Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality"

Transcription

1 Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality Sigrid Röhrs and Christoph Winter February 25, 2016 Abstract What are the welfare effects of government debt? In particular, what are the welfare consequences of government debt reductions? We answer these questions with the help of an incomplete markets economy with production. Households are subject to uninsurable income shocks. We make several contributions. First, when comparing stationary equilibria, we find that quantitatively sizable welfare gains can be achieved by reducing public debt. Second, when we also consider the transition between stationary equilibria, we find that the welfare costs of a debt reduction outweigh the benefits of being in a stationary equilibrium with lower debt. Third, by targeting the skewed wealth and earnings distribution of the US economy in our calibration, we identify inequality as a major driver of the welfare effects. Our results have important implications for the design of debt reduction policies. Since the skewed wealth distribution generates a large fraction of borrowingconstrained households, the public debt reduction should be non-linear, such that the tax burden is postponed into the future. Key words: Government Debt, Borrowing Limits, Incomplete Markets, Crowding Out JEL classification: E2, H6, D52 Acknowledgements: We would like to thank Marios Angeletos, Alexander Bick, Timo Boppart, Johannes Brumm, Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, Wouter den Haan, John Hassler, Marcus Hagedorn, Jonathan Heathcote, Kenneth Judd, Leo Kaas, Timothy Kehoe, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Felix Kübler, Alex Michaelides, Dirk Niepelt, Víctor Ríos-Rull, Karl Schmedders, Kjetil Storesletten, Iván Werning, Fabrizio Zilibotti, as well as participants of various seminars, in particular the SED 2014 in Toronto, for many useful suggestions. We particularly benefited from the input by Laura Zwyssig. Röhrs would like to thank the University of Zurich for financial support (Forschungskredit Nr ). Winter gratefully acknowledges financial support from the European Research Council (ERC Advanced Grant IPCDP ) and the National Centre of Competence in Research Financial Valuation and Risk Management (NCCR FINRISK). All remaining errors are our own. Parts of this project were previously circulated under the title Wealth Inequality and the Optimal Level of Government Debt. This paper represents the authors personal opinions and does not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank. Deutsche Bundesbank, Statistics Department, Wilhelm-Epstein-Strasse 14, Frankfurt am Main (Germany), +49 (0) , sigrid.roehrs@bundesbank.de (corresponding author) University of Zurich, Department of Economics, Office SOF-G-27, Schönberggasse 1, 8001 Zurich (Switzerland), +41 (0) , christoph.winter@econ.uzh.ch

2 1 Introduction Many countries - such as the United States - have experienced a dramatic surge in their public debt levels in the aftermath of the financial crisis. Drastic measures, including tax increases, need to be applied to bring government debt back to its pre-crisis level. 1 However, history has shown that austerity measures are very unpopular, and that their political implementation is difficult. As suggested by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), some countries have chosen to default on their sovereign debt even at moderate debt/gdp ratios in order to avoid painful austerity policies. Motivated by these observations, we study the welfare effects of reductions in government debt. In particular, we are interested in understanding how the welfare effects of public debt depend on inequality and the presence of borrowing constraints. We show that inequality and borrowing constraints are important determinants of the welfare effects across different stationary equilibria and over the transition. We conduct our analysis with the help of an incomplete markets framework in the tradition of Aiyagari (1994), following the seminal work of Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), Flodén (2001), and Desbonnet and Weitzenblum (2011), among others. Households are subject to idiosyncratic productivity shocks. These shocks are uninsurable because insurance markets are absent. Households can self-insure against adverse shocks by accumulating precautionary savings or by borrowing. In our framework, borrowing is limited. This restricts the ability of households to self-insure. This setting is ideal for our purposes for two reasons. First, government debt plays a non-trivial role if markets are incomplete and if borrowing is restricted. As it is well-known from the seminal work by Woodford (1990) and Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), government debt effectively relaxes borrowing constraints by increasing liquidity that can be used to smooth consumption if households hit the constraint. Therefore, government debt helps to complete markets. Issuing government debt might thus be an effective way to improve risk sharing and therefore also aggregate welfare (Flodén 2001, Shin 2006, Albanesi 2008). Second, the fact that markets are incomplete and risk-sharing is limited generates a non-trivial distribution of assets and consumption. One contribution of this project is to show that the degree of inequality implied by the model is crucial for the welfare effects of government debt. In order to generate a distribution of earnings and assets that resembles the skewed distributions of earnings and wealth in the US economy, we follow Castañeda, Díaz-Giménez, and Ríos-Rull (2003) in our calibration of the stochastic process that governs the evolution of idiosyncratic earning shocks. We find that the debt/gdp ratio that leads to the highest stationary equilibrium welfare is negative, i.e. the government should hold assets, not debt. This result is remarkable, given that the previous literature, most notably Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), Flodén (2001), and Desbonnet and Weitzenblum (2011), concludes that the debt/gdp ratio that maximizes social welfare in a stationary state is positive, not negative. As we will describe in greater detail below, the key difference between our approach and the previous literature is the calibration of the stochastic productivity process, which, in our case, generates a realistic degree of wealth and earnings inequality. In order to fully appreciate our findings and to understand how our outcome is influenced by inequal- 1 See Chen and Imrohoroglu (2015) for an overview over several proposals to reduce government debt that are discussed for the US. 1

3 ity, it is useful to first consider the role of borrowing constraints. If borrowing constraints are binding, lowering government debt crowds in private capital. This is because households that face binding borrowing constraints do not decrease their savings in response to a decrease in debt, and the Ricardian Equivalence proposition (as established by Barro 1974) breaks down. More specifically, under binding borrowing constraints, a decline in government bonds B generates a situation in which the aggregate (net) demand for bonds (denoted by A) by private households exceeds the total supply of bonds (given by K + B). Here, K denotes bonds supplied by private firms to finance physical capital, and B denotes bonds supplied by the government. In order to achieve market clearing, a lower interest rate r is required, which makes investment in physical capital K more attractive and therefore raises the supply of bonds. We say that reducing public debt crowds in private (physical) capital, and therefore also production and output. As a result, the marginal product of labor increases. Moreover, if taxation is distortionary instead of lump-sum, lower debt/gdp ratios are associated with even stronger positive effects on capital accumulation and output, since less government debt means lower taxes, which in turn reduces inefficiencies caused by distortionary taxes. To the extent that more capital and output translates into higher average consumption of goods and leisure, a lower debt/gdp ratio is welfare-improving. Following Flodén (2001), we label the impact of government debt on average consumption the level effect. Besides the level effect, changes in government debt give rise to other welfare effects, which operate through changes in aggregate prices. This relates our work to the papers by Azzimonti, de Francisco, and Krusell (2008), Davila et al. (2011), and Gottardi, Kajii, and Nakajima (2014), who also study the impact of factor price changes on welfare. 2 In our context, changes in aggregate prices affect welfare because markets are incomplete and households are heterogeneous. First, a decrease in the interest rate makes self-insurance more difficult for private households (Aiyagari and McGrattan 1998). Put differently, a decline in the interest rate implies that the price of the riskless production factor (capital) decreases, while the price of the risky factor (labor) increases. This insurance effect means that lower debt/gdp ratios have a negative effect on aggregate welfare. Second, government debt also affects the distribution of consumption via the composition of income. Households that receive capital income lose, whereas households that mainly rely on labor income benefit. Since the households that profit the most from the increase in wages are the consumption-poor, the income composition effect counteracts the negative impact of the insurance channel on aggregate welfare. Our results indicate that the relative importance of each of the three welfare channels depends on the calibration of the income process. Using the Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) earnings process, which generates too little wealth and earnings inequality, we show that the level effect of changes in government debt is weak. Since, in addition, the insurance and income composition effects offset each other, the overall welfare effects of government debt are also weak, in line with the findings of Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Flodén (2001). Instead, our income process gives rise to larger welfare effects of government debt. The fact that 2 Gottardi, Kajii, and Nakajima (2010) and Davila et al. (2011) analyze whether the laissez-faire outcome is constrained efficient if markets are incomplete. Gottardi, Kajii, and Nakajima (2010) and Davila et al. (2011) find that, depending on the structure of uncertainty, constrained efficiency requires a higher level of capital compared to the competitive equilibrium outcome when markets are incomplete. 2

4 the overall welfare effects of government debt are larger in our context is due to the fact that our income process generates a stronger level effect. Since our calibration generates more households at the borrowing constraint, it implies more crowding in of private capital. Hence, aggregate labor input becomes more productive when we decrease the debt/gdp ratio. In addition, the change in aggregate prices induced by the crowding in of private capital also leads to a tighter correlation of hours worked and individual productivity. As a consequence, aggregate productivity increases, which makes labor input even more productive. As a second contribution of our paper, we also analyze how inequality and the presence of borrowing constraints influence the welfare effects of government debt over the transition between two stationary equilibria. More specifically, we focus on debt reductions, i.e. we compute the welfare costs of moving to a stationary equilibrium that is characterized by lower public debt/gdp, relative to the initial stationary equilibrium. Our focus on debt reductions is in part motivated by our previous finding that stationary equilibria with lower public debt/gdp ratios offer more welfare. In addition, strategies to lower public debt are very prominent in the political debate. In particular, we focus on the impact of two important dimensions, namely the curvature of the debt/gdp path over the transition and the time span during which the debt/gdp ratio is reduced, on the welfare costs occurring over the transition. To shed more light on these issues, we compute the overall welfare effects, i.e. the sum of welfare over the transition and in the final stationary equilibrium, for a small and realistic unanticipated reduction of the debt/gdp ratio from 0.66, the long-run average of the US, to 0.6. We assume that this reduction is financed by increasing the (linear) personal income tax rate, therefore keeping the distortions on asset and labor supply constant. For all cases that we compute, we find that the transitional welfare costs associated with reducing government debt more than offset the long-run benefits of living in a stationary equilibrium with a lower debt/gdp ratio. This finding explains why debt reductions face so much political resistance, despite the fact that, according to our results, lower debt/gdp ratios are welfare-enhancing for the average household in the long run. 3 Interestingly, we show that the government can minimize the welfare costs occurring over the transition by following a concave debt/gdp path, for which the reduction is initially slow and accelerating over time. The welfare losses can be further reduced by extending the time horizon during which public debt is decreased. In order to understand the determinants of the transitional welfare effects, it is again important to consider the role of inequality. When choosing the curvature of the debt/gdp path, the government faces the following trade-off. On the one hand, a convex debt/gdp path offers the advantage of minimizing intertemporal distortions arising through asset income taxation. This is because a convex debt/gdp path implies that taxes are high at the beginning, when assets are pre-determined. On the other hand, households who are initially at the borrowing constraint prefer a concave debt/gdp path, for which the tax burden is initially low and increasing over time. The fact that in our calibration, consistent with the US economy, a substantial fraction of the population owns no assets or is in debt 3 Protests can be fierce, as documented by Ponticelli and Voth (2011), who found that fiscal consolidation increases the likelihood of social unrest, in the sense of an organized resistance to the government (riots, demonstrations, political assassinations, government crises, and attempted revolutions). 3

5 explains why the concave path is superior to a convex or a linear path. 4 In particular, our results about the importance of inequality for the transitional costs of debt reductions and inequality are consistent with the findings of D Erasmo and Mendoza (2015), who study the link between domestic inequality and the likelihood to default on domestic debt in an incomplete markets model. They show that inequality increases the probability of default. The previous literature has largely ignored welfare effects occurring over the transition altogether (see e.g. Aiyagari and McGrattan 1998 and Flodén 2001). An exception is the work by Desbonnet and Weitzenblum (2011), who, however, do not match the large degree of wealth inequality observed in the data, which makes their stationary equilibrium results very different from ours. Moreover, they restrict their analysis of the transition to linear debt/gdp paths. Different from us, their focus is on computing the debt/gdp ratio that maximizes total (transitional plus stationary equilibrium) welfare, whereas we are interested in analyzing the welfare consequences of debt reduction policies. We contribute to this strand of literature by showing that inequality is important for welfare effects of government debt in the transition and in stationary equilibrium. Apart from the aforementioned work, there are also other papers that study the effects of government debt in settings with incomplete markets. Gomes, Michaelides, and Polkovnichenko (2013) quantify the crowding out effect on the capital stock of a 10 percent increase in government debt in an incomplete market economy with aggregate risk. In a companion paper (Gomes, Michaelides, and Polkovnichenko 2012), the authors analyze the fiscal costs of the recent financial crisis in the US. Most recently, Azzimonti, de Francisco, and Quadrini (2014) study a multi-country setting in order to explain the link between two trends that have been observed during the last three decades, namely the global rise in public debt and the liberalization of financial markets. Our paper is also related to the work by Açikgöz (2014) and Dyrda and Pedroni (2015), who study the optimal Ramsey plan for a broad set of fiscal instruments in an environment with incomplete markets. In line with our findings, Açikgöz (2014) concludes the debt/gdp ratio that maximizes welfare in stationary equilibrium is negative. Similarly, Dyrda and Pedroni (2015) also find that the government should accumulate assets in the long run. Their results also indicate that, over the transition, it is optimal to tax capital income heavily, and to decrease labor income taxes in exchange. 5 Following Aiyagari (1995), models with incomplete markets have been widely applied to study various aspects of fiscal policy. The welfare effects of capital taxation are studied by Domeij and Heathcote (2004) and Conesa, Kitao, and Krueger (2009), whereas Heathcote (2005) analyzes the impact of tax changes on aggregate consumption. Bakis, Kaymak, and Poschke (2015), Krueger and Ludwig (2013), and Kindermann and Krueger (2014) analyze the implications of tax progressivity. Instead, Angeletos and Panousi (2009), Challe and Ragot (2010), and Oh and Reis (2012) analyze the implications of various types of government expenditures for economic activity. In a recent paper, Bachmann et al. (2015) analyze the welfare and distributional effects of fiscal uncertainty using a neoclassical stochastic growth 4 As a special case, we also consider the policy where the government unexpectedly raises the asset income tax in the initial period only. We find that in this case, government debt reductions lead to an overall welfare gain, which is however much smaller than the associated increase in stationary equilibrium welfare, implying that the transitional phase is still welfare-reducing. The reason is the existence of borrowing constraints. Because reducing public debt crowds in private capital, poor households, who depend largely on labor income, expect an increase in their income when public debt is decreased. As a result, they would like to borrow, which is only partially feasible. This leads to welfare losses. 5 Greulich, Laczó, and Marcet (2015) come to similar conclusions in an environment with complete markets. 4

6 model with incomplete markets. They show that the welfare gains of eliminating fiscal uncertainty decline with private wealth holdings. Their findings therefore also highlight the importance of matching inequality for understanding the consequences of fiscal policy. None of the aforementioned papers explicitly characterizes the welfare consequences of debt reductions in stationary state and over the transition. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. We present the baseline model in the next section. In Section 3 we discuss the calibration of the model. Section 4 shows the quantitative results, and Section 5 concludes. 2 The Baseline Model The economy we consider is a neoclassical growth model with incomplete markets where households face uninsurable income shocks, as in Aiyagari (1994). The economy consists of three sectors: households, firms, and a government. In the following, we describe the three sectors in greater detail. 2.1 Household Sector The economy is populated by a continuum of ex-ante identical, infinitely lived households with total mass of one. Households maximize their expected utility by making a series of consumption, c t, labor, l t, and savings, a t+1, choices subject to a budget constraint and a borrowing limit on assets. In period t = 0, before any uncertainty has realized, their expected utility is given by: U({c t, 1 l t } t=1,2,... ) = E 0 t=0 β t u(c t, 1 l t ) (1) where β is the subjective discount factor. The per-period utility function, u(.), is assumed to be strictly increasing, strictly concave, and continuously differentiable in both arguments. Each household faces the following per-period budget constraint: c t + a t+1 = y t + a t (2) where a t+1 denotes the bond holdings of the household. y t is the household s (after-tax) income from labor and bonds. y t depends, among other things, on the realization of a household-specific productivity shock, denoted by ɛ t. We assume that ɛ t follows a Markov process with transition matrix π(ɛ t ɛ t 1 ). Before we are able to fully characterize y t, we need to describe the economy s tax system, which will be done when we introduce the government s problem below. Due to the presence of uninsurable productivity shocks, households self-insure against income fluctuations by saving in one-period risk-free bonds. Bonds can be issued by firms, the government, and other households ( IOUs ). Bonds issued by firms are claims to physical capital K t. We abstract from aggregate risk, which implies that all bonds are perfect substitutes, independent of the issuer, since they yield the same return, which we denote by 1 + r t. 6 If households issue bonds, a t+1 becomes negative. Households then borrow. Compared to Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Flodén (2001), we view this as an important modification, given that the 6 In Gomes, Michaelides, and Polkovnichenko (2012, 2013), government bonds and private capital are imperfect substitutes due to aggregate uncertainty. 5

7 fraction of households that actually borrow in the data is substantial. For example, in the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), 24 percent of all households have a net financial asset position that is either zero or negative. We assume that borrowing is restricted: a t+1 a (3) In addition, we assume that the borrowing limit a is tighter than the natural borrowing limit, implying that it is binding for a certain fraction of the population. The optimization problem of a household is given by the following functional equation: { } W t (a, ɛ) = max c,l,a u(c, 1 l) + β ɛ π(ɛ ɛ)w t+1 (a, ɛ ) s.t. c + a = y + a (5) a a The households problem is time-dependent because we do not only study stationary states but also transitions between them. 7 (4) 2.2 Firm Sector There is a continuum of firms operating a production technology that features constant returns to scale. Firms take prices on all markets as given. In competitive equilibrium, the number of firms is then indeterminate, and we can assume the existence of a representative firm. The representative firm produces output, Y t, by combining aggregate capital, K t, and aggregate labor, N t : Y t = F (K t, X t N t ) (6) where X t denotes exogenous labor-augmenting technological progress. Technological progress grows at a constant rate g > 0, such that X t+1 = (1 + g)x t. By assuming that initial technology is given by X 0 = 1, the law of motion of X t simplifies to X t = (1 + g) t. In order to obtain a stationary environment, we detrend all variables by dividing through Y t. The detrended variables are denoted using a tilde, e.g. Kt Kt Y t. In Appendix A, we outline the detrended version of the households problem. There, we also illustrate that technological progress reduces the effective discount factor, therefore implying that in the presence of technological progress, households are less willing to save. 2.3 Government Sector We start by describing the balance sheet of the government. The government has to finance (exogenous) spending, G t, transfers to households, denoted by T R t, and interest payments for its outstanding debt, which are given by r t B t. The government can raise income by issuing new government bonds, B t+1, and by taxing income from assets and labor. 7 Notice that as long we focus on the transition between stationary states, the dynamic programming problem of the household falls into the class of stationary dynamic programming problems, for which the principle of optimality is satisfied. We numerically show that our economy converges to a new stationary state. 6

8 More specifically, the tax system consists of proportional taxes on asset income, τ k,t, a proportional tax on labor income, τ l,t, and a lump-sum transfer, χ t. The results are affine taxes, which are a very good approximation to the US tax code, according to Figure 1 in Bhandari et al. (2013). Proportional tax rates are given by a baseline component which is equal to the labor income tax rate, τ t = τ l,t, and a premium on the asset income tax rate, ζ, such that τ k,t = ζτ t. In our experiments, we will only vary the baseline component τ t, keeping the premium on the asset income tax fixed. Furthermore, we assume that only households with positive asset holdings are subject to the asset income tax, meaning that households in debt do not receive transfers that are proportional to their debt. More precisely, we define the tax rate on asset income τ k,t as follows: { τk,t if a 0 τ k,t (a) = 0 if a < 0 The after-tax interest rate is therefore given by r t = (1 τ k,t (a))r t. The after-tax wage rate is given by w t = (1 τ l,t )w t, where w t is the price of labor in the economy. Total after-tax income is thus given by: The government budget constraint then reads as: y t = w t ɛl t + r t a t + χ t (8) G t + r t B t + T r t = B t+1 B t + τ l w t N t + τ k r t  t (9) where Ât A t is the tax base for the asset income tax. Since taxes are levied only on positive financial income, the tax base is defined as:  t = a 0 (7) adθ t (ɛ, a) (10) where θ t (ɛ, a) denotes the distribution of households over income and asset states. Aggregate transfers equal the sum of all individual transfers: χ t dθ t (ɛ, a) = T r t (11) Since the mass of households is normalized to one, and since χ t is a lump-sum transfer that is independent of the distribution of households θ t (ɛ, a), individual transfers and aggregate transfers are identical: χ t = T r t. Along a balanced growth path equilibrium, aggregate capital K t, aggregate consumption C t, government consumption G t, public debt B t, aggregate transfers T R t, the aggregate tax base Ât, and the wage rate w t grow at the same constant rate g, while r and L are constant. Aggregate transfers are given by T R t = χ t dθ(a, ɛ), and the aggregate tax base is determined by Āt = a t dθ(a, ɛ). This implies that the detrended versions of these variables, namely K, C, G, B, T R, Â, and w are constant. We can then write the stationary version of the government s budget constraint as follows: a 0 G + (r g) B + T R = τ l wn + τ k r  (12) The stationary version of the government s budget constraint will become important for the calibration of our economy. Note that even when we compute the transition between two stationary equilibria, we keep the government spending/output ratio G and transfer/output ratio T R constant. This allows us to focus on the welfare effects of government debt and the timing of the (linear) taxes. 7

9 2.4 Competitive Equilibrium Using the characterization of the three sectors we can now define the competitive equilibrium. Definition 1. Competitive Equilibrium: Given a transition matrix π, a government policy {B t, τ t, G} t=0, and an initial distribution of the idiosyncratic productivity shocks and of the asset holdings θ 0 (ɛ, a), a recursive competitive equilibrium is defined by a law of motion Γ, factor prices {r t, w t } t=0, a sequence of value functions {W t } t=0, and a sequence of policy functions {c t, l t, a t} t=0 such that 1. Households solve the utility maximization problem as defined in equation (4). 2. Competitive firms maximize profits, such that factor prices are given by: w t = F L (K t, X t N t ) (13) r t = F K (K t, X t N t ) δ (14) 3. The government budget constraint as defined in equation (12) holds. 4. Factor and goods markets have to clear: Labor market: N t = ɛl t dθ t (ɛ, a) (15) Asset market: A t+1 = a tdθ t (ɛ, a) = K t+1 + B t+1 (16) Goods market: c t dθ t (ɛ, a) + G t + I t = F (K t, X t N t ) (17) where investment I is given by: I K (1 δ)k (18) 5. Rational expectations of households about the law of motion of the distribution of shocks and asset holdings, Γ, reflect the true law of motion, as given by: θ t+1 (a, ɛ) = Γ[θ t (a, ɛ)] (19) where θ t (a, ɛ) denotes the joint distribution of asset holdings and productivity shocks. 2.5 Welfare Measure In order to be able to compare the welfare effects of different government policies, we have to define a welfare criterion. Following the previous literature, as for example, Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Flodén (2001), we compute the aggregate value function: Ω t = W t (a, ɛ)dθ t (a, ɛ) (20) This criterion can either be interpreted as (1) a Utilitarian social welfare function where every individual has the same weight for the planner, (2) a steady-state ex-ante welfare of an average consumer before 8

10 realizing income shocks and initial asset holdings, or (3) the probability limit of the utility of an infinitely lived dynasty where households utilities are altruistically linked to each other. In order to facilitate the interpretation, we compute the average welfare change in consumptionequivalent units, i.e. the consumption that needs to be given to each household in order to make households indifferent on average between two specific policies. 8 More details are provided in Appendix B. 3 Calibration We calibrate the model such that it is consistent with long-run features of the US economy. The resulting allocation serves as a benchmark for our welfare calculations. Table 1 summarizes our parameter choices, which will be discussed in greater detail in the following subsections. 3.1 Utility Function and Production Technology Utility function. We assume that preferences can be represented by a constant relative risk aversion utility function: u(c, 1 l) = (cη (1 l) 1 η ) 1 µ 1 µ µ determines the curvature of the utility function. We set µ to 2. η denotes the share of consumption in the utility function. We calibrate η such that the average share of time worked, denoted by l, is equal to 0.3. This results in η = Our parameter choices for µ and η imply that the coefficient of risk aversion and the (average) Frisch elasticity of labor supply are both equal to (21) The coefficient of risk aversion is well in the range (between 1 and 3) commonly chosen in the literature. The Frisch elasticity is broadly in line with the outcome of other macro models in which the Frisch elasticity of the overall population is considered, but an order of magnitude larger than the Frisch elasticity estimated using micro data from prime age workers only. 10 Before we proceed, a remark regarding the utility function is in order. Our specification is adopted from Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998). It is consistent with the existence of a balanced growth path. This requires that labor supply is subject to a wealth effect, such that hours worked remain constant, despite the fact that wages are permanently growing along a balanced growth path. This wealth effect will have consequences for some of our results discussed below. In particular, it implies that the distribution of hours worked is inconsistent with the empirical evidence, see e.g. Castañeda, Díaz-Giménez, and Ríos-Rull (2003). In the data, hours worked vary little, at least if one considers prime-aged individuals who work positive hours (see e.g. Pijoan-Mas 8 More precisely, this measure provides the percentage increase in benchmark consumption at every date and state (with leisure at every date and state held fixed at benchmark values) that leads to the same welfare (under the benchmark policy) as under the new policy. 9 For our specification of the utility function, the coefficient of risk aversion is given by 1 η + ηµ = 1.3. The Frisch elasticity of labor supply is given by (1 η + ηµ)/µ (T l)/ l, where T denotes the time endowment (normalized to 1 in our case) and l denotes the average fraction of time spend at work, in our case The debate on whether micro and macro elasticities are consistent is ongoing. See Keane and Rogerson (2011) for a summary. 9

11 Table 1: Parameter Choices Parameter Value Target Data Model A. Parameters set exogenously Capital s share, α Growth rate, g Public Debt/output, B Labor income tax, τ l Asset income tax, τ a Transfers/output, χ Curvature utility function, µ Depreciation rate, δ B. Parameters calibrated Discount factor, β 0.96 Wealth/income ratio Weight of consumption in the utility function, η 0.31 Average labor supply Borrowing limit, ã -0.3 Fraction of households with assets Vector of income states, s see text Wealth and earnings distribution see Table 2 Markov transition matrix, Π see text Wealth and earnings distribution see Table 2 Remarks: see main text for more details on the sources of parameters that are set exogenously and for calibration procedure of remaining parameters. 2006). Instead, the wealth effect inherent in our preferences commands that affluent households work less and enjoy their time in form of leisure. 11 The model results for average hours worked by earnings quintile can be found in the Online Appendix. 12 Technology. We now turn to the aggregate technology. We assume that it is given by a Cobb- Douglas production function: F (K, XN) = K α (XN) 1 α (22) Initial technology is normalized to X 0 = 1, such that X t = (1 + g) t. We set g = 0.02, which implies that our economy grows at a rate of 2 percent per year. The parameter α, which denotes the share of capital in total production, is set to 0.3. This implies a labor share of 0.7. The discount factor β is chosen such that the model reproduces a wealth/income ratio of 3.2, in line with e.g. Cooley and Prescott (1995) or Ábrahám and Cárceles-Poveda (2010).13 Finally, we set the annual depreciation rate δ to 7 percent, which is a common value in the literature (see e.g. Trabandt and Uhlig 2011). 11 We are grateful to the referees for pointing this out. 12 The Online Appendix can be downloaded here: 13 As we will explain in the subsection about the calibration of the income process, we define wealth as net financial assets. We measure the distribution of net financial assets in the 2007 SCF. As we will explain in the next subsection, compared to the 2007 SCF, our calibration generates too little wealth holdings at the very top of the distribution. We therefore pick 3.2 as a target for the wealth/income ratio, although the wealth/income ratio in the 2007 SCF is higher (3.7). 10

12 3.2 Taxes, Transfers and Government Debt We now describe our choices for the tax rates, the transfers/gdp ratio, and the public debt/gdp ratio. Following Trabandt and Uhlig (2011), we set the labor income tax rate, τ l, to 0.28 and the asset income tax rate, τ k, to This implies that the baseline component of our tax system is τ l = τ = The relative premium of the asset income tax is ζ τ k τ = The values for τ l and τ k describe the average (effective) tax rate on labor and capital income, respectively. They are computed from national income and product accounts (NIPA) for the US by dividing tax receipts from labor (capital) income by total labor (capital) income, as described in Mendoza, Razin, and Tesar (1994). 14 Trabandt and Uhlig (2011) update the results of Mendoza, Razin, and Tesar (1994) for the period of 1995 to They find similar values, which suggests that average effective tax rates are stable over time. We set the benchmark debt/gdp ratio, B, to 0.66, following Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), who define public debt as the postwar average of the sum of US federal and state debt. According to Trabandt and Uhlig (2011), average public debt/gdp was 0.63 for the period between 1995 and 2007, indicating that the debt/gdp ratio was roughly constant over time, at least prior to the recent financial crisis. Lump-sum transfers/gdp, χ, are set to 0.083, in accordance with both Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Trabandt and Uhlig (2011), which again suggests that this ratio is fairly stable over time. In the data, transfers are calculated implicitly by subtracting government investment, interest rate expenditures, and government consumption from total expenditures, see Trabandt and Uhlig (2011). Finally, government spending/gdp, G, is the residual of the government s budget constraint (12). In our model, a value of G = 0.15 is needed in order to ensure a balanced budget. The appropriate empirical counterpart for G is the ratio of the sum of government consumption and investment to GDP. Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Bachmann et al. (2015) report a ratio of government consumption and investment over GDP of 0.21 for the postwar period. Trabandt and Uhlig (2011) find a value of 0.18 for the period between 1975 and In either case, G, as implied by our model, is smaller than its empirical counterpart. One reason could be that in our model, we abstract from consumption taxes. Allowing for consumption taxes (in addition to taxing labor and capital income) would increase total tax revenues, and would therefore allow the government to sustain a higher G. 3.3 Income Process We calibrate the vector s of productivity realizations ɛ and the corresponding transition matrix Π such that distributions of earnings and net financial assets generated by the model match their counterparts in the 2007 SCF. Our approach follows Castañeda, Díaz-Giménez, and Ríos-Rull (2003). It is in part motivated by the fact that for standard parameterizations of the earnings process, incomplete markets models in the tradition of Aiyagari (1994) generate too little wealth inequality, compared to the data (see e.g. Quadrini and Ríos-Rull 1997 or more recently Quadrini and Ríos-Rull 2015). Before we describe the calibration of the earnings process in greater detail, we explain how we measure wealth and earnings. In our model, households accumulate assets to self-insure against idiosyncratic productivity shocks. We should therefore target those wealth holdings in the data that are accumulated for precautionary reasons as well. For this reason, we define wealth as net financial assets. More specifi- 14 See Lucas (1990) for an early application of this approach. 11

13 cally, following Ábrahám and Cárceles-Poveda (2010), we calculate net financial assets by excluding the value of residential property, vehicles, and direct business ownership from total assets, and the value of secured debt due to mortgages and vehicle loans from total liabilities. 15 In other words, we exclude those assets that are subject to adjustment costs and that are likely to serve a different role other than to transfer resources across time and states, such as housing and vehicles. Their adjustment is costly. Moreover, they are also used as consumption goods. Instead, financial assets can be readily sold to smooth out adverse productivity shocks. 16 Earnings are defined as labor earnings (wages and salaries) plus a fraction of business income before taxes, excluding government transfers. This definition corresponds to the concept of earnings that is implied by our model. The distribution of earnings and net financial assets is computed from the 2007 SCF. 17 Table 2 shows that both earnings and net financial assets are very unequally distributed in the data. The richest 20 percent of the population hold more than 90 percent of all financial assets, net of debt. The distribution of earnings is less skewed. Households in the top quintile earn around 60 percent of the total earnings. We now turn to the details of our calibration procedure. Our strategy is to choose the vector s of productivity realizations ɛ and the corresponding transition matrix Π such that distributions of earnings and net financial assets generated by the model match their respective distributions in the 2007 SCF. More specifically, for each unknown parameter, we pick one moment from the empirical Lorenz curve of either earnings or net financial assets. Since we assume that there are four productivity states, the corresponding transition matrix Π has 16 entries. We then normalize the mean of the productivity states to one. Because the transition probabilities in each row of Π have to sum up to one, we are left with 15 unknown parameters in total, 12 unknown transition probabilities and 3 unknown productivity states. As targets, we choose the five quintiles and the Gini coefficients of the earnings distribution and the net financial asset distribution. We additionally target the top 10%, 5%, and 1% percentile of the distribution of net financial assets, in order to take into account that net financial assets are very unequally distributed within the upper quintile. However, we assign less weight to these targets, since the extremely skewed distribution of net financial assets makes it very difficult to match the top percentiles. This issue is well-known, see for example Table 14.6 in Quadrini and Ríos-Rull (2015), which shows that other calibrations targeting the Lorenz curve of wealth also have difficulties to match the extreme right tail of the distribution. The 15 unknown parameters are then jointly chosen to match the 15 empirical moments. 15 In terms of SCF variables, we calculate net financial assets as follows: Net Financial Assets = FIN - DEBT + MRTHEL + RESDBT + VEHINST. 16 To what extent housing and consumption durables (and other illiquid assets) are used for consumption smoothing purposes is subject to an ongoing debate. See Fernández-Villaverde and Krueger (2011) and Kaplan and Violante (2010). Kaplan and Violante (2014) find that a significant fraction of those households that possess a large amount of net worth do not liquidate their assets due to transaction costs in response to temporary shocks and rather live hand-to-mouth, which suggests that illiquid assets are not used to smooth consumption. See Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante (2009) for a summary of the debate and additional references. 17 The SCF does not specify the exact fraction of total business income that is attributable to labor and to capital. We define business income from sole proprietorship or a farm as labor earnings, whereas business income from other businesses or investments, net rent, trusts, or royalties is defined as capital income. 12

14 Table 2: Distribution of Net Financial Assets and Earnings, 2007 SCF and Benchmark Stationary Equilibrium Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 upper 10% upper 5% upper 1% Gini A. Net financial assets Data 1.60% 0.10% 1.64% 8.29% 91.57% 79.64% 66.83% 39.09% 0.90 Benchmark Calibration 1.57% 0.88% 3.92% 7.23% 89.54% 70.58% 47.03% 13.53% 0.83 B. Earnings Data 0.40% 3.19% 12.49% 23.33% 61.39% Benchmark Calibration 0.00% 2.38% 12.58% 22.73% 62.31% Remarks: Quintiles (Q1-Q5) denote net financial assets (resp. earnings) of a group in percent of total net financial assets (resp. earnings). For the wealth distribution, in addition to the quintiles the table also shows the percent of net financial assets held by the wealthiest 10% (upper 10%), 5% (upper 5%), and 1% (upper 1%). The entries in data are computed from the 2007 SCF. See main text for precise definitions. Notice that earnings can be negative due to the fact that labor earnings also contain part of the gains (or losses) of small enterprises. As a result, we find the following vector of income states: s = {0.055, 0.551, 1.195, 7.351} It should be noted that the highest income state is more than 130 times as high as the lowest income state. Furthermore, we get the following transition matrix for the income states: Π = As indicated by the transition matrix, there is a 10 percent probability of moving from the highest productivity state today to the lowest productivity state tomorrow, which is associated with a large drop in earnings. This, in turn, generates a strong saving motive for income-rich households. The fact that income-rich households have both the opportunity and the incentive to accumulate large savings drives the unequal distribution of net financial assets in the model. Although the combination of specific values is somewhat arbitrary, the general mechanism is informative about how extreme actual saving motives and opportunities need to be in order to generate the observable distribution of net financial assets for the US economy only by self-insurance (Quadrini and Ríos-Rull 2015) Inequality might be partly determined by other factors that we abstract from such as entrepreneurship (Quadrini 1999 or Cagetti and De Nardi 2006), discount factor heterogeneity (as in Krusell and Smith 1998), life-cycle savings (see e.g. Huggett 1996), or non-homothetic bequest motives (as in De Nardi 2004). Gourinchas and Parker (2002) argue that a large fraction of non-pension wealth (up to 70 percent) in the US can be attributed to precautionary savings. As a robustness check, we repeated the first part of our welfare analysis (comparison of stationary equilibria associated with different public debt/gdp ratios) using the Krusell and Smith (1998) approach. Preliminary results, which are available from the authors upon request, suggest that our findings are qualitatively robust to using this very different approach of generating inequality. 13

15 3.4 Borrowing Limit We calibrate the borrowing limit to match the percentage of households with negative or zero financial assets in the 2007 SCF (24 percent). 19 We find a borrowing limit of ã = 0.3, which means that households can borrow up to 30 percent of output that is produced in the benchmark economy. 4 Results We are now ready to compute the welfare effects of reductions in government debt. We distinguish between transition (in the following also labeled as short run) and stationary equilibrium (in the following also labeled as long run). We proceed in two steps. First, we analyze the welfare consequences of government debt reductions in stationary equilibrium. This is done by comparing stationary equilibria that are characterized by different debt/gdp ratios, keeping all other parameters constant. In order to keep the budget of the government balanced, we adjust taxes such that the relative distortions between capital and labor, denoted by ζ, remain constant. We find that in the long run, debt reductions are associated with welfare gains. In a second step, we also incorporate the welfare effects that occur over the transition between a high-debt stationary equilibrium to a low-debt equilibrium. We find that the costs of debt reductions occurring over the transition can be substantial, depending on the policy. The short-run costs of debt reductions can easily outweigh the long-run gains. 4.1 Effects of Public Debt in Stationary Equilibrium In this section, we compute the long-run welfare-maximizing debt/gdp ratio in our economy. Our analysis is motivated by the fact that in the textbook neoclassical model with lump-sum taxes, government debt is neutral and therefore has no impact on welfare. In a seminal paper, Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) showed that in the presence of borrowing constraints and in the absence of complete markets, government debt has non-trivial welfare effects. Two quantitative results from their paper have been very influential for the following research. First, Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) argue that the debt/gdp ratio that maximizes long-run welfare is around 2/3, which is also the historical average of debt/gdp in the US economy. Second, they find that welfare effects of deviations from the long-run historical average are small. We show that these two conclusions drastically change in our calibration. In Figure 1, we plot the aggregate welfare changes for stationary equilibria for different public debt/gdp ratios, relative to the benchmark in which debt amounts to 2/3 of GDP. Figure 1 conveys a clear message: according to our calibration, stationary equilibria with lower debt/gdp ratios offer more aggregate welfare, compared to the benchmark. In our economy, the debt/gdp ratio maximizing long-run welfare is 0.8. Moreover, relative to the welfare function computed by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), our welfare function is much steeper around the long-run historical average debt/gdp ratio. In the following, we analyze the driving forces behind the long-run welfare effects of changes in government debt in an Aiyagari (1994) style incomplete markets model in greater detail. 19 Using the 2004 SCF, Ábrahám and Cárceles-Poveda (2010) find that percent of households have negative or zero financial assets. This suggests that the this fraction is stable over time. To what extent our model generates a plausible number of borrowing-constrained households will be discussed in Footnote

16 1 0.8 Our Model Aiyagari/McGrattan Welfare Change in Consumption Equivalents (in %) Public Debt/GDP Figure 1: Comparing Welfare Between Different Stationary Equilibria. In this exercise we plot the welfare change in consumption-equivalent units implied by our baseline calibration (on the ordinate) for different stationary equilibria that differ with respect to the public debt/gdp ratio (on the abscissa), relative to the benchmark in which public debt amounts to 2/3 of GDP (green diamond and vertical line). Two cases: (1) Our Baseline Economy (blue crosses); (2) Aiyagari and McGrattan s economy (black circles). The long-run welfare effects of government debt result from the interaction between public debt and private capital. The interplay between public debt and private capital accumulation is a consequence of the fact that the borrowing constraint a is exogenous and fixed. Because of this, an increase in government debt crowds out private capital accumulation by effectively relaxing the borrowing limit (Woodford 1990, Aiyagari and McGrattan 1998). 20 For our baseline calibration, the effect of public debt on private capital (private savings minus public debt) can be seen in Figure 2, where we depict assets (i.e. aggregate private savings) and the capital stock, relative to GDP. Higher public debt/gdp ratios decrease capital. This means that the increase in assets demanded by households cannot compensate for the increase in assets supplied by the government. The reverse also holds. If government debt is reduced, the capital stock is crowded in. Households do not reduce their asset holdings as much as the government reduces its debt. As a result, the capital stock increases. If the capital stock in the baseline calibration is below its efficient level, the crowding in of capital increases welfare, all other things equal. In a recent paper, Davila et al. (2011) show that in an environment in which markets are incomplete, inequality, in particular the nature of the income risk as well as the composition of income for the consumption-poor, is an important determinant of the constrained efficient capital stock. Davila et al. (2011) show that if the earnings process is calibrated as in Castañeda, Díaz-Giménez, and Ríos-Rull (2003) - the method that we employ in this paper - the constrained efficient capital stock is much higher than its laissez-faire level. This finding is in line with our result that government debt reductions increase the private capital stock and raise welfare. 20 We study the relationship between public debt and borrowing limits in a separate paper, see Röhrs and Winter (2015). In the other project, we also allow for endogenous borrowing limits that result from a limited commitment problem. 15

17 Capital/Benchmark GDP Public Debt/GDP Assets/Benchmark GDP Public Debt/GDP 2 2 Income before taxes (GDP) Income after taxes Public Debt/GDP Public Debt/GDP Figure 2: Capital, Assets, Income Before Taxes, Income After Taxes. This figure shows the changes in selected aggregate economic variables (on the ordinate) for different stationary equilibria that differ with respect to the public debt/gdp ratio (on the abscissa). In the benchmark, public debt amounts to 2/3 of GDP (green diamond and vertical line). All variables relative to GDP in the benchmark. The interplay between government debt and private capital affects welfare through three channels, which we describe in more detail in the following. 21 Level effect: Lower government debt/gdp ratios lead to more private capital and therefore to more production (see the lower panel in Figure 2). To the extent that more capital and output translates into higher average consumption of goods and leisure, a lower debt/gdp ratio is welfare-improving. Following Flodén (2001), we label the impact of government debt on average leisure-compensated consumption the level effect. In general, we expect the level effect to be non-linear. Flodén (2001) finds that the level effect is concave around the benchmark debt/gdp ratio. Since we use a different calibration of the earnings process, which is closer to Davila et al. (2011), we would expect that lower debt/gdp ratios (and hence more private capital), relative to the benchmark, are welfare-enhancing, at least to some extent. 21 Our classification follows Flodén (2001). For more details, see Appendix C. 16

18 Insurance effect: There are two channels through which a decline in government debt affects households ability to self-insure. First, a decrease in public debt means that households effectively face tighter borrowing limits, because there is less liquidity that can be used to smooth consumption if households hit the constraint. Moreover, because reducing government debt crowds in private capital, we observe a decrease in the interest rate r and an increase in the wage rate w (see Figure 3). This, by itself, increases the opportunity costs of households to self-insure against adverse productivity shocks. Put differently, precautionary saving becomes more costly. Interest Rate Public Debt/GDP Wage Rate Public Debt/GDP Figure 3: Interest Rate and Wage Rate. This figure shows the changes in equilibrium prices for capital and labor (on the ordinate) for different stationary equilibria that differ with respect to the public debt/gdp ratio (on the abscissa). In the benchmark, public debt amounts to 2/3 of GDP (green diamond and vertical line). In addition, a fall in the interest rate and an increase in the wage rate increases uncertainty in total income, all other things equal. Imagine a household who receives income from labor and capital and who does not change its labor supply and its asset position. This household will experience an increase in uncertainty of total income since the weight of the uncertain income component, namely labor income, is increased relative to capital income, which is certain in our economy. 22 As a result of higher uncertainty regarding total income, uncertainty about consumption is amplified as well, and households experience an ex-ante welfare loss. Note that capital income is only certain in our economy because we abstract from aggregate risk. Gomes, Michaelides, and Polkovnichenko (2008) analyze the impact of changes in government debt in a framework with infinitely-lived households, idiosyncratic and aggregate uncertainty. They argue that the presence of aggregate uncertainty amplifies the impact of changes in public debt on private capital and the interest rate. Income composition effect: A reduction in government debt/gdp implies that the interest rate r falls, while the wage rate w increases. As a consequence of these price changes, asset owners experience, on average, a loss in their income if there is more government debt, while those households who primarily depend on labor income, experience a gain. We call this the income composition effect. It is important 22 Note that the aggregate income shares of capital and labor are constant, given our Cobb-Douglas specification. We are grateful to a referee for pointing this out. 17

19 to notice that the income composition effect would also exist if consumption was certain, in which case the insurance effect of government debt changes would be absent. In sum, a reduction in government debt affects aggregate welfare in the long run via a level effect, an insurance channel, and through the composition of individual income. The impact of the level effect on aggregate welfare is ambiguous. The income composition effect implies that lower debt/gdp increases aggregate welfare, whereas the insurance effect implies that welfare decreases for lower debt/gdp ratios. The relative strength of each channel depends on the degree of wealth and income inequality in the economy. In the following paragraph, we will decompose the total welfare effect into its subcomponents. Decomposition of Total Welfare Change. We now decompose the total welfare effect of public debt into its subcomponents level, insurance, and income composition effect. In order to do so, we use the procedure outlined by Flodén (2001), who in turn builds on work by Benabou (2002). The technical details of this decomposition can be found in Appendix C. Since we are particularly interested in understanding the contribution of our earnings process, we conduct the following experiment. We compute aggregate welfare changes for two different economies, namely for our baseline economy and for a modified version of it, in which we replace our earnings process by the AR(1) process used in Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998). 23 We re-calibrate the modified economy such that it is consistent with all targets of our baseline calibration (with the exception of wealth and earnings inequality). For both economies, we then decompose the total welfare effect of government debt changes into the level, insurance, and income composition effect. The results of this decomposition are shown in Figure 4. A comparison of the two economies reveals that the aggregate welfare function of government debt for the economy with the Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) (panel to the right) earnings process is substantially flatter. Consequently, the public debt/gdp ratio that maximizes long-run welfare is larger (at around 0.5 instead of 0.8). Figure 4 indicates sizable differences in the level effect between the two calibrations. In particular, our economy generates a stronger level effect for public debt/gdp ratios below the long-run average. According to Flodén (2001), the level effect measures the change in (leisure-compensated) consumption of the average household following a change in government debt. Our results therefore imply that a reduction of public debt/gdp raises the leisure-compensated consumption of the average household by more if we use our income process instead of the income process employed by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998). Leisure-compensated consumption, in turn, is determined by output (minus depreciation), relative to hours worked (Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante 2008). Since we use the same depreciation rates in the two experiments depicted in Figure 4, differences in the level effect must therefore be due to differences in the response of output/hours worked ratio across the two calibrations. In other words, our results indicate that if we use our income process, a reduction of government debt/gdp, relative to the long-run average, has a more pronounced effect on labor productivity. In the following, we want to shed more light on the relationship between changes in public debt and labor productivity, which ultimately explains the relationship between government debt and leisurecompensated consumption, i.e. the level effect. We are particularly interested in understanding how this relationship is influenced by the calibration of the income process. To be more precise, recall that 23 Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) assume a persistence parameter of 0.6 and a standard deviation of innovations of

20 10 Benchmark Economy Aiyagari/McGrattan (1998) earnings process 10 Welfare Change in Consumption Equivalents (in %) Public Debt/GDP Welfare Change in Consumption Equivalents (in %) Public Debt/GDP Zero line Total Welfare Change Level Effect Insurance Effect Income Composition Effect Figure 4: Welfare Decomposition. We plot the welfare change in consumption equivalent units implied by our baseline calibration (on the ordinate, left panel) and the baseline calibration where we replace our earnings process with the AR(1) process of Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) (on the ordinate, right panel) for various stationary equilibria that differ with respect to the public debt/gdp ratio (on the abscissa), relative to the benchmark in which public debt amounts to 2/3 of GDP. We decompose total welfare (black solid line) into a level effect (blue line with crosses), an income composition effect (green line with circles), and an insurance effect (red line with squares). in our setting, total output Y is determined by Y = K α (XN) 1 α, where K denotes aggregate capital and N denotes total (effective) labor supply, which, in equilibrium, is given by N = ɛldθ(ɛ, a). For simplicity, we will ignore the role of the labor-augmenting technology progress X in our analysis, thereby implicitly assuming that X = 1. It follows that aggregate labor productivity, defined as average output per hours worked or Y ldθ(ɛ,a), depends on aggregate capital K and the strength of the correlation between ɛ and l at the household level. The correlation can therefore influence the size of N (see Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante 2008), even if aggregate hours worked ldθ(ɛ, a) remain constant. To make things more precise, consider a tightening of the correlation between ɛ and l, in the sense that households that are subject to favorable productivity shocks increase their labor supply, whereas those that are subject to adverse productivity shocks reduce their hours worked. As we will see in greater detail below, such a change in the correlation between ɛ and l can be caused by a change in government debt (specifically, by the effect the change in public debt has on aggregate prices w and r). Let us further assume that only the distribution of hours worked changes, so that total hours worked remain constant. Due to the fact that more productive households increase their labor supply, whereas less productive households reduce their hours worked, we observe an increase in N, even though aggregate hours worked ldθ(ɛ, a) do not change. As a consequence, both aggregate labor and capital become more productive, indicated by the fact that both Y ldθ(ɛ,a) and Y K increase. Therefore, as long as ldθ(ɛ, a) is constant, changes in N can be viewed as affecting total factor productivity. In sum, to 19

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality Sigrid Röhrs and Christoph Winter July 18, 2014 Abstract What are the welfare effects of government debt? In particular, what are the welfare consequences

More information

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality Sigrid Röhrs and Christoph Winter February 4, 214 Abstract What are the welfare consequences of debt reduction policies? In this paper, we answer

More information

Uninsured Entrepreneurial Risk and Public Debt Policies

Uninsured Entrepreneurial Risk and Public Debt Policies Uninsured Entrepreneurial Risk and Public Debt Policies Sumudu Kankanamge a 1 a Paris School of Economics, CNRS, France Abstract This paper builds a stylized economy with both entrepreneurial and non entrepreneurial

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy

Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy forthcoming in the Review of Economic Studies Yena Park University of Pennsylvania JOB MARKET PAPER Abstract This paper studies optimal Ramsey taxation

More information

Sovereign Defaults. Iskander Karibzhanov. October 14, 2014

Sovereign Defaults. Iskander Karibzhanov. October 14, 2014 Sovereign Defaults Iskander Karibzhanov October 14, 214 1 Motivation Two recent papers advance frontiers of sovereign default modeling. First, Aguiar and Gopinath (26) highlight the importance of fluctuations

More information

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey MURAT ÜNGÖR Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey http://www.muratungor.com/ April 2012 We live in the age of

More information

Unemployment Insurance Generosity: A Trans-Atlantic Comparison

Unemployment Insurance Generosity: A Trans-Atlantic Comparison Unemployment Insurance Generosity: A Trans-Atlantic Comparison Stéphane Pallage (Département des sciences économiques, Université du Québec à Montréal) Lyle Scruggs (Department of Political Science, University

More information

Margin Regulation and Volatility

Margin Regulation and Volatility Margin Regulation and Volatility Johannes Brumm 1 Michael Grill 2 Felix Kubler 3 Karl Schmedders 3 1 University of Zurich 2 Deutsche Bundesbank 3 University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute Workshop:

More information

Sustainable Social Security: Four Options

Sustainable Social Security: Four Options Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Sustainable Social Security: Four Options Sagiri Kitao Staff Report no. 505 July 2011 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to

More information

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370 February 2006 Real Business Cycles Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota Abstract:

More information

Public debt and aggregate risk

Public debt and aggregate risk Public debt and aggregate risk Audrey Desbonnet, LEDa, Université Paris-Dauphine, Sumudu Kankanamge, Toulouse School of Economics (GREMAQ). First draft: March 2006, This draft: April 2011. Abstract In

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

Earnings and Wealth Inequality and Income Taxation:

Earnings and Wealth Inequality and Income Taxation: Earnings and Wealth Inequality and Income Taxation: Quantifying the Trade-Offs of Switching to a Proportional Income Tax in the U.S. Ana Castañeda, 1 Javier Díaz-Giménez 2 and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull 3 1

More information

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials Ctirad Slavík and Hakki Yazici February 19, 2014 Abstract In the United States structure and equipment capital are effectively taxed at different

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Fiscal Policy and Management in East Asia, NBER-EASE, Volume 16 Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi

More information

The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes

The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes Preliminary. Comments welcome. The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes Lars E.O. Svensson SIFR The Institute for Financial Research, Swedish House of Finance, Stockholm School

More information

Money and Public Finance

Money and Public Finance Money and Public Finance By Mr. Letlet August 1 In this anxious market environment, people lose their rationality with some even spreading false information to create trading opportunities. The tales about

More information

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 1 Consumption with many periods 1.1 Finite horizon of T Optimization problem maximize U t = u (c t ) + β (c t+1 ) + β 2 u (c t+2 ) +...

More information

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials Ctirad Slavík and Hakki Yazici July 21, 2014 Abstract In the United States structure and equipment capital are effectively taxed at different

More information

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey Jonathan Heathcote FRB Minneapolis Hitoshi Tsujiyama Goethe University Frankfurt Ohio State University, April 17 2014 The views expressed herein are those

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

How To Find Out If A Tax System Is More Efficient

How To Find Out If A Tax System Is More Efficient Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey Jonathan Heathcote FRB Minneapolis Hitoshi Tsujiyama Goethe University Frankfurt Iowa State University, April 2014 The views expressed herein are those of

More information

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix By Urban Jermann and Vincenzo Quadrini Data sources Financial data is from the Flow of Funds Accounts of the Federal Reserve Board. We report the

More information

Optimal fiscal policy under commitment

Optimal fiscal policy under commitment Abstract Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy with Commitment Mikhail Golosov and Aleh Tsyvinski 1 May 31, 2006 Forthcoming in New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and Law Optimal fiscal and monetary policy

More information

Wealth vs. Income Taxes in a Model of Credit Constraints and Inequality

Wealth vs. Income Taxes in a Model of Credit Constraints and Inequality Wealth vs. Income Taxes in a Model of Credit Constraints and Inequality Paul Shea Bates College July 13, 215 Abstract We compare the performance of net wealth and income taxes in a macroeconomic model

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Zeldes, QJE 1989 Background (Not in Paper) Income Uncertainty dates back to even earlier years, with the seminal work of

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Description of the model. This is a special case of a Mirrlees model.

More information

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function Jarek Hurnik Department of Economics Lecture III Jarek Hurnik (Department of Economics) Monetary Economics 2012 1 / 24 Basic Facts So far, the

More information

Dividend and Capital Gains Taxation Under Incomplete Markets

Dividend and Capital Gains Taxation Under Incomplete Markets Dividend and Capital Gains Taxation under Incomplete Markets Alexis Anagnostopoulos, Eva Cárceles-Poveda,DanmoLin Stony Brook University; Stony Brook University; University of Maryland Received Date; Received

More information

The Japanese Saving Rate

The Japanese Saving Rate The Japanese Saving Rate By KAIJI CHEN, AYŞE İMROHOROĞLU, AND SELAHATTIN İMROHOROĞLU* * Chen: Department of Economics, University of Oslo, Blindern, N-0317 Oslo, Norway (e-mail: kaijic@econ. uio.no); A.

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 10, 2013 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 10, 2013 1 / 44 Growth

More information

welfare costs of business cycles

welfare costs of business cycles welfare costs of business cycles Ayse Imrohoroglu From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, 2008 Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume Abstract The welfare cost of business

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK

WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK Francisco Covas Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Shigeru Fujita Federal

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 1 Introduction This note describes the canonical real business cycle model. A couple of classic references

More information

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing. Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of International Consumption Risk Sharing. Ergys Islamaj June 2014 Abstract This paper investigates how output volatility and productivity correlations

More information

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Prep. Course Macroeconomics Prep. Course Macroeconomics Intertemporal consumption and saving decision; Ramsey model Tom-Reiel Heggedal tom-reiel.heggedal@bi.no BI 2014 Heggedal (BI) Savings & Ramsey 2014 1 / 30 Overview this lecture

More information

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey SIMULATING THE TURKISH TAX SYSTEM ADEM İLERİ Middle East Technical University Department of Economics aileri@metu.edu.tr PINAR DERİN-GÜRE Middle East Technical University Department of Economics pderin@metu.edu.tr

More information

A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models

A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol. 18, No. 4, Fall 1994 A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models Ellen R. McGrattan* Economist Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary

On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary Marco Bassetto a,b,, Narayana Kocherlakota c,b a Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 271 19th Ave. S., Minneapolis, MN 55455,

More information

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Optimality Conditions Euler equation under uncertainty: u C (C t, 1 N t) = βe t [u C (C t+1, 1 N t+1)

More information

Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy

Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy Tom Krebs University of Mannheim Moritz Kuhn University of Bonn Mark Wright UCLA and Chicago Fed General Issue: For many households (the young),

More information

The Long-Run Optimum Level of Public Debt

The Long-Run Optimum Level of Public Debt Public debt and aggregate risk Audrey Desbonnet a 1 and Sumudu Kankanamge b 2 a University of Vienna, Austria. b Paris School of Economics, CNRS, France Abstract This paper assesses the long-run optimal

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 1 Introduction Having developed an operational model of the economy, we want to ask ourselves the

More information

Margin Calls, Trading Costs and Asset Prices in Emerging Markets: The Financial Mechanics of the Sudden Stop Phenomenon

Margin Calls, Trading Costs and Asset Prices in Emerging Markets: The Financial Mechanics of the Sudden Stop Phenomenon Discussion of Margin Calls, Trading Costs and Asset Prices in Emerging Markets: The Financial Mechanics of the Sudden Stop Phenomenon by Enrique Mendoza and Katherine Smith Fabrizio Perri NYUStern,NBERandCEPR

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

The Real Business Cycle model

The Real Business Cycle model The Real Business Cycle model Spring 2013 1 Historical introduction Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynesian

More information

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions Franck Portier TSE Macro II 29-21 Chapter 3 Real Business Cycles 36 3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model Perfectly competitive economy Optimal growth model + Labor decisions 2 types of agents

More information

Money and Capital in an OLG Model

Money and Capital in an OLG Model Money and Capital in an OLG Model D. Andolfatto June 2011 Environment Time is discrete and the horizon is infinite ( =1 2 ) At the beginning of time, there is an initial old population that lives (participates)

More information

14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 2, 2014. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 11 December 2, 2014. 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G 1. Use the IS-LM model to determine the effects of each of the following on the general equilibrium values of the real wage, employment, output, the real interest rate, consumption, investment, and the

More information

Consumption, Saving, and Investment, Part 1

Consumption, Saving, and Investment, Part 1 Agenda Consumption, Saving, and, Part 1 Determinants of National Saving 5-1 5-2 Consumption and saving decisions : Desired consumption is the consumption amount desired by households Desired national saving

More information

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment Multiple Choice Questions 1. Desired national saving equals (a) Y C d G. (b) C d + I d + G. (c) I d + G. (d) Y I d G. 2. With no inflation and a nominal interest

More information

The saving rate in Japan: Why it has fallen and why it will remain low

The saving rate in Japan: Why it has fallen and why it will remain low The saving rate in Japan: Why it has fallen and why it will remain low R.Anton Braun University of Tokyo Daisuke Ikeda Bank of Japan Douglas H. Joines University of Southern California September 12, 2006

More information

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 13 2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Introduction Simplistic RBC Model Simple stochastic growth model Baseline RBC model Introduction

More information

Why do emerging economies accumulate debt and reserves?

Why do emerging economies accumulate debt and reserves? Why do emerging economies accumulate debt and reserves? Juliana Salomao June, 2013 University of Minnesota Abstract Reserve accumulation has the benet of decreasing external vulnerability but it comes

More information

The Impact of Government Debt and Taxation on Endogenous Growth in the Presence of a Debt Trigger

The Impact of Government Debt and Taxation on Endogenous Growth in the Presence of a Debt Trigger The Impact of Government Debt and Taxation on Endogenous Growth in the Presence of a Debt Trigger Gregory W. Huffman March, 2015 Abstract Relatively little is known about how government debt influences

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour. Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS

Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour. Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS Introduction The most important empirical question for economics: the behavorial response to taxes Calibration of macro models

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Real Business Cycle Models Lecture 2 Nicola Viegi April 2015 Basic RBC Model Claim: Stochastic General Equlibrium Model Is Enough to Explain The Business cycle Behaviour of the Economy Money is of little

More information

Contents. List of Figures... 11. List of Variables and Abbreviations... 13. Introduction... 19

Contents. List of Figures... 11. List of Variables and Abbreviations... 13. Introduction... 19 Contents List of Figures... 11 List of Variables and Abbreviations... 13 Introduction... 19 Chapter 1. Stylised Facts of Saving Paragraph 1.1 Data Sets and Statistical Issues... 33 1.1.1 Various Saving

More information

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet) DEREE COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS EC 1101 PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS II FALL SEMESTER 2002 M-W-F 13:00-13:50 Dr. Andreas Kontoleon Office hours: Contact: a.kontoleon@ucl.ac.uk Wednesdays 15:00-17:00 Study

More information

Durable Goods, Borrowing Constraints, and Consumption Insurance

Durable Goods, Borrowing Constraints, and Consumption Insurance Durable Goods, Borrowing Constraints, and Consumption Insurance Enzo A. Cerletti Goethe University Frankfurt Josep Pijoan-Mas CEMFI and CEPR March 29, 214 Abstract We study the different transmission of

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2015 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

College Pricing and Income Inequality

College Pricing and Income Inequality College Pricing and Income Inequality Zhifeng Cai University of Minnesota Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis February 16, 2016 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE 1 Introduction Rising college

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Phd Macro, 2007 (Karl Whelan) 1 Real Business Cycle Models The Real Business Cycle (RBC) model introduced in a famous 1982 paper by Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott is the original DSGE model. 1 The early

More information

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall 2014. Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall 2014. Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall 2014 Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Everything else held constant, an increase in net

More information

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Challenges for defined contribution plans While Eastern Europe is a prominent example of the importance of defined

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION March 1, 2005 JCX-4-05 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance

Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance Lucas-Stokey, JME 1983 Optimal public finance with stochastic G, allowing for rich structure of asset markets (including claims equivalent to statecontingent

More information

Bankruptcy, Incorporation, and the Nature of Entrepreneurial Risk

Bankruptcy, Incorporation, and the Nature of Entrepreneurial Risk Bankruptcy, Incorporation, and the Nature of Entrepreneurial Risk Andy Glover University of Minnesota Jacob Short University of Minnesota JOB MARKET PAPER March 16, 2010 Abstract Entrepreneurship is risky;

More information

Lending in Last Resort to Governments

Lending in Last Resort to Governments Olivier Jeanne, Johns Hopkins University Indiana University, March 2015 Introduction Fiscal fundamentals in 2009: an international comparison Net debt/gdp (%) 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 US JAP UK EUR

More information

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Paul Krugman JPE,1991 March 4, 2010 Paul Krugman (JPE,1991) Increasing Returns March 4, 2010 1 / 18 Introduction Krugman claims that the study of economic outcomes

More information

Fiscal Policy and Alternatives - A Review

Fiscal Policy and Alternatives - A Review WP/12/38 Macroeconomic and Welfare Costs of U.S. Fiscal Imbalances Bertrand Gruss and José L. Torres 201 International Monetary Fund WP/12/38 IMF Working Paper Fiscal Affairs Department Macroeconomic and

More information

The Redistributive Benefits of Progressive Labor and Capital Income Taxation, or: How to Best Screw the Top 1%

The Redistributive Benefits of Progressive Labor and Capital Income Taxation, or: How to Best Screw the Top 1% The Redistributive Benefits of Progressive Labor and Capital Income Taxation, or: How to Best Screw the Top 1% Fabian Kindermann University of Würzburg and Netspar Dirk Krueger University of Pennsylvania,

More information

Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects of Social Security

Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects of Social Security Macroeconomic and Distributional Effects of Social Security Luisa Fuster 1 Universitat Pompeu Fabra and University of Toronto First draft: September 2002. This version: December 2002 1. Introduction Social

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Exam: ECON4310 Intertemporal macroeconomics Date of exam: Thursday, November 27, 2008 Grades are given: December 19, 2008 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon

More information

1 Teaching notes on GMM 1.

1 Teaching notes on GMM 1. Bent E. Sørensen January 23, 2007 1 Teaching notes on GMM 1. Generalized Method of Moment (GMM) estimation is one of two developments in econometrics in the 80ies that revolutionized empirical work in

More information

Female labor supply as insurance against idiosyncratic risk

Female labor supply as insurance against idiosyncratic risk Female labor supply as insurance against idiosyncratic risk Orazio Attanasio, University College London and IFS Hamish Low, University of Cambridge and IFS Virginia Sánchez-Marcos, Universidad de Cantabria

More information

Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2013

Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2013 Department of Economics Boston College Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Meetings: Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:30pm-2:45pm, Gasson Hall 209 Email address: sanjay.chugh@bc.edu

More information

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth Michael Bräuninger October 2002 Abstract This paper analyzes the effects of public debt on endogenous growth in an overlapping generations model. The

More information

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY Learning goals of this chapter: What forces bring persistent and rapid expansion of real GDP? What causes inflation? Why do we have business cycles? How

More information

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 We focus on three aspects of a cut in payroll taxes as a stabilizer in a recession: (1)

More information

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers Ralph S. J. Koijen Motohiro Yogo University of Chicago and NBER Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 1 1 The views expressed herein are not necessarily

More information

Credit Lines. December 31, 2007. Abstract

Credit Lines. December 31, 2007. Abstract Credit Lines Xavier Mateos-Planas University of Southampton, F.X.Mateos-Planas@soton.ac.uk José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota, CAERP University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER FRB Mpls, vr0j@.umn.edu

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 15, 2008 The recent dramatic rise in income inequality in the United

More information

The Provision of Public Universal Health Insurance: Impacts on Private Insurance, Asset Holdings and Welfare

The Provision of Public Universal Health Insurance: Impacts on Private Insurance, Asset Holdings and Welfare The Provision of Public Universal Health Insurance: Impacts on Private Insurance, Asset Holdings and Welfare Minchung Hsu Junsang Lee GRIPS KDI November, 2011 Abstract This paper aims to investigate impacts

More information

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities Asset Prices And Asset Quantities Monika Piazzesi University of Chicago, CEPR and NBER Martin Schneider NYU and FRB Minneapolis October 2006 Abstract We propose an organizing framework that determines

More information

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? No. 11-1 Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? Geoffrey M.B. Tootell Abstract: This public policy brief examines the relationship between trend inflation and commodity price increases and

More information

Segmented Asset Markets and the Distribution of Wealth

Segmented Asset Markets and the Distribution of Wealth Segmented Asset Markets and the Distribution of Wealth Aubhik Khan Ohio State University Heejeong Kim Ohio State University February 2015 ABSTRACT Using the 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances data, we find

More information

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Karl Walentin Sveriges Riksbank 1. Background This paper is part of the large literature that takes as its starting point the

More information

1 National Income and Product Accounts

1 National Income and Product Accounts Espen Henriksen econ249 UCSB 1 National Income and Product Accounts 11 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Can be measured in three different but equivalent ways: 1 Production Approach 2 Expenditure Approach

More information

Topic 2. Incorporating Financial Frictions in DSGE Models

Topic 2. Incorporating Financial Frictions in DSGE Models Topic 2 Incorporating Financial Frictions in DSGE Models Mark Gertler NYU April 2009 0 Overview Conventional Model with Perfect Capital Markets: 1. Arbitrage between return to capital and riskless rate

More information

Intergenerational Persistence of Earnings: The Role of Early and College Education

Intergenerational Persistence of Earnings: The Role of Early and College Education Intergenerational Persistence of Earnings: The Role of Early and College Education Diego Restuccia University of Toronto Carlos Urrutia Centro de Investigación Económica, ITAM Universidad Carlos III de

More information