The Share Price Puzzle

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Share Price Puzzle"

Transcription

1 The Share Price Puzzle Edward A. Dyl University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ 85721, USA William B. Elliott Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK 74078, USA June, 2000 Abstract We document substantial variation in the prices of common stocks in U.S. markets, a phenomenon that apparently results from firms selecting particular price ranges for their stock. We present cross-sectional evidence that variables consistent with Merton s (1987) model of capital market equilibrium explain roughly 45 percent of the variation in share prices. We also find that measures of trading range and share price appreciation are significant predictors of stock splits, that very widely held firms are less inclined to split their stock than less widely held fi rms, and that the investor base of firms splitting their stock increases compared to other firms.

2 2 The Share Price Puzzle A glance at the stock prices published each weekday in The Wall Street Journal and other newspapers reveals a wide range of common stock prices in United States markets. For example, on a given day at the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), Anheuser-Busch sells for about $75 per share, whereas Boston Beer sells for only $8.75 per share. Similarly, on Nasdaq, Intel sells for $72 per share, but a share of Applied Microsystems costs only $ Why is there so much variation in share prices among firms trading in the same and/or similar markets? Most items in tend to be packaged in ways designed to reduce price dispersion across companies and brands. Bonds typically have a par value of $1,000, most pasta comes in 16-ounce packages, wine bottles generally hold 750 milliliters, and so forth. If the total value of a firm is primarily determined by the firm s future earning power, then the price per share of the firm s stock simply depends on the number of shares outstanding, which the firm controls. Why isn t there more commonality among stock prices? We refer to this heretofore unexplained variation in common stock prices as the Share Price Puzzle. Table I documents the dispersion in prices of common stocks trading in United States markets during Panel A contains aggregate results for the three major U.S. stock markets. The mean and median stock prices of these 6,756 firms are $19.31 and $14.62 per share, respectively, but 33 percent of the firms have average prices lower than $10.00 per share and 19 percent have average prices higher than $30 per share, so more

3 3 than 50 percent of all traded firms have share prices that dif fer considerably from the average. Higher stock prices and the firm s market value are directly associated. This relation is not merely due to higher price, ceteris paribus, causing market higher value. The mean share price of firms in the Greater-than-$70 group is 18 times the mean price of firms in the Less-than -$10 group, whereas the mean market value of firms in the former group is 243 times the mean market value of the firms in the latter group. Panels B, C, and D show the same information sep arately for the three major U.S. stock exchanges. The mean share price of firms trading on the NYSE is roughly twice as high as that of firms trading on the Amex and Nasdaq, and the NYSE firms are much larger. Not surprisingly, both the Amex and Nasdaq have a larger proportion of their firms in the Less-than -$10 category. One apparent anomaly is that, although the Amex and Nasdaq firms in the Greater-than- $70 category have smaller market capitalizations than the corresponding NYSE firms, they have higher stock prices. Evidently stock prices vary all over the place. It is possible that this phenomenon is simply inexplicable, in the sense that stock prices just happen. That is, firms shares begin trading following an Initial Public Offering (IP O), generally priced at an average of about $10.00 per share, 2 and some firms are subsequently more successful than others. Thus, some firms share prices go up over time, and other firms prices go down. These differences in performance over a long period of time may explain the cross- sectional variation in stock prices that we observe in today s markets. The problem with this conjecture is that firms take actions to select a preferred trading range for their shares (i.e., by manipulating the number of shares outstanding). 1 T h e s e p r i c e s r e f e r t o c l o s i n g p r i c e s o n A u g u s t 1 0,

4 4 Consider the evidence in Figure 1, which shows the average annual common stock price of the 1,452 firms having continuous annual data available from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) for the period from 1976 through The average annual price for each firm is an average of the monthly closing prices for the year, and the solid line depicts the average price over time for the 1,452 firms. The average annual share price for these stocks over the 21 -year period is $24.78, ranging from lows of $18.87 and $19.28 in 1977 and 1976 to highs of $29.74 and $29.84 in 1986 and 1996, respectively. It is remarkable that the average price of these firms shares changes so little during a period when the S&P 500 Composite index appreciated by 692 percent and the NYSE Composite Index appreciated by 785 percent, and it is also prima facie evidence that these firms manage their share prices. 4 The broken line in the figure shows what the average share price would have been in the absence of stock splits. The average price in 1996 would have been $196.01, not $ Clearly stock prices don t just happen! This paper is organized as follows. In the next section we consider the relation between trading range considerations, transaction costs, and share prices, and advance some hypotheses about why it may make sense for some firms to have high share prices and vice versa. Section II presents cross-sectional evidence about share ownership and share price levels from 1976 to 1996 that is consistent with these hypotheses. In Section III, we show that the decisions of the firms in our sample to split their stock, or not to 2 A r e c e n t s t u d y o f 2, I P O s f r o m f i n d s a n a v e r a g e i n t i a l o f f e r i n g p r i c e o f $ p e r s h a r e. S e e A f f l e c k-graves e t. a l. ( ). 3 T h e r a t i o n a l e f o r e x a m i n i n g t h i s s a m p l e o f f i r m s i s d i s c u s s e d b e l o w. 4 O u r s a m p l e c o n t a i n s o n l y s u r v i v o r s, s o t h e s e f i r m s a p p r e c i a t i o n w a s e v e n g r e a t e r t h a n t h e i n d i c e s ( 1, p e r c e n t ).

5 5 split their stock, are also consistent with these hypotheses. Conclusions are summarized in Section IV. I. Stock Splits, Trading Ranges, and Transaction Costs The notion that there is an optimal (or, at least preferable) trading range for a firm s common stock is widely accepted among finance practitioners. In a survey of 100 chief financial officers of NYSE - listed firms, Baker and Gallagher (1980) find almost universal agreement with the statement that Stock splits keep a firm s stock price in an optimal price range. In a similar vein, the New York Stock Exchange Listed Company Manual contains the following statements: Exchange statistics indicate a preferential price range within which a significant percentage of Exchange round lot volume is generated.... Today, liquidity is probably the most important element in the investment decision, other than the financial condition or suitability of the security under consideration.... Consideration of a stock split is therefore justified when a company s shares are selling at a relatively high price, and when such action is accompanied by healthy operating results and a strong financial condition. (page 7-11) Apparently firms heed the NYSE s advice. Numerous empirical studies report that firms tend to announce a stock split when their share price is higher than usual, and that stock splits convey positive information about the firms future prospects. 5 5 L a k o n i s h o k a n d L e v ( ), L a m o u r e u x a n d P o o n ( ), M c N i c h o l s a n d D r a v i d ( ) a n d I k e n b e r r y e t. a l. ( ). W h e t h e r o r n o t t h e c o n v e y a n c e o f i n f o r m a t i o n i s i n t e n t i o n a l ( i. e., s o -c a l l e d s i g n a l l i n g ) o r s i m p l y i n a d v e r t e n t b e c a u s e m a n a g e r s b e h a v e a c c o r d i n g t o t h e g u i d e l i n e s i n t h e N Y S E L i s t e d C o m p a n y M a n u a l i s, f o r t u n a t e l y, o u t s i d e t h e s c o p e o f t h i s p a p e r.

6 6 Despite the NYSE s assertion regarding the importance of liquidity, however, stock splits and lower trading ranges do not necessarily result in increased liquidity for a firm s shares, at least in any traditional meaning of the word. Traditionally, liquidity is associated with low transaction costs and high trading volume. Several studies document that stock splits actually increase percentage bid-ask spreads. 6 In fact, lower share prices are generally associated with higher transaction costs, such as percentage bid-ask spreads and commissions, and not vice versa. 7 In a market that specifies a minimum price variation between quotes (i.e., a tick size), an inverse relation between share prices and b i d -ask spreads is almost inevitable. 8 For example, if the minimum price variation in a market is one-eighth of a dollar ($.125), as it was in U.S. stock markets for most of this century, then the smallest percentage bid-ask spread that can occur for a stock priced at $5.00 is 2.5 percent, whereas the smallest percentage spread possible for a stock priced at $12.50 is 1.0 percent and 0.25 percent for a $50 stock. Also, the dollar volume of trading in a stock frequently declines following stock splits. 9 This inverse relation between transaction costs and trading volume is not unexpected; an extensive amount of literature addresses this issue. 1 0 Amihud and Mendelson (1986) document that such illiquidity is costly, in the sense that, ceteris paribus, it reduces the value of the firm. Why, then, do firms voluntarily use stock splits to move their share price to a less liquid trading range? 6 C o p e l a n d ( ), C o n r o y e t. a l. ( ), a n d S c h u l t z ( ). 7 B e n s t o n a n d H a g e r m a n ( ), S t o l l a n d W h a l e y ( ), B r e n n a n a n d C o p e l a n d ( ), B r e n n a n a n d H u g h e s ( ), a n d H a r r i s ( ). 8 H a r r i s ( ), A n s h u m a n a n d K a l a y ( ), a n d A n g e l ( ). A n g e l ( ) d o c u m e n t s a n i n t r i g u i n g r e l a t i o n b e t w e e n a v e r a g e s h a r e p r i c e s a n d t i c k s i z e s a c r o s s m a r k e t s w o r l d w i d e, b u t d o e s n o t a d d r e s s t h e i s s u e o f p r i c e v a r i a t i o n w i t h i n t h e s e m a r k e t s. 9 C o p e l a n d ( ), L a k o n i s h o k a n d L e v ( ), L a m o u r e u x a n d P o o n ( ), a n d C o n r o y e t. a l. ( ). 1 0 D e m s e t z ( ), T i n i c ( ), B e n s t o n a n d H a g e r m a n ( ) S t o l l ( ), A m i h u d a n d M e n d e l s o n ( ), C o n s t a n t a n i d e s ( ), a n d A t k i n s a n d D y l ( ).

7 7 Part of the answer to this question lies with Merton s (1987) model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. Merton assumes that investors generally are aware of only a subset of all available securities, that these subsets differ among investors, and that investors can only invest in securities that they know about. He shows that an increase in the relative size of a firm s investor base (i.e., the group of investors and potential investors who are aware of the firm) increases the market value of the firm. Firms may select a trading range for their shares that enlarges the firm s investor base, perhaps resulting in an increase in value that more than offsets the costs of the higher bid-ask spreads following stock splits noted by the studies cited in footnote 6. Muscarella and Vetsuypens (1996) provide evidence that splits of American Depository Receipts (ADRs) are to move the price of the ADRs to a particular trading range, and Conroy and Harris (1999) show that managers apparently design stock splits to return their firms stock prices to a desired trading range (i.e., the price level after the firms s last stock split). It is also well documented that the number of shareholders in a firm generally increases following a stock split, which is akin to an increase in the firm s investor base. 1 1 The specific mechanism through which a particular trading range for a firm s shares increases its investor base is not clear. The simplest explanation derives from a combination of investors revealed preferences for trading in round lots, the benefits of holding a diversified portfolio (Markowitz (1952)), and the limited wealth of most investors. In particular, a diversified portfolio of common stocks may require as many as 1 1 L a m o u r e u x a n d P o o n ( ), M a l o n e y a n d M u l h e r i n ( ), a n d M u k h e r j i e t. a l. ( ) r e p o r t t h i s f i n d i n g f o r c o m m o n s t o c k s p l i t s. F e r n a n d o e t. a l. ( ) r e p o r t a s i m i l a r r e s u l t f o r m u t u a l f u n d s p l i t s.

8 8 30 different stocks. 1 2 The NYSE s Shareownership 1998 publication indicates that the median and mean values of the common stock portfolios of all adult shar eholders are $15,500 and $95,000, respectively. 1 3 Thus, the median (mean) investor can only invest in about two (12) round lots of stocks in the Annheuser Busch/Intel trading range of $70- $75 per share, whereas he/she could invest in ten (more than 60) rounds lots of stocks priced at around $15 per share. It is likely that stock splits increase the number of shareholders simply because the lower price facilitates and, therefore, attracts investment by individual investors. Schultz (2000), for example, documents a large number of small buy orders following stock splits. Other explanations linking stock splits and the firm s investors have also been suggested. Brennan and Hughes (1991) observe that brokerage commissions are inversely related to share price and suggest that, in a world with incomplete information, brokers produce and disseminate more information (e.g., research reports and recommendations) about lower-priced firms, so firms are able to use stock splits to increase their investor base. Angel (1997) suggests that a single tick size in a market means that stock splits increase the minimum percentage bid-ask spread for a stock, consequently encouraging more market makers to both make a market in the firm s stock and to promote that stock to investors. Amihud et.al. (1999), however, find support for the simplest explanation. They investigate reductions in the minimum trading unit (MTU) in Japan, which is the minimum number of a firm s shares required for a transaction on an exchange in Japan, an d report an increase in the number of shareholders following a reduction in a firm s 1 2 S t a t m a n ( ). E a r l i e r w o r k b y E v a n s a n d A r c h e r ( ) s u g g e s t s a s m a l l e r n u m b e r.

9 9 MTU. They also observe a concomitant increase in stock price that is related to the increase in the number of shareholders. In Japan, brokerage commissions are a function of the value of the transaction, not the share price, and the reduction in the MTU does not change the stock price, so the Brennan and Hughes (1991) and Angel (1997) conjectures do not apply. The driving force behind the increase in shareholders and market value found in Japan following a reduction in a firm s MTU is apparently new investment by the small investors whose limited wealth did not permit them to purchase these stocks previously. The explanation of the dispersion in share prices in U.S. markets that emerges from Merton s model and from these other studies is that firms whose owners are primarily individual investors are most concerned with the trading range issue, and so these firms opt for lower share prices to expand their investor bases. Merton s model also implies the converse. Large, well-known, widely- held firms already have a very large investor base, with a high percentage of institutional and/or wealthy investors, and changes in the investor base of these firms have essentially no effect on the firm s market value. 1 4 For these firms, the qualitative predictions of Merton s model and Black s (1972) zero -beta Capital Asset Pricing Model coincide. These firms may therefore care little about share price levels in the trading range sense, but rather place a higher value on liquidity and low transaction costs, explaining why large firms tend to have higher share prices. 1 3 T h e s e d a t a a r e b a s e d o n t h e S u r v e y o f C o n s u m e r F i n a n c e s, a n o n g o i n g s u r v e y c o n d u c t e d b y t h e S u r v e y R e s e a r c h C e n t e r a t t h e U n i v e r s i t y o f M i c h i g a n f o r t h e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B o a r d. 1 4 B a d r i n a t h e t. a l. ( ) d o c u m e n t t h e p e n c h a n t o f i n s t i t u t i o n a l i n v e s t o r s f o r t h i s t y p e o f s t o c k.

10 10 II. Ownership Characteristics and Share Prices Merton s (1987) model leads to two testable hypotheses about the dispersion of share prices in U.S. markets: (1) lower share prices are characteristic of firms owned by s o -called small investors and the converse; and (2) higher share prices are characteristic of large firms and the converse. In this section we present cross-sectional evidence regarding these hypotheses. A. Methodology and Data We test the hypotheses posed above by estimating the regression parameters associated with the following variables: SharePrice j,t = δ 0 + δ 1 TotalAssets j,t + δ 2 AvgHldg j,t + δ 3 InstPct j,t + ε j,t (1) where the dependent variable, SharePrice j,t, is the average price per share of firm j s common stock during year t, measured as the average of its monthly closing prices, the δ s are the parameters to be estimated, and ε j,t is an error term. The first independent variable, TotalAssets j,t, is the logarithm of the book value of firm j s assets at the end of year t. We use the book value of the firm s assets, rather than the firm s market capitalization, as the measure o f firm size in Equation (1) to avoid any spurious correlation that might arise with the latter measure (since the dependent variable is share price and market capitalization is share price times the number of shares outstanding). The book value of the firm s assets is obtained from Compustat.

11 11 The next independent variable, AvgHldg j,t, is the average dollar investment per shareholder in firm j during year t. The average dollar holding per shareholder is a measure of whether the firm s ownership clientele consists of small or large investors, at least on average. The number of shareholders per firm is also from Compustat. The final variable, InstPct j,t, is the percentage of firm j owned by institutional investors during year t. Institutional ownership is an alternative measure of the nature of the firm s ownership structure. Institutional investors are large investors, who are generally especially interested in liquidity and low transaction costs, and they are increasingly important participants in U.S. stock markets over the period of our study. Data regarding institutional ownership are from Compact Disclosure. Our initial data include all firms listed in the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) database that have both continuous data available over the 21-year period from 1976 to 1996 and a share price of at least $1.25 at the end of January, We examine only firms with continuous data over the whole period to eliminate firms whose share price is largely a consequence of either circumstance (e.g., newly public firms) or vicissitude (e.g., firms experiencing financial distress). The initial sample consists of 1,426 firms. In 1976, 74.8 percent of the firms were listed on the NYSE and 26.2 percent were listed on the Amex. 1 6 In 1996, 84.6 percent of the firms are listed on the NYSE, 13.7 percent on the Amex, and 1.7 percent on Nasdaq. Even survivors do not all prosper. Table II shows summary statistics regarding our sample at five- year intervals from 1976 to Panel A contains data on share prices. The mean and median share 1 5 T h e m i n i m u m p r i c e o f $ w a s c h o s e n a r b i t r a r i l y t o e l i m i n a t e s o -c a l l e d p e n n y s t o c k s. I t i s s i m p l y t e n t i m e s t h e t i c k s i z e t h a t w a s i n e f f e c t d u r i n g t h i s p e r i o d.

12 12 prices are slightly higher in the later years than in the earlier years, although, as we have already noted in our discussion of Figure 1, the increase in share prices pales in comparison to the increase in the value of these firms during the period. The slight differences between the mean figures reported in Table II and the values for the same years in Figure 1 are because the data in Table II exclude common stocks with a price of less than $1.25 per share in 1976 whereas these firms are included in Figure 1. Panel B shows the mean and median market values of the firms (i.e., the year-end market capitalization reported by CRSP). The mean and median market values increase by 793 percent and 1,046 percent, respectively, from 1976 to Panels C and D report the number of shareholders per firm and the average investment per shareholder, respectively. Although the value of these firms increases greatly over the period, the average number of shareholders remains remarkably constant at roughly 21,000 shareholders per firm. The median number of shareholders per firm increases from just under 4,000 in 1976 to about 4,800 in 1996, a 20 percent increase. The mean number of shareholders is almost five times the median, indicating that the distribution of shareholders across the firms in our sample is very skewed. Overall, the combination of no meaningful increase in the average number of shareholders per firm and a substantial increase in the average market value of the firms results in a very large increase in the average investment per shareholder from 1976 to The mean investment increases from $24,600 per shareholder in 1976 to $235,840 in 1996, and the median shareholding also increases roughly tenfold during the period, from $12,090 in 1976 to $116,020 in Again, skewness is evident in the distribution of this variable 1 6 D a t a f o r N a s d a q f i r m s a r e n o t a v a i l a b l e o n C R S P u n t i l a f t e r

13 13 across firms. The substantial increase in the average dollar holdings per shareholder may be largely driven by increasing institutional ownership from 1976 to Finally, Panel E shows mean and median percentage institutional ownership beginning in 1986, as reported by Compact Disclosure. 1 7 These data are from Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) reports (Form 13 -F) required of all institutions with equity holdings of $100 million or more, including banks, insurance companies, investment companies, pension funds, and foundations. The mean and median holding of these institutions averages about 42 percent of the firms shares in each year. Note, however, that whereas large institutions report holdings in only 305 of the firms in 1986, they report holdings in 1,228 of the firms in 1996 a 400 percent increase. B. Regression Results The results of our regression analysis are summarized in Table III. Panel A shows the coefficients of the share price regression when the independent variables are firm size and average dollar holding per shareholder. The numbers in parentheses are White (1980) heteroskedasticity-consistent t-statistics, and the double and single asterisks denote statistical significance at the.01 and.05 levels, respectively. The coefficient on firm size (δ 1 ) is positive and significant in each annual cross-sectional regression, a finding consistent with the hypothesis that larger, well-known firms have high share prices and vice versa. The coefficient on average investment per shareholder (δ 2 ) is also positive and significant at the.01 level in each regression, consistent with the hypothesis 1 7 T h e s e d a t a a r e n o t a v a i l a b l e f r o m t h i s s o u r c e f o r a n d

14 14 that lower share prices are preferred by firms owned by small investors and vice versa. 1 8 The average R 2 of the five regressions is Panel B shows estimates of the regression coefficients when the independent variables in the regression are firm size and institutional ownership. The coefficient on firm size (d 1 ) remains positive and significant in each year. The coefficient on institutional ownership (d 3 ) is also positive in each year, consistent with firms owned by large institutional investors having higher share prices and vice versa, but it is not significant in the 1986 regression. The R 2 s of the three regressions average 0.30, much lower than the 0.45 average for the five regressions in Panel A. Panel C shows the results when all three independent variables are included in the regression. The findings regarding firm size and average investment per shareholder remain unchanged. The significance of the coefficient on institutional ownership drops in each regression, however, and the adjusted R 2 s are actually slightly lower that those of the comparable regressions in Panel A. Apparently the size of the average dollar shareholding, indicating the general wealthiness of the firm s ownership clientele per se, is paramount, and the distinction between large individual inv estors and institutional investors is irrelevant. C. Summary The cross-sectional regression estimates in Table III provide strong support both for the hypothesis that lower share prices characterize firms owned largely by small 1 8 T h e m a g n i t u d e o f t h e c o e f f i c i e n t o n AvgHldg j,t d e c l i n e s s t e a d i l y o v e r t h e p e r i o d, a n d t h e v a l u e i n i s only one-t e n t h t h e v a l u e i n T h i s d e c r e a s e i s s i m p l y a m a t t e r o f s c a l e, a n d h a s n o e c o n o m i c i n t e r p r e t a t i o n. R e c a l l f r o m T a b l e I I t h a t t h e a v e r a g e i n v e s t m e n t p e r s h a r e h o l d e r i n c r e a s e s r o u g h l y t e n f o l d f r o m t o

15 15 investors and vice versa, and for the hypothesis that higher share prices are associated with large, well- known firms and vice versa. When interpreted in the light of Merton (1987), these findings are consistent with the widespread belief among finance practitioners that the choice of an appropriate trading range for a firm s shares affects the value of the firm. III. Share Prices and Stock Splits If firms manage the price of their shares in an attempt to keep the price within an appropriate trading range, where appropriate is defined in terms of the size of the firm and the characteristics of its owners as per Panel A in Table III, then firms whose share prices rise above this range are presumably more likely to split their stock than are firms whose share prices remain at or below the appropriate trading range. We investigate this issue by testing whether firms whose share prices are in some sense too high are more likely to split their stock than are firms whose share prices are not too high. Merton s model also indicates that additional shareholders provide only negligible increases in firm value for firms with very large shareholder bases, which may reduce the likelihood that a firm will split their stock. We incorporate this possibility into the tests described in the next section. A. Methodology We examine the propensity of firms to split their stock by estimating the parameters of the following logit model:

16 16 StockSplit j,t = F (ß 0 + ß 1 TradeRange j,t + ß 2 StockApprec j,t + ß 3 Shareholders j,t ) (2) where StockSplit j,t is the probability that firm j will split its stock during time period T a binary variable with a value of 1 if firm j splits its stock during time interval T and 0 otherwise, F is the logistic cumulative density function, TradeRange j,t measures the location of firm j s share price in year t relative to the stock s predicted trading range an indication of whether or not the price of the stock is too high, StockApprec j,t measures the proportionate increase in the firm s stock price over the five years preceding year t, Shareholders j,t is a binary variable based on the relative size of the firm s investor base in year t, and the ß s are the parameters of the logit model. 1 9 The dependent variable, StockSplit j,t, equals 1 if firm j has a stock split of 1.25-t o- 1 or greater during time interval T, and 0 otherwise. 2 0 These data are identified for two - year and four-year intervals following the years 1976, 1981, 1986, and 1991 by examining the stock split factors reported in CRSP. The proportion of firms in our sample having common stock splits during each four-year interval is shown in Table IV. Panel A shows the incidence of 2 -for -l or greater splits, and Panel B shows for-1 or greater splits. Clearly stock splits are not exactly a rare event for the firms in our sample in any of the four sub-periods. Roughly 23 percent of the firms had at least a 2 -for-1 s p l i t during each of the four-year periods, and roughly 34 percent had at least a 1.25-for-l split. The first independent variable, TradeRange j,t, is defined as follows: 1 9 U s i n g a n o r m a l c u m u l a t i v e d e n s i t y f u n c t i o n ( i. e., p r o b i t ) y i e l d s q u a l i t a t i v e l y s i m i l a r r es u l t s. 2 0 T h e r e s u l t s a r e n o t s e n s i t i v e t o t h e m i n i m u m l e v e l u s e d t o d e f i n e w h e t h e r o r n o t a f i r m h a s s p l i t i t s s t o c k. W e c h o s e t o -1 a s a m i n i m u m s i m p l y t o e x c l u d e f i r m s t h a t u s e s m a l l s t o c k d i s t r i b u t i o n s i n l i e u o f c a s h d i v i d e n d s.

17 17 TradeRange j,t = SharePrice j,t / E (SharePrice j,t TotalAssets j,t, AvgHldg j,t ), (3) where E(SharePrice j,t ) is estimated for each of the four years (1976, 1981, 1986, and 1991) using the regression relation shown in Panel A of Table III. 2 1 That is, E( SharePrice j,t ) = d 0 + d 1 TotalAssets j,t + d 2 AvgHldg j,t, (4) s o TradeRange j,t is the ratio of a firm s actual share price in year t to its predicted share price given the firm s size and average holdings per shareholder. A value greater than 1 for TradeRange j,t suggests that firm j s share price is too high for the firm s size and average investment per shareholder, and a value less than or equal to 1 indicates that the firm s share price is below or close to its appropriate trading range, respectively. The second independent variable, StockApprec j,t, is the proportional increase in the jth firm s split-adjusted average stock price over the four years ending with the estimation year, computed as follows: StockApprec j,t = SharePrice j,t / SharePrice j,t-4. (5) We include share price appreciation as an explanatory variable in our logit model of stock splits because numerous studies report an increase in stock prices (in excess of market 2 1 W e r e q u i r e t h a t E (S h a r e P r i c e j,t ) b e g r e a t e r t h a n f i v e d o l l a r s f o r t h e f i r m t o b e i n c l u d e d i n t h e l o g i t a n a l y s i s. I n c l u s i o n o f a l l o b s e r v a t i o n s d o e s n o t q u a l i t a t i v e l y a l t e r t h e r e s u l t s o f t h e l o g i t a n a l y s i s.

18 18 returns) preceding splits that begins up to five years before the announcement of the stock split. 2 2 The last independent variable, Shareholders j,t, is a binary variable created by ranking all firms in descending order based on the number of shareholders. Shareholders j,t has a value of 1 when the number of shareholders is in the top five percent, otherwise it is 0. We include this variable because Merton s model implies that the size of the firm s investor base is not a concern for firms that already have a great many shareholders. B. Logit Results The results of the logit analysis are shown in Table V, when the time interval T in StockSplit j,t is the four-year period following year t. 2 3 Panel A shows the findings when TradeRange j,t and ShareApprec j,t are the only variables in the model. The coefficients on TradeRange j,t (i.e., the ß 1 s) are positive and significant, indicating that a firm whose share price in year t is above its predicted trading range is more likely to split its stock in the next four years than is a firm whose price is near or below its predicted trading range. When the actual share price is twice the predicted price, a firm is between 1.8 and 4 times (depending on the cross section) more likely to split its stock than is a firm whose actual and predicted prices are equal. For example, in the logit, a firm is 2.6 times more likely to split its stock when its actual share price is double the predicted price, F a m a e t. a l. ( ), L a k o n i s h o k a n d L e v ( ), L a m o u r e u x a n d P o o n ( ), a n d M c N i c h o l s a n d D r a v i d ( ). 2 3 U s e o f a t w o -y e a r p e r i o d y i e l d s s i m i l a r r e s u l t s. 2 4 T h i s i n t e r p r e t a t i o n o f a l o g i t p a r a m e t e r e s t i m a t e i s k n o w n a s a n o d d s r a t i o, a n d i s c o m p u t e d a s e x p { ß 1 } ( s e e D e m a r i s ( ) ).

19 19 strong evidence that trading range considerations are important to firms and that they use stock splits to manage share price levels. The coefficients on StockApprec j,t (i.e., the ß 2 s) are also positive and generally significant, indicating that firms are more likely to split their stock after a period of price appreciation, consistent with the findings of earlier studies (see footnote 22). This result is not surprising, since an increase I share prices is likely to be the primary cause of share prices becoming too high relative to their appropriate trading range. The trading range variable is, however, more important than the price appreciation variable as a predictor of a firm s propensity to split its stock. Panel B in Table V reports the results of the logit model when the variable measuring the firm s relative investor base, Shareholders j,t, is included. The results for TradeRa n g e j,t and StockApprec j,t are similar to those reported in Panel A, and the overall significance levels are slightly higher. In three of the four cross-sections, firms with relatively large shareholder bases (i.e., the number of shareholders is in the 95 th percentile) are less likely to split than are firms with smaller shareholder bases, a result significant at the.01 level for the 1976 and 1981 cross-sections. 2 5 The results in both Panels A and B of Table V suggest that when stock prices exceed some preferred trading range, firms are more likely to split their stock to move prices back toward a desired share price habitat, but that firms with very large shareholder bases are less likely to split. C. Do Stock Splits Increase the Number of Shareholders? A basic theme of this paper is that firms manage share price levels to make the 2 5 T h e c o e f f i c i e n t o n S h a r e h o l d e r s j,t i n t h e c r o s s -s e c t i o n i s p o s i t i v e, b u t i n s i g n i f i c a n t.

20 20 firm s common stock more attractive to investors. Why might one share price be more attractive than another to a particular firm s current and potential shareholders? We have already summarized the explanations offered by Merton (1987), Brennan and Hughes (1991), Angel (1997) and the NYSE Listed Company Manual (undated) and have presented various reasons why the preferences of so-called small investors might differ markedly f rom those of large institutional investors. Indeed, it is likely that all of these explanations at least partially account for the differences in share price preferences among firms. Although a unified theory of share price levels and stock splits is b eyond the scope of this paper, we can document whether or not stock splits by the firms in our sample are associated with subsequent increases in the number of shareholders (for whatever reason). These findings are summarized in Table VI. Firms that have at least a 2 -for-1 stock split average a 50 percent increase in shareholders during the four years, whereas firms that do not split their stock or have a smaller split average a 0.5 percent decrease in shareholders. Similarly, firms that have a 1.25-to-1 or greater split exhibit an average increase in shareholders of 42 percent and the other firms average a 5 percent decrease in shareholders. The results for our sample are thus consistent with those of earlier studies (see footnote 11). If the purpose o f stock splits is to increase a firm s socalled investor base, it appears that, on average, they accomplish this goal (even if the mechanism is not entirely clear).

21 21 IV. Conclusions We observe wide variations among share prices in U.S. stock markets, and it i s evident that these differences in share prices do not just happen. That is, apparently firms manage their share prices. We present cross-sectional evidence that variables consistent with Merton s (1987) model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information explain 45 percent of the variation among firms share prices. In particular, firms owned by small investors have lower share prices and vice versa, and large, wellknown firms have higher share prices and vice versa. We also find that trading range, share price appreciation, and shareholder base are significant predictors of subsequent stock splits, and that firms splitting their stock experience an increase in shareholders compared to non -splitting firms. We conclude that the Share Price Puzzle is not so puzzling after all. Rather, it is a matter of the optimal design of a security. The high dispersion in stock prices in U.S. markets is largely a manifestation of firms tailoring their share prices to reflect the desires of the firm s owners.

22 22 References Affleck-Graves, John, Shantaram Hegde, and Robert E. Miller, 1996, Conditional price trends in the aftermarket for initial public offerings, Financial Management 2 5, Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson, 1986, Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread, Journal of Financial Economics 17, Amihud, Yakov, Haim Mendelson, and Jun Uno, 1999, Number of shareholders and stock prices: Evidence from Japan, Journal of Finance 54, Angel, James J., 1997, Tick size, share prices, and stock splits, Journal of Finance 52, Anshuman, V. Ravi, and Avner Kalay, 1998, Market making with discrete prices, Review of Financial Studies 1 1, Atkins, Allen B., and Edward A. Dyl, 1997, Transactions costs and holding periods for common stocks, Journal of Finance 52, Badrinath, S. G., Gerald D. Gay, and Jayant R. Kale, 1989, Patterns of institutional investment, prudence, and the managerial safety-net hypothesis, Journal of Risk and Insurance 56, Baker, W. Kent, and Patricia L. Gallagher, 1980, Management s view of stock splits, Financial Management 9, Benston, George J., and Robert L. Hagerman, 1974, Determinants of bid-ask spreads in the over- the-counter market, Journal of Financial Economics 1, Black, Fischer, 1972, Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing, Journal of Business 45, Brennen, Michael J., and Thomas E. Copeland, 1988, Stock splits, stock prices, and transaction costs, Journal of Financial Economics 2 2, Brennen, Michael J., and Patricia J. Hughes, 1991, Stock prices and the supply of information, Journal of Finance 46, Conroy, Robert M., and Robert S. Harris, 1999, Stock splits and information: The role of share price, Financial Management 28, Conroy, Robert M., Robert S. Harris, and Bruce A. Benet, 1990, The effects of stock splits on bid-ask spreads, Journal of Finance 45,

23 23 Constantanides, George, 1986, Capital market equilibrium with transaction costs, Journal of Political Economy 94, Copeland, Thomas E., 1979, Liquidity changes following stock splits, Journal of Finance 34, Demaris, Alfred, 1992, Logit modeling: Practical applications, Sage University Paper Series: Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences , Sage Publications, Beverly Hills, CA. Demsetz, Harold, 1968, The cost of transacting, Quarterly Journal of Economics 8 2, Evans, John L., and Stephen H. Archer, 1968, Diversification and the reduction of disperson: An empirical analysis, Journal of Finance 23, Fama, Eugene F., Lawrence Fisher, Michael C. Jensen, and Richard Roll, 1969, The adjustment of stock prices to new information, International Economic Review 10, Fernando, Chitru S., Srinivasan Krishnamurthy, and Paul A. Spindt, 1999, Is share price related to marketability? Evidence from mutual fund share splits, Financial Management 2 8, Harris, Lawrence, 1994, Minimum price variations, discrete bid-ask spreads, and quotation sizes, Review of Financial Studies 7, Ikenberry, David L., Graeme Rankine, and Earl K. Stice, 1996, What do stock splits really signal? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, Lakonishok, Josef, and Baruch Lev, 1987, Stock splits and stock dividends: Why, who, and when? Journal of Finance 42, Lamoureux, Christopher G., and Percy Poon, 1987, The market reaction to stock splits, Journal of Finance 42, Maloney, Michael T., and J. Harold Mulherin, 1992, The effects of splitting on the ex: A microstructure reconciliation, Financial Management 2 1, Markowitz, Harry, 1952, Portfolio selection, Journal of Finance 7, McNichols, Maureen, and Ajay Dravid, 1990, Stock dividends, stock splits, and signaling, Journal of Finance 45, Merton, Robert C., 1987, A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete infromation, Journal of Finance 42,

24 24 Mukherji, Sandip, Yong H. Kim, and Michael C. Walker, 1997, The effect of stock splits on the ownership structure of firms, Journal of Corporate Finance 3, Muscarella, Chris J., and Michael R. Vetsuypens, 1996, Stock splits: Signaling or liquidity? The case of ADR solo-splits, Journal of Financial Economics 42, Schultz, Paul, 2000, Stock splits, tick size and sponsorship, Journal of Finance 5 5, Statman, Meir, 1987, How many stocks make a diversified portfolio? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22, Stoll, Hans R., 1978, The pricing of security dealer services: An empirical study of Nasdaq stocks, Journal of Finance 33, Stoll, Hans R., and Robert E. Whaley, 1983, Transactions costs and the small firm effect: A comment, Journal of Financial Economics 1 2, Tinic, Seha M., 1972, The economics of liquidity services, Quarterly Journal of Economics 86, White, Halbert, 1980, A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48,

25 25 $250 $200 $150 Price $100 $50 Average Price w/o Splits Average Price $ Year Figure 1. Average Common Stock Prices from 1976 to Average annual stock prices for 1,452 firms with continuous data available on CRSP for 1976 through The annual price for each firm is the average of monthly closing prices. The solid line shows actual prices. The broken line shows what the prices would have been in the absence of stock splits that occurred during this period.

26 26 Table I Stock Prices on the NYSE, Amex, and Nasdaq in 1996 I n c l u d e s a l l f i r m s r e p o r t e d i n t h e C R S P d a t a b a s e f o r h a v i n g a n a v e r a g e p r i c e o f a t l e a s t $ p e r s h a r e. I n d i v i d u a l f i r m s s t o c k p r i c e s a r e t h e a v e r a g e o f m o n t h l y c l o s i n g p r i c e s i n M a r k e t v a l u e i s t h e year-e n d m a r k e t c a p i t a l i z a t i o n r e p o r t e d i n t h e C R S P d a t a b a s e. All Prices Less than $ 1 0 $ 1 0 to $30 $ 3 0 t o $ 5 0 $ 5 0 t o $ 7 0 Greater than $70 Panel A: All Firms Listed on the NYSE, Amex, and Nasdaq Share Price Mean $ $ $ $ $57.84 $ Median $ $ $ $ $56.81 $ Number of Firms 6, , , Proportion of Firms % 33.2% % % 3. 5 % 1. 7 % Market Value (000,000) Mean $ 1, $ 8 4 $ $ 2, $8,545 $ 2 0, Median $149 $ 3 3 $ $ 1, $4,259 $ 7, Panel B: NYSE Firms Share Price Mean $ $ $ $ $57.68 $ Median $ $ $ $ $56.62 $ Number of Firms 2, , Proportion of Firms % 15.6% % % 6. 9 % 3. 5 % Market Value (000,000) Mean $ 2, $ $ $ 3, $ 1 0, $ 2 2, Median $531 $ $ $ 1, $4,963 $ 1 3, Panel C: Amex Firms Share Price Mean $ $ $ $ $58.95 $ Median $ $ $ $ $ Number of Firms Proportion of Firms % 46.4% % 5.4% 0. 4 % 1. 1 % Market Value (000,000) Mean $209 $ 5 9 $ $ 1, $1,045 $ Median $ 5 8 $ 2 9 $ 9 0 $ $ Panel D: Nasdaq Firms Share Price Mean $ $ $ $ $58.27 $ Median $ $ $ $ $57.49 $ Number of Firms 3, , , Proportion of Firms % 43.3% % 9.4% 1. 7 % 0.1 Market Value (000,000) Mean $366 $ 4 8 $ $ 1, $3,667 $ 1 5, Median $ 7 9 $ 2 7 $ $ $1,982 $ 1, 0 9 7

27 27 Table II Descriptive Statistics for Sample Firms, T h e s h a r e p r i c e s a m p l e i n c l u d e s a l l f i r m s w i t h a s h a r e p r i c e g r e a t e r t h a n o r e q u a l t o $ i n a n d w i t h c o n t i n u o u s i n f o r m a t i o n a v a i l a b l e o n C R S P f r o m t o A n n u a l s h a r e p r i c e i s t h e a v e r a g e o f m o n t h l y c l o s i n g p r i c e s f r o m C R S P. M a r k e t v a l u e i s t h e y e a r -e n d c a p i t a l i z a t i o n r e p o r t e d o n C R S P. N u m b e r o f s h a r e h o l d e r s i s f r o m C o m p u s t a t, a n d i n s t i t u t i o n a l o w n e r s h i p i s f r o m C o m p a c t D i s c l o s u r e P a n e l A : S h a r e P r i c e M e a n $ $ $ $ $ ( S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) M e d i a n $ $ $ $ $ N u m b e r o f F i r m s 1, , , , , P a n e l B : M a r k e t V a l u e ( 0 0 0, ) M e a n $ $ $ 1, $ 1, $ 3, ( S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n ) ( 2, ) ( 2, ) ( 3, ) ( 6, ) ( 1 1, ) M e d i a n $ 5 2 $ $ $ $ N u m b e r o f F i r m s 1, , , , , P a n e l C : N u m b e r o f S h a r e h o l d e r s ( ) M e a n ( S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) M e d i a n N u m b e r o f F i r m s , , , P a n e l D : A v e r a g e I n v e s t m e n t p e r S h a r e h o l d e r ( ) M e a n $ $ $ $ $ ( S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) M e d i a n $ $ $ $ $ N u m b e r o f F i r m s , , , P a n e l E : I n s t i t u t i o n a l O w n e r s h i p M e a n n.a. n.a % % % ( S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n ) n.a. n.a. ( ) ( ) ( ) M e d i a n n.a. n.a % % % N u m b e r o f F i r m s n.a. n.a , 2 2 8

28 28 Table III Share Prices, Firm Size, and Ownership Characteristics T h i s t a b l e r e p o r t s c r o s s -s e c t i o n a l e s t i m a t e s o f t h e p a r a m e t e r s o f t h e f o l l o w i n g r e g r e s s i o n v a r i a b l e s : S h a r e P r i c e j,t = δ 0 + δ 1 T o t a l A s s e t s j,t + δ 2 A v g H l d g j,t + δ 3 I n s t P c t j,t + ε j,t w h e r e S h a r e P r i c e j,t i s t h e a v e r a g e p r i c e p e r s h a r e o f f i r m j s c o m m o n s t ock during year t, T o t a l A s s e t s j,t i s t h e l o g a r i t h m o f t h e b o o k v a l u e o f f i r m j s a s s e t s a t t h e e n d o f y e a r t, A v g H l d g j,t i s t h e a v e r a g e d o l l a r i n v e s t m e n t p e r s h a r e h o l d e r i n f i r m j d u r i n g y e a r t, a n d I n s t P c t j,t i s t h e p e r c e n t a g e o f f i r m j o w n e d b y i n s t i t u t i o n a l i n v e s t o r s d u r i n g y e a r t. T h e n u m b e r s i n p a r e n t h e s e s a r e W h i t e ( ) h e t e r o s k e d a s t i c i t y c o n s i s t e n t t -s t a t i s t i c s, a n d * * ( * ) d e n o t e s s i g n i f i c a n c e a t t h e. 0 1 (. 0 5 ) l e v e l. Year δ 0 δ 1 δ 2 δ 3 Adj. R 2 F- test Number of Firms Panel A: The Independent Variables are T o t a l A s s e t s a n d A v g H l d g (-4.63**) (10.57**) (8.24**) ( ) (15.12**) (9.16**) (-3.54**) (15.41**) (4.27**) , (-5.21**) (16.61**) (8.49**) , (-6.38**) (15.05**) (4.93**) , Panel B: The Independent Variables are T o t a l A s s e t s a n d InstPct (- 2.29*) (6.65**) ( ) (-6.88**) (14.47**) (6.19**) (-8.94**) (16.81**) (4.69**) , Panel C: The Independent Variables are T o t a l A s s e t s, A v g H l d g, and I n s t P c t ( ) (7.63**) (4.95**) ( ) (-4.99**) (13.10**) (7.06**) (2.42*) (-6.46**) (13.72**) (4.45**) ( *) , 1 0 1

The Share Price Puzzle*

The Share Price Puzzle* Edward A. Dyl William B. Elliott University of Arizona The Share Price Puzzle* In frictionless markets, share prices per se do not affect the value of the firm. Consider two identical firms, each with

More information

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden This version: May 2008 JEL Classification: G14, G32 Keywords: Stock Price Levels, Ownership structure,

More information

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Thomas J. Chemmanur Boston College Gang Hu Babson College Jiekun Huang Boston College First Version: September

More information

Stock Splits and Liquidity: The Case of the Nasdaq-100 Index Tracking Stock

Stock Splits and Liquidity: The Case of the Nasdaq-100 Index Tracking Stock Stock Splits and Liquidity: The Case of the Nasdaq-100 Index Tracking Stock Patrick Dennis University of Virginia Keywords: stock splits, signaling, liquidity, index-tracking stock JEL Classi cations:

More information

The Information Content of Stock Splits *

The Information Content of Stock Splits * The Information Content of Stock Splits * Gow-Cheng Huang Department of Accounting and Finance Alabama State University Montgomery, AL 36101-0271 Phone: 334-229-6920 E-mail: ghuang@alasu.edu Kartono Liano

More information

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us?

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? Bernt Arne Ødegaard Sep 2008 Abstract We empirically investigate the costs of trading equity at the Oslo Stock

More information

On Existence of An Optimal Stock Price : Evidence from Stock Splits and Reverse Stock Splits in Hong Kong

On Existence of An Optimal Stock Price : Evidence from Stock Splits and Reverse Stock Splits in Hong Kong INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF BUSINESS, 2(1), 1997 ISSN: 1083-4346 On Existence of An Optimal Stock Price : Evidence from Stock Splits and Reverse Stock Splits in Hong Kong Lifan Wu and Bob Y. Chan We analyze

More information

http://www.jstor.org LINKED CITATIONS -Page1of7- You have printed the following article: Can the Treatment of Limit Orders Reconcile the Differences in Trading Costs between NYSE and Nasdaq Issues? Kee

More information

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Thomas J. Chemmanur Boston College Gang Hu Babson College Jiekun Huang Boston College First Version: September

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 THE USE OF FINANCIAL RATIOS AS MEASURES OF RISK IN THE DETERMINATION OF THE BID-ASK SPREAD Huldah A. Ryan * Abstract The effect

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

Stock Market Liquidity and Firm Dividend Policy

Stock Market Liquidity and Firm Dividend Policy Stock Market Liquidity and Firm Dividend Policy Suman Banerjee A. B. Freeman School of Business Tulane University 7 McAlister Drive New Orleans, LA 70118 Suman.Banerjee@tulane.edu (504) 865-5558 Vladimir

More information

Efficient Effects of Stock Splits on the Market

Efficient Effects of Stock Splits on the Market Stock splits, liquidity, and information asymmetry An empirical study on Tokyo Stock Exchange Fang Guo Department of Economics and Finance City University of Hong Kong Tat Chee Avenue, Kowloon Hong Kong,

More information

The Impact of Clientele Changes: Evidence from Stock Splits *

The Impact of Clientele Changes: Evidence from Stock Splits * The Impact of Clientele Changes: Evidence from Stock Splits * Ravi Dhar Yale School of Management Shane Shepherd Anderson School at UCLA William N. Goetzmann Yale School of Management Ning Zhu Yale School

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 THE VALUE OF INDIRECT INVESTMENT ADVICE: STOCK RECOMMENDATIONS IN BARRON'S

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 THE VALUE OF INDIRECT INVESTMENT ADVICE: STOCK RECOMMENDATIONS IN BARRON'S Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 THE VALUE OF INDIRECT INVESTMENT ADVICE: STOCK RECOMMENDATIONS IN BARRON'S Gary A. Benesh * and Jeffrey A. Clark * Abstract This

More information

The Market Reaction to Stock Split Announcements: Earnings Information After All

The Market Reaction to Stock Split Announcements: Earnings Information After All The Market Reaction to Stock Split Announcements: Earnings Information After All Alon Kalay Columbia School of Business Columbia University Mathias Kronlund College of Business University of Illinois at

More information

Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator

Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator A Comment On Pricing of Liquidity Risks: Evidence from Multiple Liquidity Measures by Soon-Ho Kim and Kuan-Hui Lee, Journal of Empirical Finance

More information

THE NASDAQ-AMEX MERGER, NASDAQ REFORMS, AND THE LIQUIDITY OF SMALL FIRMS. Abstract

THE NASDAQ-AMEX MERGER, NASDAQ REFORMS, AND THE LIQUIDITY OF SMALL FIRMS. Abstract The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXVI, No. 2 Pages 225 242 Summer 2003 THE NASDAQ-AMEX MERGER, NASDAQ REFORMS, AND THE LIQUIDITY OF SMALL FIRMS Travis R. A. Sapp Iowa State University Xuemin (Sterling)

More information

CHAPTER 17. Payout Policy. Chapter Synopsis

CHAPTER 17. Payout Policy. Chapter Synopsis CHAPTER 17 Payout Policy Chapter Synopsis 17.1 Distributions to Shareholders A corporation s payout policy determines if and when it will distribute cash to its shareholders by issuing a dividend or undertaking

More information

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance Journal of Applied Corporate Finance WINTER 2000 VOLUME 12.4 The Liquidity Route to a Lower Cost of Capital by Yakov Amihud, New York University, and Haim Mendelson, Stanford University THE LIQUIDITY ROUTE

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 3 Fall 1995

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 3 Fall 1995 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 3 Fall 1995 EXPECTATIONS OF WEEKEND AND TURN-OF-THE-MONTH MEAN RETURN SHIFTS IMPLICIT IN INDEX CALL OPTION PRICES Amy Dickinson * and David

More information

Stock Splits, Trading Continuity, and the Cost of Equity Capital

Stock Splits, Trading Continuity, and the Cost of Equity Capital Stock Splits, Trading Continuity, and the Cost of Equity Capital Ji-Chai Lin, Louisiana State University Ajai K. Singh, Case Western Reserve University Wen Yu, University of St. Thomas Abstract: Based

More information

A Study of information asymmetry using Bid-Ask spread on firm value: evidence from Tehran Stock Exchange

A Study of information asymmetry using Bid-Ask spread on firm value: evidence from Tehran Stock Exchange International Research Journal of Applied and Basic Sciences 2013 Available online at www.irjabs.com ISSN 2251-838X / Vol, 4 (9): 2872-2876 Science Explorer Publications A Study of information asymmetry

More information

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance Online Appendix Mikhail Simutin Abstract This online appendix shows robustness to alternative definitions of abnormal cash holdings, studies the relation between

More information

What is the relationship between investor holding period and liquidity?

What is the relationship between investor holding period and liquidity? What is the relationship between investor holding period and liquidity? Randi Næs and Bernt Arne Ødegaard April 2007 Very Preliminary Abstract Expected holding period for individual investors is a central

More information

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans ABSTRACT The pricing of China Region ETFs - an empirical analysis Yao Zheng University of New Orleans Eric Osmer University of New Orleans Using a sample of exchange-traded funds (ETFs) that focus on investing

More information

Transactions Costs for TSE-listed stocks

Transactions Costs for TSE-listed stocks Transactions Costs for TSE-listed stocks Transactions costs can erode the performance of an investment strategy. by Sean Cleary, Kevin Kerr and John Schmitz Transactions costs are an important consideration

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 THE ROLE OF INSIDERS AND DIVIDEND POLICY: A COMPARISON OF REGULATED AND UNREGULATED FIRMS M. Cary Collins *, Atul K. Saxena **

More information

Market Share. Open. Repurchases in CANADA 24 WINTER 2002 CANADIAN INVESTMENT REVIEW

Market Share. Open. Repurchases in CANADA 24 WINTER 2002 CANADIAN INVESTMENT REVIEW Open Market Share Repurchases in CANADA Many Canadian firms time repurchases when their shares are undervalued. What does this mean for investors? BY WILLIAM J. MCNALLY Open market repurchases are becoming

More information

Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities

Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities Journal of Financial Markets 1 (1998) 51 87 Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities Hee-Joon Ahn, Charles Q. Cao *, Hyuk Choe

More information

CONFORMED COPY Q.k~c~S ' UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA. Philadelphia 4. July 9, 1962. Wharton School of Finance and Commerce

CONFORMED COPY Q.k~c~S ' UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA. Philadelphia 4. July 9, 1962. Wharton School of Finance and Commerce CONFORMED COPY Q.k~c~S ' UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA Philadelphia 4 Wharton School of Finance and Commerce Securities and Exchange Commission 425 Second St., N. W. Washington 25, D. C. Gentlemen: We are

More information

THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE

THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE A Thesis Submitted to The College of Graduate Studies and Research in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master

More information

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market Abstract The purpose of this paper is to explore the stock market s reaction to quarterly financial

More information

The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume*

The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume* JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 7, 130 150 (1998) ARTICLE NO. JF980238 The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume* Michael J. Barclay University of Rochester, Rochester, New

More information

Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis

Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVII, NO. 4 AUGUST 2002 Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis GUSTAVO GRULLON and RONI MICHAELY* ABSTRACT We show that repurchases have not only became

More information

STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS

STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS Chia-Shang James Chu Department of Economics, MC 0253 University of Southern California Los Angles, CA 90089 Gary J. Santoni and Tung Liu Department

More information

Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002

Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002 The Financial Review 40 (2005) 281--304 Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002 Bonnie F. Van Ness University of Mississippi Robert A. Van Ness University of Mississippi Richard S. Warr North Carolina

More information

THE REPURCHASE OF SHARES - ANOTHER FORM OF REWARDING INVESTORS - A THEORETICAL APPROACH

THE REPURCHASE OF SHARES - ANOTHER FORM OF REWARDING INVESTORS - A THEORETICAL APPROACH THE REPURCHASE OF SHARES - ANOTHER FORM OF REWARDING INVESTORS - A THEORETICAL APPROACH Maria PRISACARIU Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Alexandru Ioan Cuza University, Iasy, Romania,

More information

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Question 5.1. Four different ways to sell a share of stock that has a price S(0) at time 0. Question 5.2. Description Get Paid at Lose Ownership of Receive Payment

More information

Trading Turnover and Expected Stock Returns: The Trading Frequency Hypothesis and Evidence from the Tokyo Stock Exchange

Trading Turnover and Expected Stock Returns: The Trading Frequency Hypothesis and Evidence from the Tokyo Stock Exchange Trading Turnover and Expected Stock Returns: The Trading Frequency Hypothesis and Evidence from the Tokyo Stock Exchange Shing-yang Hu National Taiwan University and University of Chicago 1101 East 58

More information

Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading near Ten Dollars 1

Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading near Ten Dollars 1 Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 213 239 (2000) doi:10.1006/jfin.2000.0288, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading

More information

Institutional ownership, analyst following and share prices *

Institutional ownership, analyst following and share prices * Institutional ownership, analyst following and share prices * Chitru S. Fernando (corresponding author) Michael F. Price College of Business, University of Oklahoma 307 West Brooks, Norman, OK 73019 cfernando@ou.edu

More information

Morgan Stanley Reports First Quarter 2016:

Morgan Stanley Reports First Quarter 2016: Media Relations: Michele Davis 212-761-9621 Investor Relations: Kathleen McCabe 212-761-4469 Morgan Stanley Reports First Quarter 2016: Net Revenues of $7.8 Billion and Earnings per Diluted Share of $0.55

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

Rates for Vehicle Loans: Race and Loan Source

Rates for Vehicle Loans: Race and Loan Source Rates for Vehicle Loans: Race and Loan Source Kerwin Kofi Charles Harris School University of Chicago 1155 East 60th Street Chicago, IL 60637 Voice: (773) 834-8922 Fax: (773) 702-0926 e-mail: kcharles@gmail.com

More information

Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets

Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets Liping Zou 1 and Ying Zhang Massey University at Albany, Private Bag 102904, Auckland, New Zealand

More information

ACTIVITY 20.1 THE LANGUAGE OF FINANCIAL MARKETS: DEFINITIONS

ACTIVITY 20.1 THE LANGUAGE OF FINANCIAL MARKETS: DEFINITIONS ACTIVITY 20.1 THE LANGUAGE OF FINANCIAL MARKETS: DEFINITIONS AMEX: The acronym stands for American Stock Exchange, formerly an independent market but now part of the New York Stock Exchange; the AMEX s

More information

Cross-Country Listing and Trading Volume: Evidence from the Toronto and Vancouver Stock Exchanges

Cross-Country Listing and Trading Volume: Evidence from the Toronto and Vancouver Stock Exchanges Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting 8:3 1997 Cross-Country Listing and Trading Volume: Evidence from the Toronto and Vancouver Stock Exchanges Usha R. Mittoo* University of Manitoba

More information

ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT

ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT NICOLAS P.B. BOLLEN * ROBERT E. WHALEY * ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT On June 5 th, 1997, the NYSE voted to adopt a system of decimal price quoting, changing its longstanding practice of using 1/8 th s.

More information

How Stock Splits Affect Trading: A Microstructure Approach

How Stock Splits Affect Trading: A Microstructure Approach How Stock Splits Affect Trading: A Microstructure Approach by David Easley*, Maureen O Hara** and Gideon Saar*** First version: March 1998 This version: July 2000 Forthcoming in the Journal of Financial

More information

NATIONAL SURVEY OF HOME EQUITY LOANS

NATIONAL SURVEY OF HOME EQUITY LOANS NATIONAL SURVEY OF HOME EQUITY LOANS Richard T. Curtin Director, Surveys of Consumers Survey Research Center The October 1998 WP51 The 1988, 1994, and 1997 National Surveys of Home Equity Loans were sponsored

More information

Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the Saudi Market

Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the Saudi Market 2011 International Conference on Economics, Trade and Development IPEDR vol.7 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the

More information

The High-Volume Return Premium: Evidence from Chinese Stock Markets

The High-Volume Return Premium: Evidence from Chinese Stock Markets The High-Volume Return Premium: Evidence from Chinese Stock Markets 1. Introduction If price and quantity are two fundamental elements in any market interaction, then the importance of trading volume in

More information

What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 1998 1

What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 1998 1 Craig H Furfine +4 6 28 923 craig.furfine@bis.org Eli M Remolona +4 6 28 844 eli.remolona@bis.org What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 998 Autumn 998 witnessed

More information

A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA

A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA ABSTRACT Modigliani and Miller (1958, 1963) predict two very specific relationships between firm value

More information

Empirical Evidence on the Existence of Dividend Clienteles EDITH S. HOTCHKISS* STEPHEN LAWRENCE** Boston College. July 2007.

Empirical Evidence on the Existence of Dividend Clienteles EDITH S. HOTCHKISS* STEPHEN LAWRENCE** Boston College. July 2007. Empirical Evidence on the Existence of Dividend Clienteles EDITH S. HOTCHKISS* STEPHEN LAWRENCE** Boston College July 2007 Abstract This paper provides new evidence the existence of dividend clienteles.

More information

Some Insider Sales Are Positive Signals

Some Insider Sales Are Positive Signals James Scott and Peter Xu Not all insider sales are the same. In the study reported here, a variable for shares traded as a percentage of insiders holdings was used to separate information-driven sales

More information

Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq

Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq Journal of Financial Economics 45 (1997) 3 8 Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq G. William Schwert William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester,

More information

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157 A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157 By Stanley Jay Feldman, Ph.D. Chairman and Chief Valuation Officer Axiom Valuation Solutions 201 Edgewater Drive, Suite 255 Wakefield,

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Financial Markets And Financial Instruments - Part I

Financial Markets And Financial Instruments - Part I Financial Markets And Financial Instruments - Part I Financial Assets Real assets are things such as land, buildings, machinery, and knowledge that are used to produce goods and services. Financial assets

More information

Evidence and Implications of Increases in Trading Volume around Seasoned Equity Offerings

Evidence and Implications of Increases in Trading Volume around Seasoned Equity Offerings Evidence and Implications of Increases in Trading Volume around Seasoned Equity Offerings Surendranath R. Jory *, Assistant Professor University of Michigan at Flint Thanh N. Ngo, Assistant Professor University

More information

Determinants of short-term debt financing

Determinants of short-term debt financing ABSTRACT Determinants of short-term debt financing Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University In this study, it is shown that both theories put forward to explain the amount of shortterm debt financing

More information

No More Weekend Effect

No More Weekend Effect No More Weekend Effect Russell P. Robins 1 and Geoffrey Peter Smith 2 1 AB Freeman School of Business, Tulane University 2 WP Carey School of Business, Arizona State University Abstract Before 1975, the

More information

INCORPORATION OF LIQUIDITY RISKS INTO EQUITY PORTFOLIO RISK ESTIMATES. Dan dibartolomeo September 2010

INCORPORATION OF LIQUIDITY RISKS INTO EQUITY PORTFOLIO RISK ESTIMATES. Dan dibartolomeo September 2010 INCORPORATION OF LIQUIDITY RISKS INTO EQUITY PORTFOLIO RISK ESTIMATES Dan dibartolomeo September 2010 GOALS FOR THIS TALK Assert that liquidity of a stock is properly measured as the expected price change,

More information

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson.

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson. Internet Appendix to Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson August 9, 2015 This Internet Appendix provides additional empirical results

More information

Chapter 12. Investing in the Stock Market. The Indexing Alternative. The Performance of Active and Passive Funds

Chapter 12. Investing in the Stock Market. The Indexing Alternative. The Performance of Active and Passive Funds Chapter 12 Investing in the Stock Market Most investors, both institutional and individual, will find the best way to own common stocks is through an index fund that charges minimal fees. Warren Buffet

More information

Decimalization and market liquidity

Decimalization and market liquidity Decimalization and market liquidity Craig H. Furfine On January 29, 21, the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) implemented decimalization. Beginning on that Monday, stocks began to be priced in dollars and

More information

Qi Yongjun. Three Gorges University, China

Qi Yongjun. Three Gorges University, China Journal of Modern Accounting and Auditing, ISSN 1548-6583 March 2012, Vol. 8, No. 3, 374-380 D DAVID PUBLISHING A Study on the Behavior of Large Stock Dividends and Stock Splits Among Chinese Listed Companies:

More information

The Young Investor s Guide To Understanding The Terms Used In Investing.

The Young Investor s Guide To Understanding The Terms Used In Investing. The Young Investor s Guide To Understanding The Terms Used In Investing. The Young Investor Dictionary compliments of Integrity Mutual Funds. YOUNG INVESTOR DICTIONARY Asset Something of value. The property

More information

Trading restrictions and stock prices:

Trading restrictions and stock prices: Trading restrictions and stock prices: Robin Harvard Business School QWAFAFEW Boston October 17, 2006 Trading Restrictions Trading restrictions reduce ability of liquidity providers to dampen uninformed

More information

Payout Ratio: The Most Influential Management Decision a Company Can Make?

Payout Ratio: The Most Influential Management Decision a Company Can Make? leadership series market research Payout Ratio: The Most Influential Management Decision a Company Can Make? January 2013 In today s equity market, payout ratios have a meaningful impact on both equity

More information

DSIP List (Diversified Stock Income Plan)

DSIP List (Diversified Stock Income Plan) Kent A. Newcomb, CFA, Equity Sector Analyst Joseph E. Buffa, Equity Sector Analyst DSIP List (Diversified Stock Income Plan) Commentary from ASG's Equity Sector Analysts January 2014 Concept Review The

More information

An Examination of the Narrow Window of Opportunity for Concurrent Regular Way and When-issued Trading

An Examination of the Narrow Window of Opportunity for Concurrent Regular Way and When-issued Trading An Examination of the Narrow Window of Opportunity for Concurrent Regular Way and When-issued Trading Thomas Thompson * and Vincent Apilado ** * Lamar University ** University of Texas-Arlington Abstract

More information

Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service

Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service David S. Allen Associate Professor of Finance The W. A. Franke College of Business Northern Arizona University P.O. Box

More information

Investor recognition and stock returns

Investor recognition and stock returns Rev Acc Stud (2008) 13:327 361 DOI 10.1007/s11142-007-9063-y Investor recognition and stock returns Reuven Lehavy Æ Richard G. Sloan Published online: 9 January 2008 Ó Springer Science+Business Media,

More information

The Homogenization of US Equity Trading. Lawrence Harris * Draft: September 30, 2011. Abstract

The Homogenization of US Equity Trading. Lawrence Harris * Draft: September 30, 2011. Abstract The Homogenization of US Equity Trading Lawrence Harris * Draft: September 30, 2011 Abstract NASDAQ stocks once traded in quote-driven dealer markets while listed stocks traded in orderdriven auctions

More information

The Nominal Price Puzzle. Shlomo Benartzi UCLA. Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC. Richard H. Thaler University of Chicago and NBER

The Nominal Price Puzzle. Shlomo Benartzi UCLA. Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC. Richard H. Thaler University of Chicago and NBER The Nominal Price Puzzle Shlomo Benartzi UCLA Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC Richard H. Thaler University of Chicago and NBER William C. Weld Cornell University December 2006 We would like to

More information

Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings. by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings. by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) Jennifer Francis (Duke University) Thomas Lys (Northwestern University) Linda Vincent (Northwestern University) This

More information

SHORT INTRODUCTION OF SHORT SELLING

SHORT INTRODUCTION OF SHORT SELLING Financial Assets and Investing SHORT INTRODUCTION OF SHORT SELLING Dagmar Linnertová Faculty of Economics and Administration, Masaryk University, Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno, e-mail: Dagmar.Linnertova@mail.muni.cz

More information

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY Gary L. Caton *, Jeffrey Donaldson**, Jeremy Goh*** Abstract Studies on the announcement effects of bankruptcy filings have found that when a firm

More information

Institutional and individual investor preferences for dividends and share repurchases

Institutional and individual investor preferences for dividends and share repurchases Journal of Economics and Business 59 (2007) 406 429 Institutional and individual investor preferences for dividends and share repurchases Ravi Jain National University of Singapore Business School, 1 Business

More information

Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange #

Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange # Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange # Kee H. Chung * and Jung S. Shin State University of New York at Buffalo Abstract The Korea Stock Exchange (KSE) imposes larger mandatory tick sizes

More information

What Drives the S&P 500 Inclusion Effect? An Analytical Survey

What Drives the S&P 500 Inclusion Effect? An Analytical Survey What Drives the S&P 500 Inclusion Effect? An Analytical Survey William B. Elliott, Bonnie F. Van Ness, Mark D. Walker, and Richard S. Warr* We present an analytical survey of the explanations price pressure,

More information

The Nominal Price Puzzle. William C. Weld Cornell University. Shlomo Benartzi UCLA. Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC

The Nominal Price Puzzle. William C. Weld Cornell University. Shlomo Benartzi UCLA. Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC The Nominal Price Puzzle William C. Weld Cornell University Shlomo Benartzi UCLA Roni Michaely Cornell University and IDC Richard H. Thaler University of Chicago and NBER March 2007 We would like to thank

More information

Shares Mutual funds Structured bonds Bonds Cash money, deposits

Shares Mutual funds Structured bonds Bonds Cash money, deposits FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND RELATED RISKS This description of investment risks is intended for you. The professionals of AB bank Finasta have strived to understandably introduce you the main financial instruments

More information

Asset Liquidity and Mutual Fund Management Fees: Evidence from Closed-End Mutual Funds

Asset Liquidity and Mutual Fund Management Fees: Evidence from Closed-End Mutual Funds Asset Liquidity and Mutual Fund Management Fees: Evidence from Closed-End Mutual Funds Charles Cullinan (Corresponding author) Department of Accounting, Bryant University 1150 Douglas Pike, Smithfield,

More information

Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service. David S. Allen. Associate Professor of Finance

Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service. David S. Allen. Associate Professor of Finance Learning by Doing: Portfolio Management Using the Bloomberg Professional Service David S. Allen Associate Professor of Finance The W. A. Franke College of Business Northern Arizona University P.O. Box

More information

Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices

Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices Capital Market Frictions Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices By Terrence Hendershott and Mark S. Seasholes* Empirical studies linking liquidity provision to asset prices follow naturally from inventory

More information

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36) Readings Chapters 9 and 10 Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock 1. The investor s expected return 2. Valuation as the Present Value (PV) of dividends and the growth of dividends 3. The investor s required

More information

THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY

THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY Accounting: A method of recording a company s financial activity and arranging the information in reports that make the information understandable. Accounts payable: The

More information

Form of the government and Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price

Form of the government and Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price Form of the government and Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price Abstract One of the important functions of the stock market is to produce information through stock prices. Specifically, stock market aggregates

More information

Virtual Stock Market Game Glossary

Virtual Stock Market Game Glossary Virtual Stock Market Game Glossary American Stock Exchange-AMEX An open auction market similar to the NYSE where buyers and sellers compete in a centralized marketplace. The AMEX typically lists small

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies. Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis

Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies. Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis March 18, 2014 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the extent

More information

LIQUIDITY, STOCK RETURNS AND OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF THE BOMBAY STOCK EXCHANGE

LIQUIDITY, STOCK RETURNS AND OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF THE BOMBAY STOCK EXCHANGE LIQUIDITY, STOCK RETURNS AND OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF THE BOMBAY STOCK EXCHANGE Dr. Venkat R. Eleswarapu, and Dr. Chandrasekar Krishnamurti ABSTRACT We study the problem of illiquidity

More information

On the Conditioning of the Financial Market s Reaction to Seasoned Equity Offerings *

On the Conditioning of the Financial Market s Reaction to Seasoned Equity Offerings * The Lahore Journal of Economics 11 : 2 (Winter 2006) pp. 141-154 On the Conditioning of the Financial Market s Reaction to Seasoned Equity Offerings * Onur Arugaslan ** and Louise Miller *** Abstract Consistent

More information

Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange?

Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange? Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange? Wong Kie Ann a, John M. Sequeira a and Michael McAleer b a Department of Finance and Accounting, National University of Singapore

More information

The term structure of equity option implied volatility

The term structure of equity option implied volatility The term structure of equity option implied volatility Christopher S. Jones Tong Wang Marshall School of Business Marshall School of Business University of Southern California University of Southern California

More information

Interpretation of Financial Statements

Interpretation of Financial Statements Interpretation of Financial Statements Author Noel O Brien, Formation 2 Accounting Framework Examiner. An important component of most introductory financial accounting programmes is the analysis and interpretation

More information