco Economist Intelligence Unit Limited 2009 A new ranking of the world s Preface In April 2009, the Economist Intelligence

More information

14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory)

14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today s Plan 1 Introduction to New Trade Theory 2 Monopolistically

More information

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina Paula Bustos CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra September 2007 Abstract In this paper I analyze the financing and

More information

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000. Macroeconomics ECON 2204 Prof. Murphy Problem Set 2 Answers Chapter 4 #2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, and 9 (on pages 102-103) 2. a. When the Fed buys bonds, the dollars that it pays to the public for the bonds increase

More information

Recently, the Bureau of Labor Statistics projected

Recently, the Bureau of Labor Statistics projected and Economic Growth GDP and Economic Growth GDP components contributions to U.S. economic growth Rebasing GDP and its components on chained 2001 dollars enhances the role of services as a contributor to

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction What is productivity, how is it measured and why is it important? These questions are a useful starting point from which we can define and explain the range of productivity measures

More information

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach August 26, 2015 - Week 1

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach August 26, 2015 - Week 1 ECO 745: Theory of International Economics Jack Rossbach August 26, 2015 - Week 1 Course Details Time & Location: 1:15-2:35 PM Wed & Fri in BA 214 Office Hours: 3:00-4:00 PM Wed in BA 109B (or by appointment)

More information

Corporate Income Taxation

Corporate Income Taxation Corporate Income Taxation We have stressed that tax incidence must be traced to people, since corporations cannot bear the burden of a tax. Why then tax corporations at all? There are several possible

More information

ECON 35101: International Macroeconomics and Trade University of Chicago, Fall Quarter, 2015 Syllabus

ECON 35101: International Macroeconomics and Trade University of Chicago, Fall Quarter, 2015 Syllabus ECON 35101: International Macroeconomics and Trade University of Chicago, Fall Quarter, 2015 Syllabus Time: Wednesday 9:00-11:50 am Room: HC3B Instructor: Ralph Ossa Office: Booth 379 Email: ralph.ossa

More information

How To Calculate The Price Of A Dollar

How To Calculate The Price Of A Dollar Exchange Rates Costas Arkolakis teaching fellow: Federico Esposito Economics 407, Yale January 2014 Outline De nitions: Nominal and Real Exchange Rate A Theory of Determination of the Real Exchange Rate

More information

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade 19. Transfer Prices A. The Transfer Price Problem A.1 What is a Transfer Price? 19.1 When there is a international transaction between say two divisions of a multinational enterprise that has establishments

More information

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION 7 The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION Since the 1970s one of the major issues in macroeconomics has been the extent to which low output and high unemployment

More information

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU. Inter-American Development Bank

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU. Inter-American Development Bank The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU Alejandro Micco, Ernesto Stein and Guillermo Ordoñez +* Inter-American Development Bank March, 2003 Abstract In this paper we estimate the early

More information

Trade, Finance, Specialization and Synchronization: Sensitivity Analysis

Trade, Finance, Specialization and Synchronization: Sensitivity Analysis Trade, Finance, Specialization and Synchronization: Sensitivity Analysis Jean Imbs London Business School and CEPR September 2003 Abstract This note contains sensitivity analyses for the results described

More information

International Trade without CES: Estimating Translog Gravity

International Trade without CES: Estimating Translog Gravity International Trade without CES: Estimating Translog Gravity Dennis Novy * August 2012 Abstract This paper derives a micro-founded gravity equation based on a translog demand system that allows for flexible

More information

Our development of economic theory has two main parts, consumers and producers. We will start with the consumers.

Our development of economic theory has two main parts, consumers and producers. We will start with the consumers. Lecture 1: Budget Constraints c 2008 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. Two Goods are Often Enough 3. Properties of the Budget Set 4. How the Budget Line Changes 5. The Numeraire 6. Taxes, Subsidies,

More information

International Comparisons of Australia s Investment and Trading Position

International Comparisons of Australia s Investment and Trading Position Journal of Investment Strategy Volume 1 Number 3 perspectives 45 International Comparisons of Australia s Investment and Trading Position By Kevin Daly and Anil Mishra School of Economics and Finance,

More information

Big Concepts. Measuring U.S. GDP. The Expenditure Approach. Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics

Big Concepts. Measuring U.S. GDP. The Expenditure Approach. Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics Lecture 6 Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics Measuring GDP Professor Yamin Ahmad Real GDP and the Price Level Economic Growth and Welfare Big Concepts Ways to Measure GDP Expenditure Approach Income

More information

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE I. Alternatives to Comparative Advantage Economies of Scale The fact that the largest share of world trade consists of the exchange of similar (manufactured) goods between

More information

Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Markups, and Inventories

Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Markups, and Inventories Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Markups, and Inventories Adam Copeland James A. Kahn Staff Report No. 584 December 2012 Revised December 2012 FRBNY Staff REPORTS

More information

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP?

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP? 107 INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP? Maurice K. Shalishali, Columbus State University Johnny C. Ho, Columbus State University ABSTRACT A test of IFE (International

More information

Partial Fractions Decomposition

Partial Fractions Decomposition Partial Fractions Decomposition Dr. Philippe B. Laval Kennesaw State University August 6, 008 Abstract This handout describes partial fractions decomposition and how it can be used when integrating rational

More information

The Simple Analytics of the Melitz Model in a Small Economy

The Simple Analytics of the Melitz Model in a Small Economy The Simple Analytics of the Melit Model in a Small Economy Svetlana Demidova McMaster University Andrés Rodrígue-Clare University of California at Berkeley and NBER March 15, 2013 Abstract In this paper

More information

Hiau Looi Kee y, Alessandro Nicita z, Marcelo Olarreaga x

Hiau Looi Kee y, Alessandro Nicita z, Marcelo Olarreaga x IMPORT DEMAND ELASTICITIES AND TRADE DISTORTIONS Hiau Looi Kee y, Alessandro Nicita z, Marcelo Olarreaga x Abstract This paper provides a systematic estimation of import demand elasticities for a broad

More information

A Note on Extensive Import Margins and Technology Adoption

A Note on Extensive Import Margins and Technology Adoption A Note on Extensive Import Margins and Technology Adoption Final version: May 2009 Forthcoming in the Journal of International and Global EconomicStudies (JIGES). Richard Frensch * Abstract As suggested

More information

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance Morris A. Davis Cambridge University Press stands for Gross Domestic Product. Nominal is the dollar value of all goods and services that

More information

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r),

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Chapter 0 Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r), Section 0-: Overview We have already explored the basics of describing single variable data sets. However, when two quantitative variables

More information

Trade, Di usion and the Gains from Openness

Trade, Di usion and the Gains from Openness Trade, Di usion and the Gains from Openness Andres Rodríguez-Clare Pennsylvania State University and NBER May 2007 Abstract Building on Eaton and Kortum s (2002) model of Ricardian trade, Alvarez and Lucas

More information

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU Inter-American Development Bank Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo (BID) Research Department Departamento de Investigación Working Paper #490 The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU

More information

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L)

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L) A CLOSED ECONOMY IN THE LONG (MEDIUM) RUN For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = C(Y T ) + I(r) + G the left hand side of the equation is the total supply of goods and services

More information

Agenda. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates.

Agenda. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates. Agenda, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1 How Are Determined A Supply-and-Demand Analysis 19-1 19-2 Nominal exchange rates: The nominal exchange rate indicates how much

More information

Chap 11 & 12. Measuring the Cost of Living THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX

Chap 11 & 12. Measuring the Cost of Living THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX Chap 11 & 12 Chap 10: Measuring a Nation s Income: GDP, Nominal GDP, Real GDP, and GDP Deflator Next topic: Chap 11: Measuring the Cost of Living: CPI GDP from an whole economy point of view CPI from a

More information

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data Patrick D Arcy and Emily Poole* This article discusses how bond, equity and foreign exchange markets have responded to the surprise component of Australian

More information

Modelling multilateral trade resistance in a gravity model with exchange rate regimes * Christopher Adam (University of Oxford) 5 AUGUST 2007 ABSTRACT

Modelling multilateral trade resistance in a gravity model with exchange rate regimes * Christopher Adam (University of Oxford) 5 AUGUST 2007 ABSTRACT CENTRE FOR DYNAMIC MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS CONFERENCE PAPERS 2007 CDMC07/02 Modelling multilateral trade resistance in a gravity model with exchange rate regimes * Christopher Adam (University of Oxford)

More information

Did the Container Increase International Trade? Initial Explorations

Did the Container Increase International Trade? Initial Explorations Did the Container Increase International Trade? Initial Explorations D. Bernhofen, Z. El-Sahli, R. Kneller University of Nottingham, GEP, CESIfo Motivation Born of the need to reduce labor, time and handling,

More information

UK EXPORTS TO CHINA NOW AND IN THE FUTURE

UK EXPORTS TO CHINA NOW AND IN THE FUTURE UK EXPORTS TO CHINA NOW AND IN THE FUTURE FCO ECONOMICS UNIT January 213 1 STRUCTURE SECTION 1: GETTING PERSPECTIVE WHERE ARE WE NOW? Assessing the size of China s import market and the UK s position within

More information

Note on growth and growth accounting

Note on growth and growth accounting CHAPTER 0 Note on growth and growth accounting 1. Growth and the growth rate In this section aspects of the mathematical concept of the rate of growth used in growth models and in the empirical analysis

More information

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012 SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS David Romer University of California, Berkeley First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012 Copyright 2012 by David Romer CONTENTS Preface vi I The IS-MP Model 1 I-1 Monetary

More information

Relative prices and Balassa Samuleson e ect

Relative prices and Balassa Samuleson e ect Relative prices and Balassa Samuleson e ect Prof. Ester Faia, Ph.D. Johann Wolfgang Goethe Universität Frankfurt a.m. March 2009 rof. Ester Faia, Ph.D. (Johann Wolfgang Goethe Relative Universität prices

More information

Section 1.3 P 1 = 1 2. = 1 4 2 8. P n = 1 P 3 = Continuing in this fashion, it should seem reasonable that, for any n = 1, 2, 3,..., = 1 2 4.

Section 1.3 P 1 = 1 2. = 1 4 2 8. P n = 1 P 3 = Continuing in this fashion, it should seem reasonable that, for any n = 1, 2, 3,..., = 1 2 4. Difference Equations to Differential Equations Section. The Sum of a Sequence This section considers the problem of adding together the terms of a sequence. Of course, this is a problem only if more than

More information

NOTE: IMES Discussion Paper Series is circulated in order to stimulate discussion and comments. Views expressed in Discussion Paper Series are those

NOTE: IMES Discussion Paper Series is circulated in order to stimulate discussion and comments. Views expressed in Discussion Paper Series are those IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Implications for the Yen of Japanese Current Account Adjustment Maurice Obstfeld Discussion Paper No. 2006-E-15 INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF JAPAN C.P.O

More information

Imagine you are planning a trip to France

Imagine you are planning a trip to France International price comparisons based on purchasing power parity Because exchange rate movements, in general, tend to be more volatile than changes in national price levels, the purchasing power parity

More information

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems Interlinkages between Payment and Securities Settlement Systems David C. Mills, Jr. y Federal Reserve Board Samia Y. Husain Washington University in Saint Louis September 4, 2009 Abstract Payments systems

More information

INFLATION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE

INFLATION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE INFLATION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE James P. Houck Professor, Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Minnesota International trade and trade policy are difficult enough to understand

More information

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program International Comparison Program [03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing Global Office 3 rd Technical Advisory Group Meeting June 10-11, 2010 Paris, France

More information

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition Ethan Kaplan September 19, 2011 Outline 1. Convexity and Declining MRS 2. Duality and Hicksian Demand 3. Slutsky Decomposition 4. Net and Gross Substitutes

More information

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models A Comparison of Option Pricing Models Ekrem Kilic 11.01.2005 Abstract Modeling a nonlinear pay o generating instrument is a challenging work. The models that are commonly used for pricing derivative might

More information

Trade in High-Tech Services

Trade in High-Tech Services Trade in High-Tech Services J. Bradford Jensen y McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University Peterson Institute for International Economics October 2007 Abstract This paper examines the size, scope,

More information

Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade

Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade Costas Arkolakis Yale University, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and NBER I am grateful to my advisors Timothy Kehoe and

More information

Measuring the Cross-Country Distribution of Gains from Trade

Measuring the Cross-Country Distribution of Gains from Trade Measuring the Cross-Country Distribution of Gains from Trade B. Ravikumar Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and Arizona State University Michael E. Waugh New York University and NBER September 9, 2015

More information

UK export performance by industry

UK export performance by industry 308 Quarterly Bulletin 2006 Q3 UK export performance by industry By Ana Buisán of Banco de España and David Learmonth and María Sebastiá-Barriel of the Bank of England s Monetary Analysis Division. The

More information

Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary

Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary Karl H. Schlag European University Institute 1 December 14, 2006 1 Economics Department, European University Institute. Via della Piazzuola

More information

Do Currency Unions Affect Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from US FDI Flows into the European Union

Do Currency Unions Affect Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from US FDI Flows into the European Union Economic Issues, Vol. 10, Part 2, 2005 Do Currency Unions Affect Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from US FDI Flows into the European Union Kyriacos Aristotelous 1 ABSTRACT This paper investigates the

More information

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy A Two-Period Model of the Current Account Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 1 1 Small Open Endowment Economy 1.1 Consumption Optimization problem maximize U i 1 = u c i 1 + u c i 2 < 1 subject to the budget constraint

More information

Specialization Patterns in International Trade

Specialization Patterns in International Trade Specialization Patterns in International Trade Walter Steingress March 2, 213 Abstract I document new facts on the pattern of specialization by looking at export and import concentration. As a result of

More information

Purchasing-Power Parity: Definition, Measurement, and Interpretation

Purchasing-Power Parity: Definition, Measurement, and Interpretation Purchasing-Power Parity: Definition, Measurement, and Interpretation Robert Lafrance and Lawrence Schembri, International Department The concept of purchasing-power parity (PPP) has two applications: it

More information

The Elasticity of Export Demand for U.S. Cotton

The Elasticity of Export Demand for U.S. Cotton The Elasticity of Export Demand for U.S. Cotton Laxmi Paudel Graduate Student Dept of Agricultural and Applied Economics The University of Georgia, Conner, 205 Athens, GA 30602 email:lpaudel@agecon.uga.edu

More information

How could a shock to growth in China affect growth in the United Kingdom?

How could a shock to growth in China affect growth in the United Kingdom? 4 Quarterly Bulletin 2016 Q1 How could a shock to growth in China affect growth in the United Kingdom? By Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi and Kate Stratford of the Bank s Global Spillovers and Interconnections Division.

More information

How Important Is the New Goods Margin in International Trade?*

How Important Is the New Goods Margin in International Trade?* Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 324 Revised April 2013 (First Version: October 2003) How Important Is the New Goods Margin in International Trade?* Timothy J. Kehoe

More information

The Wage Return to Education: What Hides Behind the Least Squares Bias?

The Wage Return to Education: What Hides Behind the Least Squares Bias? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 8855 The Wage Return to Education: What Hides Behind the Least Squares Bias? Corrado Andini February 2015 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information