Network Neutrality and Competition on Advertising Markets -Preliminary-

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Network Neutrality and Competition on Advertising Markets -Preliminary-"

Transcription

1 Network Neutrality and Competition on Advertising Markets -Preliminary- Anna D'Annunzio Antonio Russo 0 March 013 Abstract We investigate the eects of removing network neutrality regulation on the distribution of contents in the Internet. We model a two-sided market, where consumers and advertisers interact through Content Providers (CPs), and CPs and consumers through Internet Service Providers (ISPs). We consider two CPs, and we rst model a monopolist ISP and then two duopolist ISPs. An ad on multiple contents browsed by the same consumer is partially wasted, so advertisers' willingness to pay for a slot on a CP decreases in the number of multiple impressions on a single consumer. Under network neutrality, CPs can connect to ISPs for free, while in the unregulated regime, an ISP allows access to its network to a CP conditional on the payment of a fee. We show that switching to the unregulated regime makes universal distribution of contents less likely, specically when repeated impressions of an ad rapidly lose value and consumers care for content availability to a relatively small extent. The unregulated regime is never superior from a welfare point of view to the net neutrality regime. Consumer and advertiser surplus are weakly higher under net neutrality. ISPs are unambiguosly better o in the unregulated regime, while CPs are unambiguosly worse o. University of Rome Sapienza and Toulouse School of Economics European University Institute 1

2 1 Introduction Traditionally, the Internet has been subject to net neutrality regulation, that refers to the principle that all Internet trac is treated equally according to the principle of rst-come- rst-served. However, there is an ongoing debate on the eects of removing net neutrality, that counts many proponents and many opponents. Net neutrality regulation has dierent practical implications. In particular, Schuett (010) assesses that net neutrality implies a zero-price rule and a non-discrimination rule, and these are the two main aspects that have been studied by the literature. 1 In this paper, we consider the former feature of net neutrality, namely the fact that Interner Service Providers (hereafter, ISPs) are not allowed to impose fees to Content Providers (hereafter, CPs) in order to deliver their contents to nal users. charge a fee to a CP willing to access its customers base. 3 This entails that, when net neutrality is removed, an ISP may In this paper we are interested to study the competitive eects of removing net neutrality. In particular, we investigate whether an ISP that can charge an access fee to CPs may have incentives to restrict its oer of contents for consumers, fragmenting the Internet and departing from the end-to-end principle that has gouverned the Internet till now. In our paper, the rationale for doing so is to increase the eectiveness of the ads on a given CP, hence its market power and the revenues collected on the advertisers market, so as to increase the prots the ISPs can extract from CPs through the access fee. In our model, we take into consideration the stilized fact that the value of an ad impression on a consumer decreases with the number of impressions on that consumer. 4 Indeed, an ad that reaches a consumer that is already informed could be (at least partially) wasted, since the consumer could elicit no more information from the ad and could have already decided wether to buy the advertised product. Hence, we consider the rst ad impression on a consumer to be the most valuable since it allows consumers to know about the product and to decide to buy it, if they are interested. Following impressions are still valuable for advertisers, since they can still induce some consumers to purchase or remind them about the product, but they have less impact than the rst one. 5 Under net neutrality, CPs decide whether to access an ISP or not. When we consider a monopoly ISP, both CPs always connect to it, since a CP has no incentives to stay out of the market and no instrument to exclude the rival CP. Under duopoly, we nd that, since 1 For further details, see the literature review is in section. Actually, CPs pay some small fee to ISPs, but here we consider these fees to be zero under net neutrality. 3 The AT&T CEO, Edward Whitacre, said that he does not want content providers to use my lines for free. 4 See Calvano and Jullien (011), Anderson, Foros and Kind (011). 5 See Athey, Calvano and Gans (011).

3 access is free, there still always exists an equilibrium where CPs access both ISPs, hence where there is universal distribution of content. Indeed, CPs do not take into consideration the externalities they impose on each other and they are not able to coordinate on their preferred conguration of the network. CPs are in a prisoner dilemma situations. Hence, ISPs have to compete strongly for attracting consumers (low dierentiation) and CPs to attract ads. When the value of the second impression is very low, we nd a second equilibrium, where CPs can nd protable to share the market and to join dierent ISPs, leading to a total segmented network. Indeed, when one CP is connected exclusively to an ISP, it oers only high quality customers to advertisers, since consumers connected to that ISP can be reached only by buying ads from that CP. This increases the price that a CP can impose for its advertising space, and could increase their total revenues. When net neutrality is removed, an ISP can impose an access fee for its network. This access fee could be low, so that all CPs choose to access the market, or it could be as high as only one CP nds ptoitable to join one platform. Under this scenario, an ISP thinks as an editor, who cares about the protability of the contents it carries. With a monopolist ISP, we nd that both CPs access the network when the value of the second impression is high enough, while one CP is excluded when the value of the second impression is low. In this case an equilibrium always exists and for each value of the parameters this equilibria is unique. With dupoly ISPs, we nd two pure-strategy equilibria: universal distribution of contents exists when the value of the second impression is high enough, while total fragmentation exists when the value of the second impression is low enough. Indeed, when the value of rst impressions of ads on consumers are high enough, ISPs prefer to restrict the access to their network. In this way, they allow CPs to increase their prots, since they are monopolist of consumers' attention, and then they extract CPs' prots trough the access fee. We never nd multiple equilibria. However, for intermediate values of the second impression, we do not nd any pure strategy equilibrium, since each ISP tries to deviate from an equilibrium conguration in order to have some exclusive relations with the CPs. Hence, comparing the two regulatory regimes, we nd that the region where universal distribution of contents occurs in the unregulated regime shrinks. Moreover, we nd that the region where universal dustribution occurs never intersects the one where total fragmentation occurs under the net neutrality regime. It can easily be shown that universal distribution is benecial for consumers, advertisers and total welfare. Indeed, universal distribution of contents creates a higher gross surplus both on the consumers' side of the market (consumers enjoy more contents and stand less transportation costs) and on the advertisers' side of the market (more consumers' attention is provided to advertisers). Hence, we can conclude that removing net neutrality might entail 3

4 a loss in total, consumers and advertisers surplus, in the region where the equilibrium moves from total distribution under net neutrality to total fragmentation under the unregulated regime, since it restricts the access of nal users to contents. The unregulated regime is never superior to the net neutrality one from a welfare point of view. Moreover, when net neutrality is removed, ISPs are unambiguosly better o, while CPs are unambiguosly worse o. This paper is organized as follows. Section analyzes the relevant literature. Section 3 presents the basic model, that is solved in section 4 when we consider a monopoly ISP and in section 5 for dupoly ISPs. In each section we consider both regulatory regime, namely the net neutrality and the unregulated regime, we compare the two regimes and we derive welfare eects of removing net neutrality regulation. Then, section 6 concludes. All proofs are relegated to the Appendix. Literature There is a wide debate on net neutrality, that involves lawyers, engineers and economists. This debate tries to assess the consequencies of a change in the regulatory regime. Only recently this issue has been formally analized from an economic perspective. Choi and Kim (010) studies how both the incentives to invest of a monopolist ISP and of two horizontally dierentiated CPs change when net neutrality regulation is removed. They use the queuing theory to model scarce bandwidth, and in their model departing from net neutrality means allowing the platform to charge content providers in order to have priority on the net while best eort is assured for the others. In the short run, an ISP prefers to sell priority if the advertising margin for the content providers are high, since in this case it can impose a high price for the priority. If it has enough bargaining power, the content provider that receives the priority is better o in the discriminatory, while the content provider without priority is always worse o. As concerns total welfare, the result depends on the weight of the total margins for content providers and the total transportation costs for consumers, since both increase under the discriminatory regime. In the long run, an ISP can invest more or less under the discriminatory regime. Indeed, as the capacity of the network increases, the ISP can charge more for access to consumers. However, capacity expansion decreases the value of the scarce resource, i.e. the fast line. As concerns content providers, the incentive to invest of the high-speed contents depends on its ability to exploit the fast line and on its bargaining power, while the rival content always invests less under the discriminatory regime. In a related paper, Choi, Jeon and Kim (01) consider two interconnected ISPs and two 4

5 types of content providers that dier in their sensitivity to the delay in the network. They show that ISPs contract on reciprocal access charges as they were a monopoly bottleneck againts content providers. They nd that ISPs x a price for the content providers as if all the trac were o-net (this is the o-net principle established by Laont et al., 001). The advantage of net neutrality regulation crucially depends on the business model of the content providers. In particular, the quality provided to low-quality types is too distorted downwards under discrimination compared to the neutrality regime when the level of surplus extracted by content providers from consumers is positive but suciently small. Hermalin and Katz (007) consider a monopolist ISP and a continuum of content providers that dier in their attractiveness for consumers. 6 When the ISP is free to charge content providers for accessing the network and to oer dierent level of quality connections, it oers a menu of contract. At equilibrium, higher types purchase higher quality. The highest type buys the ecient quality, then quality is distorted downwards for other types. When net neutrality is imposed, the ISP is forced to oer a unique quality to all content providers. At equilibrium, low types are not anymore active, high types obtain less quality while intermediate types purchase higher quality. Compared to the unregulated model, welfare can increase or decrase under net neutrality: the rst and second eect pull down welfare, while the third one pulls it up. Even if the total eect is a priori ambiguous, the authors argue that the it is often negative. Also Bourreau, Kourandi and Valletti (01) gives the same interpretation of net neutrality: when it is removed, content providers can buy priority from the two competing ISPs. In a model that uses the queing theory, they show that the discriminatory regime is welfare superior to the net neutrality regime, since it allows a more ecient use of the network. Under discrimination, ISPs have larger investment incentives, more content providers are active and there is less congestion. However, they also show that under discrimination, ISPs could have the incentive to sabotate the best eort network, with adverse eects for welfare. Dierently from the previous papers, Economides and Tag (01) consider net neutrality to be a zero-price rule on the content side. They concentrated on the pricing issues linked to the two-sidedness of the market that could arise due to a depart from net neutrality. They consider both a model with a monopolist ISP and one with two horizontally dierentiated ISPs with single-homing consumers, and they show that results are not qualitatively aected. They nd that, when content providers value consumers more than consumers value contents, net neutrality is welfare enhancing compared to a situation where ISPs are allowed to charge a positive price to content providers. Indeed, only if this condition is veried, ISPs are willing to impose a positive price to content providers when net neutrality is removed. However, in 6 They consider an extension where ISPs compete, and the results of the basic model carry on. 5

6 this region, consumers are worse o under net neutrality. Indeed, the direct eect of a higher subscription fee for viewers overcome the indirect eect of higher content provision. Economides and Hermalin (01) gives the same denition as Economides and Tag (01) of net neutrality. They rst show that the preferred conguration from a welfare point of view is the one where more contents are delivered to consumers. This implies that welfare connot be enhanced by blocking contents. Departing from net neutrality through a tiering service can either increase or decrease total content sent, and then welfare. In particular, welfare increases when the delay times are shorter for content with greater elasticities of demand with respect to trasmission time than for contents with smaller elasticities. Remark that more time sensitive contents need not to be the contents with the highest elasticity. Thus, prioritizing these contents could entail a loss of welfare. They also show that, contrary to Choi and Kim (010), departing from net neutrality unambiguosly increases the incentives of the ISP to invest in the bandwidth. However, the net welfare eect, taking into account dynamic and static eects, is not a priori clear. The authors show that when consumer surplus weight a lot on total welfare, net neutrality is welfare-enhancing. In our paper, we consider net neutrality as a zero-price rule. Dierently from the previous paper, we are interested to analyse the segmentation issue that could arise when net neutrality is removed. Indeed, when a price is imposed for the access, ISPs have a stake in prots made by content providers, and this entails that they can nd protable to exclude some contents from their network in order to extract more prots from them through the access fee. Indeed, content providers can increase their prots when they oer the attention of some consumers as a monopolist. A similar issue is analysed in an independent paper by Kourandi, Kramer and Valletti (01), in a quite dierent model. Both papers analyse fragmentation of the Internet, in a setting with As we do, they consider two content providers and two ISPs. However, they consider exclusivity contracts among CPs and ISPs, while here we are interested to analyse exclusionary decisions made by the ISPs when net neutrality is removed. They consider that each ISP contracts sequentially with CPs for exclusivity. 7 Then, if no exclusive contract is signed, agents contract for non-exclusive provision. In our paper, we consider instead exclusionary fees. Namely, each ISP xes a fee that a CP has to pay if it wants access its network. This tari will be high if the ISP wants to exclude a CP and will be low if it wants to attract both CPs. In such a way, we simplify the negotiation stage, and we think to a negotiation process that could resemble a probable one in a big world like the Internet is. Moreover, they do not model how competition works on the advertisers market, and they just use a parameter to capture the protability of a given CP on the advertising market. Instead, in our model, we explicitely model competition between CPs on the advertising 7 First, an ISP contacts for exclusivity with a CP. Then, if no agreement is reached, with the other CP. 6

7 market. We model competition between CPs so as to capture the stylized fact concerning the decreasing value of multiple advertising impressions on viewers (see, among others, Calvano and Jullien, 011, and Anderson, Foros and Kind, 011). 3 The Model 3.1 Setup We consider a setting with two horizontally dierentiated Internet Service Providers (ISPs), indexed by i = A, B, and two identical Content Providers (CPs), indexed by j = 0, 1. An ISP is a platform connecting consumers to CPs, and a CP is a platform connecting consumers to advertisers. Obviously, a CP needs to be connected to at least one ISP in order to be able to reach consumers. Moreover, each CP reaches only the consumers of the ISP it is conncted to. We consider ISPs and CPs to be independent rms. We compare the connection choices made by rms under two alternative regulatory regimes: one in which network neutrality regulation is in place and one in which it is removed, referred to as the unregulated regime. In the former case, ISPs have to grant access to their network to all CPs for free. In the latter, ISPs impose an access fee to CPs. Internet Service Providers. ISPs are located at the extremes of a Hotelling line: ISP i = A is located at point 0 and ISP i = B at point 1. ISP i sets a subscription fee a i (which can be positive or negative) for consumers. In the unregulated regime, ISP i also xes an access fee F i (which can be positive or negative) for CPs. In the net neutrality regime, CPs can freely access both ISPs, hence F i = 0. Access fees F i are exclusionary: if a CP pays it, it can access ISP i's consumer base, otherwise it is excluded. All fees are non-discriminatory and non-contingent. The prot function of ISP i is π i = a i q i + F i I ij j=0,1 i = A, B where q i is the number of consumers connecting to ISP i and I ij is an indicator function, such that I ij = 1 if CP j acquires access to ISP i's consumers and I ij = 0 otherwise. More details on this function are provided below. Content Providers. Each CP provides free content to consumers but charges advertisers for ad spaces. A CP j charges a per-impression price p j to an advertiser if and only if a consumer is exposed to the ad while browsing content (an impression). We assume that 7

8 there is no cost of providing ad spaces and that CPs set a uniform price for all advertisers. We abstract from the issue of consumer targeting, assuming all consumers are equally valuable targets for all advertisers. Hence, each time a consumer visits a given content, she is impressed with all ads with probability one and all impressions are relevant. However, their eect may depend on how many times the consumer has already been impressed with the same ad, as we discuss below. We also assume that each avertiser can buy at most one ad space per content provider. 8 Given these assumptions, the volume of impressions for an ad put on CP j is equal to q j, which is the number of consumers connected to the ISPs distributing j's content, i.e. q j = q i I ij j = 0, 1 i=a,b The prot of CP j is π j = d j p j q j F i I ij j = 0, 1 i=a,b where d j is the number of advertisers on CP j. A CP can connect to either no ISP, only one or both. CPs make connection decisions by comparing prots under all network congurations, taking as given the couple (F A, F B ) and the decision of the rival CP. A given network conguration arises at equilibrium when no CP nds a protable unilateral deviation. Consumers. There is a mass of size one of consumers uniformely distributed on the Hotelling line on the interval [0, 1]. Consumers connect to one and only one ISP and visit all available contents. 9 The utility U i consumer x [0, 1] gets from connecting to ISP i and browsing contents available on it is U i (x) = Z + i t x l i a i i = A, B (1) where Z is the gross surplus from accessing the Internet, assumed large enough that all consumers connect to an ISP. t is the transportation cost on the Hotelling line, i.e. disutility for consumer x from not consuming its preferred specication of the content. l i represents the position of the ISP on the Hotelling line. a i is the subscription fee to access ISP i. i represents the utility consumers get from browsing contents available on ISP i. We 8 The results would not change if CPs could charge a dierent per-impression price depending on which ISP the consumer impressed is connected to. 9 The rst assumption implies single-homing consumers. This assumption could be linked to some technological constraint that prevents consumers from having multiple connections at home. Moreover, many players in the telecom sector are active both in the mobile and xed telephony markets, and bundle access to the Internet on mobile and landline, so that it could be advantageous for consumers to use the same operator for both services. The second assumption follows from the fact that we ignore costs of visiting content. the 8

9 assume that each CP connected to ISP i increases individual utility by a value δ > 0, hence i = j δi ij. 10 We assume that the market is covered and that the demand for each ISP is positive, i.e. q i = 1 and q i > 0 i. Net consumer surplus (CS ) can be computed as CS = ˆ x (Z + A tx a A ) dx + ˆ 1 0 x (Z + B t (1 x) a B ) dx where x is the marginal consumer, indierent between subscribing to ISP A or B. Consumers' surplus can be written as CS = Z + ( i a i ) q i + t tq B tqa i=a,b Advertisers. There is a mass of size one of advertisers interested in reaching consumers by means of CPs' content. V 1 denotes the gross advertiser surplus (e.g. the increase in the expected value of sales due to the consumer seeing the ad) produced by impressing the ad on a consumer for the rst time, while V the gross advertiser surplus produced by impressing the ad on a consumer for the second time. The consumer may, in particular, have already been impressed with the same ad by consulting the content of the rival CP. Recent literature on online advertising suggests that ads seen multiple times are partially wasteful (Calvano and Jullien, 011). This is because ads end up hitting already informed consumers and hence are wasted together with their attention. 11 As a response, internet platforms introduce tracking technologies that reduce within-outlet waste. However, when consumers have access to multiple platforms (as in the setup we study here), more attention gets wasted as there is no across-outlet tracking. Therefore, we make the following Assumption V 1 V 0 Advertisers can buy ad spaces from none, one or both CPs. Suppose an advertiser multihomes, buying ad space from both content providers. Its total surplus would be V 1 j=0,1 q j + V j=0,1 q j p j q j 10 We do not endogenize consumers' demand for content, hence we do not explicitely take into account nuisance cost of advertising. 11 Athey, Calvano and Gans (011) estimate that more than two thirds of the ads in large campaigns are wasted, hitting the same receivers more than 10 times. j=0,1 9

10 where j=0,1 q j denotes the mass of consumers accessing at least one contentand j=0,1 q j denotes the number of consumers that access both contents. Given the assumptions taken above, each consumer that access at least a CP ( j=0,1 q j) is impressed at least once by each ad. Consumers that access both CPs ( j=0,1 q j) are impressed twice. Suppose instead the advertiser single-homed, buying an ad space only from CP j. Then, its total surplus would be (V 1 p j ) q j j = 0, 1 Obviously, the surplus is zero if no ad space is bought. Taking as given the network conguration and the prices p j, the advertiser will choose the option that guarantees the highest surplus. We may therefore compute the total surplus for advertisers as follows AS = ( d sj (V 1 p j ) q j + d m V 1 q j + V q j ) p j q j j=0,1 where d sj is the number of advertisers that single-home on CP j and d m is the number of advertisers that multi-home. j=0,1 j=0,1 j=0,1 Social Welfare. We dene Social Welfare as the sum of consumer surplus, advertisers surplus and prots of ISP and CPs. Thus SW = CS + AS + π i + i=a,b j=0,1 It is intutive that social welfare coincides with the gross surplus generated by connections at the two ends of the market, i.e. with the sum of gross surplus for consumers and advertisers. Indeed, payments collected by ISPs and CPs are simply transfers from other agents and cancel out in the social welfare formula. Replacing CS, AS, i=a,b π i and j=0,1 π j in SW, we get SW = Z + i + t tq B tqa + ( ) d sj V 1 q j + d m V 1 q j + V q j i=a,b j=0,1 j=0,1 j=0,1 It is straightforward to conclude the following π j Lemma 1 The socially optimal market conguration is such that each CP connects to both ISPs and all advertisers multi-home. PROOF: The fact that each CP is connected to both ISPs implies that q j = 1 j, as 10

11 consumers have access to all contents, irrespectively of the ISP they subscribe to. It also implies that q A = q B = 1/, hence total transport cost t tq B tqa are minimized. SW is strictly increasing in i=a,b i, which is maximized when I ij = 1 i, j. It is also optimal to have advertisers buy all ad spaces, since SW increases in the number of ad impressions to consumers. Timing and denition of equilibrium. The timing of the game is as follows: 1. Under the unregulated regime, ISP A and B simultaneously set access fees F i. Under the net neutrality regime, F i is restricted to be zero. Having observed fees F i, CPs simultaneously decide which ISPs to connect to (if any).. ISP A and B simultaneously set subscription fees a i. CPs simultaneously set (perimpression) prices p j for their ad spaces. Advertisers buy ad spaces from CPs. 3. Consumers connect to their preferred ISP and visit the available CPs, getting exposed to the ads. A subgame perfect equilibrium of this game is a set of fees, prices, connection decisions and demands such that, at each stage, no player wants to deviate given what has been decided at the previous stages and the choice of other players at the given stage. We assume all agents have perfect foresight. 1 The model is solved by backward induction. A remark is in order at this point. In a standard two-sided market framework, one could expect ISPs to cut subscription fees in order to attract more consumers and exploit network externalities on the content side. The timing we assume rules this out, since price competition for consumers comes at a later stage with respect to competition for contents. Hence, ISPs take revenues collected on the content side as given when deciding on subscription fees. We believe this to be a reasonable simplication, justied by the fact that contracts between ISPs and CPs have generally a more long-run perspective and their connection decision is more rigid than that between ISPs and consumers. 1 At Stage 1, ISPs set their fees anticipating the possible network congurations that may arise considering incentive and partecipation constraints of CPs. Given a couple (F A, F B ), one or more network congurations (i.e. quadruples {I ij } i=a,b;j=0,1 ) may occur in equilibrium. We make the assumption that, when they are indierent between connecting or not to an additional ISP, CPs always choose to connect. 11

12 4 ISP monopoly In order to understand the forces at work in the model, it is instructive to start by a simplied scenario in which only one ISP (say, A) is active. We simply disregard the presence of ISP B, so A acts as a monopolist. To describe in a concise way the network congurations that may arise in equilibrium, we now introduce some notation. In the following, network conguration (0A, 1A) means that both 0 and 1 connect to A (i.e. I Aj = 1 j); (0A, 1N) means that 0 connects to A and 1 does not (i.e. I A0 = 1 I A1 = 0); (0N, 1N) means that no CP connects to the ISP. 4.1 Stage 3 At Stage 3, consumers decide whether to connect to ISP A or stay out of the market. Indeed, only consumers with a low x participate to the market, while consumers with a high x prefer not to, since their transportation cost are too high. We calculate the marginal consumer x who is indierent between conecting to ISP A and not accessing the Internet at all. Solving for x equation U A (x) = 0, we nd x = Z + A a A t Demand for ISP A is given by all consumers who get positive utility from connecting to this ISP, that is q A = x Stage At Stage, ISP A decides its subscription fee a A maximizing its prots. ISP A's prots are π A = q A a A + j F Aj. By solving the rst order condition π A a A a Amon = Z + A By substitution, we obtain equilibrium demand and prot: = 0 i = A, B, we nd q Amon = Z + A t π Amon = (Z + A) 4t + j F Aj We nd that both subscription fee and demand are increasing in A. Hence, taking access fees j F Aj as given, prots are increasing in A. 13 In this special case, we relax the assumption that all market is covered. Hence, x 1. 1

13 Pricing of advertising spaces. At Stage, CPs also choose the price for advertising spaces. In order to understand how prices are formed, it is useful to start with a description of how much ad slots are worth to advertisers. Suppose an advertiser puts ads only on a single content provider, say, CP0. All consumers reached by 0 would be impressed once. The value of impressing a consumer with an ad for the rst time (a rst impression) is V 1. Consider now the possibility that the advertiser bought an ad space also from CP 1. The value of such additional space depends on whether consumers reached by CP1 have already been reached by CP0 or not. If a consumer browsing CP1 already browsed CP0, she would be exposed to the ad for a second time. Therefore, the additional ad space is worth V, i.e. the value of a second impression. If instead CP1 is the only outlet to reach the consumer, she will be exposed to the ad for the rst time. Hence, the additional ad space is worth V 1. If content providers are gatekeepers of their customers' attention they can always insist on charging the monopoly price for an impression. On the contrary, multi-homing on CPs by consumers introduces substitutability between platforms. As the fraction of consumers reached by multiple outlets goes up, strategic externalities become relevant, as in a standard Bertrand oligopoly model. These induce lower equilibrium prices (Ambrus, Calvano and Reisinger, 011, and Anderson, Foros and Kind, 011). To illustrate, assume to be in the universal distribution conguration: equilibrium prices are such that CPs charge a per-impression price V to all advertisers. To see why, consider that a higher price could protably be undercut by the rival CP, winning it the entire market. This is because advertisers would optimally single-home on the cheapest outlet. On the other hand, there is no point in charging less than V. This is because advertisers multi-home, since the price per impression is lower or equal than the value of a second impression V. 14 Consequently, when two CPs are connected to the same ISP, they charge p j = V j = 0, 1. Suppose, instead, a CP were the only one available to subscribers at a given ISP. Intuitively, it can act as a monopolist and set a per-impression price equal to p j = V 1, capturing the entire advertiser gross surplus. The above discussion introduces us to Lemma, presenting CPs' prots at Stage. We provide in its proof a more formal and complete description of how ad space prices are determined. Lemma In equilibrium, advertisers buy ad slots from all CPs that have access to consumers. Advertising prots π j for each CP, conditionally on its connection status, are as reported in the following table 14 If multi-homing was not possible, the equilibrium price would be equal to the marginal cost of providing ad spaces, which is zero by assumption. 13

14 π 1 π 0 A No A No V q mon ++ F A 0 V q mon ++ F A V 1 q mon + F A V 1 q mon + F A where q ++ mon = Z+δ t and q + mon = Z+δ t PROOF: We consider each possible market conguration in turn. Consider rst the universal distribution case. Thus, q j = q A j = 0, 1. Suppose an advertiser put ads on both CPs. Its total surplus would be (V 1 + V (p 0 + p 1 )) q A. Suppose instead the advertiser decided to put ads only on CP j. Its total surplus is (V 1 p j ) q A since, in this case, consumers are exposed only to rst impressions. This implies that, if it is already putting ads on, say, CP 0, an advertiser will also put them on CP 1 if and only if p 1 V. We now prove that p j = V j = 0, 1 is the unique equilibrium price for advertising spaces. Suppose p j V : as long as p j V advertisers would optimally multi-home and put ads on both CPs. Hence, it is optimal for CP j to set p j = V. Suppose instead that p j > V : then, it is optimal for j to set p j = p j ε. By so doing, all advertisers would single-home and buy only ad slots from j, leaving the other CP with zero revenues. It follows that the only equilibrium prices (mutual best response) are such that p j = V j = 0, 1. It is easily seen that, in such equilibrium, all advertisers multi-home. Finally, each CP makes a prot equal to V q A F i. Suppose now the market conguration involved full fragmentation, i.e. either (0A,1N) or (0N,1A). For instance, consider conguration (0A,1N). If an advertiser puts ads on both CPs, its total surplus is (V 1 p 0 p 1 ) q A. If ads are put only on CP 0, the surplus is (V 1 p 0 ) q A. If instead ads are put only on CP 1, the surplus is 0 p 1. We now prove that CPs set the following equilibrium prices: p 1 = 0 and p 0 = V 1. Indeed, as CP 1 does not provide any surplus to advertisers (since it is not able to reach consumers), they never join its platform for any positive price. Instead, CP 0 has no incentive to x any price lower than V 1, since advertisers join this platform for a price up to this value. Hence, CP 1's prots are π 1 = 0 and CP 0's prots are π 0 = V 1 q A F A. Trivially, when no CP is connected, no advertising takes place. Hence, all prots are zero. 4.3 Stage 1 At Stage 1, ISP A sets the access fee F A and CPs decide whether to connect to its platform or not. This decision determines, in turn, the network conguration. We now present the 14

15 subgame perfect equilibria of the game. We begin from the benchmark case of net neutrality, where the access fee is constrained to zero. Next, we consider the unregulated scenario, in which ISP A freely sets F A. In the following, we denote with superscript N the equilibrium variables under net neutrality, and with superscript U the ones under the unregulated regime Benchmark: net neutrality regime In the Network Neutrality case, prots for ISPs are simply given by revenues collected from subscription fees πamon N = (Z + A) since FA N = 0 4t We now study CPs connection decisions, and derive the corresponding conguration of the network. We assume that, when CPs are indierent between connecting or not, they choose to connect. Elaboration from the table provided in Lemma leads to the following Proposition 1 In the net neutrality regime there exists a unique subgame perfect equilibrium where the market conguration is (0A,1A). It is such that a N Amon = Z + δ q N A = q N j = Z + δ t p N j = V I N Aj = 1 j PROOF: The proposition is easily proved using Lemma, showing that, when F i = 0, this equilibrium exists and is the only one. Under net neutrality, the network conguration in which all CPs connect to A is always an equilibrium. When signing up to an additional ISP, a CP produces a negative externality on the rival, eliminating the possibility to charge the monopoly price V 1 for ad slots. Each CP would be better o if the rival was excluded from the market. Since connection is free, however, there is no mechanism to internalize this external eect. Nonetheless, the equilibrium is ecient from society's perspective Unregulated regime In the unregulated regime, ISP A is allowed to impose an access fee F A to CPs. The following Proposition presents the subgame perfect equilibria in this regulatory regime: Proposition In the unregulated regime: 15

16 ) if and only if the value of second ad impressions is high enough, i.e. V (V (Z+δ) (Z+δ), 4t 4t there exists a subgame perfect equilibrium where the market conguration is (0A,1A). It is such that F U A = V a U A = Z + δ q U A = q U j = Z + δ t p U j = V I U Aj = 1 j if and only if the value) of second ad impressions is low enough, i.e. if 0 < V < 1 (V 1 + (Z+δ) (Z+δ), there exists a subgame perfect equilibrium where the market 4t 4t conguration is (0A,1N) or (ON,1A). It is such that F U A = V 1 a U i = Z + δ q U A = q U j = Z + δ t p U j = V 1 IAj U = 1 j j=0,1 PROOF: see Appendix. When setting the access fee at Stage 1 the ISP essentially makes a choice between two alternative network congurations. If the access fee is suciently low, both content providers connect to the platform. If instead the fee is high, only one will do it. This is because, as shown in Lemma, if both connect the protability of ad spaces is reduced. Hence, as long as one CP connects, the other will not nd paying worthwile. As a consequence, the ISP faces a trade-o between obtaining a relatively large fee from a single content provider, while also renouncing to a share of consumers (who subscribe to its platform only if multiple content are available), and obtaining smaller fees from both CPs, while also maximising prots on the consumer side of the market. This is the reason why the equilibrium access fee depends crucially on the relation between the value of rst and second ad impressions, V 1 and V, as well as on the attractiveness of content for consumers δ. When V and/or δ are high enough, the monopolist ISP is better o attracting both content providers. This is because CPs have a substantial willingness to pay for connection even if they cannot sell access to consumers' attention as monopolists. Hence, they are both willing to pay a high access fee. Moreover, the loss of consumer base when excluding a content is too strong. If instead V and/or δ are low enough, the monopolist ISP prefers to ask for a high access fee, thereby excluding one CP. This is because attracting both content providers would require renouncing to a large share of prots on the content side, while the gains on the consumer side would be insucient. 16

17 4.4 Comparison of the two regulatory regimes Let us now compare network congurations in the two regulatory regimes. While CPs are always universally distributed under net neutrality, one might be excluded from the network under the unregulated regime. This happens when there is a large premium for being the only available advertising outlet. The ISP can then nd protable to exclude a CP in order to boost advertising revenues of the remaining one and recoup them through the high access fee. Let us now look at welfare implications. Consumers are always better o under the (0AB,1AB) conguration that under the (0i,1 i) conguration, since they have access to more contents. Advertisers are also better o under universal distribution, since the number of ad impressions increases, while their price goes down. CPs are clearly better o under net neutrality, since they have positive prots, while all their prots are extracted by the ISP under the unregulated regime. On the contrary, the ISP is better o under the unregulated regime, since it can extract prots from CPs. 5 ISP duopoly Let us now move to the fully-edged version of the model, with both ISPs active on the market. Following the notation introduced in Section 4, network conguration (0AB, 1AB) will here mean that 0 connects to both A and B and 1 connects to both A and B (i.e. I ij = 1 i, j); (0A, 1B) means that 0 connects only to A and 1 connects only to B (i.e. I A0 = I B1 = 1 I A1 = I B0 = 0); (0N, 1AB) means that 0 connects to no ISP and 1 connects to both A and B, (I A1 = I B1 = 1 I A0 = I B0 = 0). Similar notation is used for all other congurations. 5.1 Stage 3 At Stage 3, consumers choose which ISP to connect, maximizing U, taking as given the CPs available at each ISP and subscription fees a i. In order to compute demands, we determine the marginal consumer x who is indierent between the two ISPs. Equalizing U A (x) = U B (x) and solving for x we nd x = 1 + ( A B ) (a A a B ) t The demand for ISP A is given by all consumers to the left of x on the Hotelling line, while that for ISP B is given by all consumers to its right. That is, q A = x and q B = 1 x. 17

18 5. Stage At stage, ISPs simultaneously set subscription fees a i, maximising their prots. They do so taking as given access fees F i as well as CPs connection decisions (set at Stage 1), and anticipating consumers' behavior at stage 3. Equilibrium fees are obtained as the solution to the system of rst order conditions π i a i = 0 i = A, B. The result, for any network conguration, is a i = t + ( i i ) 3 i = A, B i i Replacing a i in q i and π i, we get demands and prots 15 q i = 1 + ( i i ) 6t π i = (3t + i i ) 18t + I ij F i i = A, B i i j=0,1 To describe in a brief way the equilibrium demands conditional on the values of i i, we introduce some additional notation, summarized in the following table i i q i dened as 1 δ 6t q δ 6t q + 1 δ 6t q ++ CPs set prices for ad spaces in the same way as in the monopoly case of Section 4. However, we can now nd situations where a CP is the unique gatekeeper only for a part of consumers connected to the Internet (the remaining part being reached by the other CP). In this case, the price of an ad space is a weighted average of the value of rst impression V 1 and of the second impression V, the weights being respectively the demand of subscribers who visit only one CP and the demand of subscribers who visit both CPs. Lemma 3 presents CP prots at Stage. Lemma 3 All advertisers multi-home at equilibrium. Prots π j for each CP, conditional on the network conguration, are as reported in the following table 15 Since we have assumed q i = 1 and q i > 0 i, this implies that we need δ 6t < 1 18

19 π 1 π 0 A&B A B None A&B A B None V F i V F i V q + + V 1 q F i V q + F A V q + + V 1 q F i V q + F A V 1 F i 0 V q + F A V q + + V 1 q F i V q + F B V q + + V 1 q 0 F i V 1 F i 0 V q ++ V F 1 A F B V q ++ F A V 1 F A V 1 q + F A V 1 F A V q++ F B 0 V 1 F B V q ++ F B V 1 q + F B V 1 q + F A V 1 q + F B PROOF: We consider each of the possible market congurations in turn. First, consider universal distribution. The discussion concerning this conguration is the same as the one in the proof of Lemma. Suppose now the market conguration involves partial fragmentation. For instance, consider the case (0AB,1A). If an advertiser puts ads on both CPs, its total surplus would be (V 1 p 0 ) q + (V 1 + V p 0 p 1 ) q +. If instead ads are put only on CP 0, the surplus is V 1 p 0. Finally, if ads are put only on CP 1, its surplus is (V 1 p 1 ) q +. We now prove that ISPs set the following equilibrium prices: p 1 = V and p 0 = V 1 q + V q + and that advertisers multi-home. Let us start by describing the best response function for CP 0. Suppose p 1 V. In that case, advertisers would buy ad spaces from CP 1, irrespectively of whether they have already bought ads from CP 0 or not, since price is surely below the value of a repeated impression. If they put ads on CP 1, however, they will also put them on CP 0 only if p 0 is low enough, i.e. only if (V 1 p 0 ) q + (V 1 + V p 0 p 1 ) q + (V 1 p 1 ) q + which results in p 0 V 1 q + V q +. It follows that the best response for CP 0 is to set p 0 = V 1 q + V q + (otherwise, CP 0 would not be able to sell any ad space). Suppose now p 1 > V : in that case, advertisers putting ads on CP 0, would never put them on CP 1, the price being too high. This rules out multi-homing, so all advertisers put ads either on CP 0 or CP 1. Clearly, CP 0 is better o being the player capturing all the market. This happens if and only if (V 1 p 0 ) (V 1 p 1 ) q + holds. As a consequence, the best response is p 0 = V 1 q + p 1 q +. 19

20 Let us now describe the best response function for CP 1. Suppose rst that p 0 V 1 q + V q +. Advertisers multi-home if and only if p 1 V. Otherwise, they all converge on one of the two CPs. However, if p 1 > V, this CP is 0, as condition (V 1 p 0 ) (V 1 p 1 ) q + is holds. It follows that the best response is p 1 = V. Suppose now that p 0 > V 1 q + V q +.p 0 is suciently high for CP 1 to be able to capture all the market while still setting a higher price than V. Indeed, it can easily be veried that condition (V 1 p 0 ) (V 1 p 1 ) q + holds as long as p 1 p 0 V 1 q. The threshold on the right hand side of the inequality is q + strictly higher than V as long as p 0 > V 1 q + V q +. Hence, by setting p 1 = p 0 V 1 q > V q +, CP 1 is able to capture all the market. Hence, the best response is p 1 = p 0 V 1 q. q + We are now in a position to describe the equilibrium. It is quite easy to see that the only mutual best response is such that p 1 = V and p 0 = V 1 q + V q +. This implies that CPs' prots are π 1 = V q + F A and π 0 = V 1 q + V q + F i and that advertisers multi-home. A similar reasoning applies when the conguration is (0A,1AB), (0B,1AB) and (0AB,1B). Consider now a conguration with all CPs being distributed by only one ISP, i.e. either (0A,1A) or (0B,1B). With a reasoning similar to that of the case of universal connection, one can prove that the only equilibrium is such that p 0 = p 1 = V so that CPs' prots are π 1 = π 0 = V q ++ F A. Again, advertisers multi-home. Consider a market conguration involving full segmentation, i.e. either (0A,1B) or (0B,1A). In this case, each CP would be a monopolistic outlet for the consumers it reaches. It is quite intuitive (we omit the proof) that equilibrium prices are p 0 = p 1 = V 1 and prots π 1 = π 0 = V 1 F i. It is again the case that, in equilibrium, advertisers multi-home. Consider now a conguration with one CP being distributed by both ISPs, while the other CP being distributed by no ISP. Take, for example, the case (0AB,1N). No advertiser puts an ad on CP 1 since no consumer can reach it. If an advertiser puts ads on CP 0, its total surplus is V 1 p 0. Thus, quite simply, the only equilibrium is such that p 0 = V 1. Hence, CPs' prots are π 1 = 0, π 0 = V 1 F i. In this case, advertisers single-home, since they have no benet from advertising on CP 1. A similar reasoning applies to conguration (0N,1AB). Finally, consider a conguration with one CP being distributed by one ISP, with the other CP being distributed by none, such as (0A, 1N). No advertiser puts an ad on CP1 since no 0

21 consumer is reached. If an advertiser puts ads on CP 0, its total surplus is (V 1 p 0 ) q +. Thus, p 0 = V 1. Hence, CPs' prots are π 1 = 0, π 0 = V 1 q + F A. A similar reasoning applies when the conguration is (0N,1A), (0N,1B) and (0B.1N). 5.3 Stage 1 At Stage 1, ISP i sets the access fee F i and CPs decide to which ISP they want to connect, if any. Our objective is now to determine the subgame perfect equilibria of the game. We begin from the benchmark case of net neutrality, where access fees F i are constrained to zero. Next, we consider the unregulated scenario, in which ISPs freely set F i. As in Section 4, we denote with superscript N the equilibrium variables under net neutrality, and with superscript U the ones under the unregulated regime Benchmark: net neutrality regime In the net neutrality case, prots for ISPs are simply given by revenues collected from subscription fees π i (F i = 0) = (3t + i i ) i = A, B 18t We now check which conguration of the network occurs at equilibrium, by studying CPs' choices of connection, given F i = 0. Elaboration from the table provided in Lemma 3 leads to the following Proposition 3 In the net neutrality regime: there always exists a subgame perfect equilibrium where the market conguration is (0AB,1AB). It is such that a N i = t q N i = 1 p N j = V q N j = 1 I N ij = 1 i, j if and only if the value of second impressions of advertisements is low enough, i.e. V V 1 ( δ 6t+δ ), there also exists a subgame perfect equilibrium where the market conguration is (0A,1B) or (0B,1A). It is such that a N i = t q N i = 1 p N j = V 1 q N j = 1 Iij N = 1 Iij N I ij N i, j j=0,1 1

22 PROOF: The proposition is easily proved using the table in Lemma 3, and showing that, when F i = 0, the equilibria are the only ones to exist. Under net neutrality, the network conguration in which all CPs connect to both ISPs is always an equilibrium. Interestingly, this is not necessarily the most desirable outcome from the perspective of CPs. More precisely, when the price of ad spaces is strongly reduced due to competition between multiple CPs, each could make higher prots if the network were fully segmented. This is because, if a single CP can act as a gatekeeper for advertisers interested in reaching consumers, it can charge monopoly prices for ad spaces. As in the monopoly case of Section 4, when connecting to an additional ISP, each CP produces a negative strategic externality on its rival, eliminating the possibility to charge the full price V 1 for ad slots. Since connection is free, this strategic externality is uninternalized, so the equilibrium with universal connection is always possible. Hence, when V is low compared to V 1, the game between CPs is a typical prisoner's dilemma. Nevertheless, quite inuitively, the equilibrium is ecient from society's perspective as availability of content is maximised and price of ad spaces are competitive. There also exists the possibility of a second equilibrium, characterized by the (0A,1B) or (0B,1A) market conguration. This is possible when the value of the second impression is suciently small. This is more likely to happen when consumers value contents to a large extent. 16 To get the intuition, suppose (0A,1B) to be the market conguration. Consider the problem of a content provider, say 0, deciding whether to connect also to ISP B or not. If it does not connect to B, the price it can charge for ad spaces is V 1, given that it is the only outlet for advertisers wanting to reach A's consumers. If CP 0 connects to B as well, its consumer base is enlarged but the price it can charge for ad spaces is the weighted average V 1 q + V q +. This is because part of its audience would already be reached by the rival content. Although connection to B is free and gives the possibility to reach more consumers, there is an implicit cost for CP 0. The quantity of eyeballs it monopolizes shrinks: when connecting also to B, CP 0 induces part of A's consumers to migrate to B. Hence, if the eect of content availability on consumers' demand is high enough and/or the relative value of second ad impressions is small, the implicit cost of an additional connection for CP 0 is too high. It follows that the CP may prefer not to connect to the extra ISP, even if it can ( do so for free. The above also implies that if V V δ ) 1 6t+δ, multiple equilibria exist Indeed, observe that the threshold V 1 ( δ 6t+δ ) is strictly increasing in δ. 17 One could use a given selection criterion to eliminate one of the two. We nd that the equilibrium where the market conguration is (0A,1B) ( ) or (0B,1A) payo-dominates the one where the market conguration is (0AB,1AB) when V V 1. We also nd that the equilibrium that induces δ (0AB,1AB) 6t+δ

Network Neutrality, Access to Content and Online Advertising. RSCAS 2013/57 Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies

Network Neutrality, Access to Content and Online Advertising. RSCAS 2013/57 Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies RSCAS 013/57 Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies Network Neutrality, Access to Content and Online Advertising Anna D Annunzio and Antonio Russo European University Institute Robert Schuman Centre

More information

Working Paper Net Neutrality and Internet Fragmentation: the Role of Online Advertising

Working Paper Net Neutrality and Internet Fragmentation: the Role of Online Advertising econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics D'Annunzio,

More information

Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-air and Pay-TV s

Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-air and Pay-TV s Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-air and Pay-TV s Emilio Calvano (CSEF - U. of Naples) and Michele Polo (U. Bocconi, IEFE and IGIER) October 2014 - Naples. 12th Conference on Media

More information

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality ROBERTO ROSON Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Venice, Italy. Abstract I review two papers, addressing the issue of

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Impact of QoS on Internet User Welfare

Impact of QoS on Internet User Welfare Impact of QoS on Internet User Welfare Galina Schwartz, Nikhil Shetty, and Jean Walrand Department of Electrical Engineering and Computer Sciences (EECS), University of California Berkeley, Cory Hall,

More information

How Effective are Advertising Bans? On the Demand for Quality in Two-Sided Media Markets

How Effective are Advertising Bans? On the Demand for Quality in Two-Sided Media Markets How Effective are dvertising ans? On the Demand for Quality in Two-Sided Media Markets Tanja Greiner Marco Sahm CESIFO WORKING PPER NO. 3524 CTEGORY 11: INDUSTRIL ORGNISTION JULY 2011 n electronic version

More information

Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality

Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality Jay Pil Choi Doh-Shin Jeon Byung-Cheol Kim June 19, 2012 Abstract This paper analyzes competition between interconnected networks when content is heterogeneous

More information

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Carlo Reggiani Tommaso Valletti y 15th May 2011 - Very preliminary and incomplete Abstract Net neutrality is a hotly debated topic. A key point

More information

On the incentives of an integrated ISP to favor its own content

On the incentives of an integrated ISP to favor its own content On the incentives of an integrated ISP to favor its own content Duarte Brito y UNL and CEFAGE-UE dmb@fct.unl.pt Pedro Pereira z AdC and CEFAGE-UE pedro.br.pereira@gmail.com. João Vareda x European Commission

More information

Advertising versus Brokerage Model for Online Trading Platforms

Advertising versus Brokerage Model for Online Trading Platforms Advertising versus Brokerage Model for Online Trading Platforms Jianqing Chen The University of Texas at Dallas chenjq@utdallas.edu Ming Fan University of Washington mfan@uw.edu Mingzhi Li Tsinghua University

More information

«Internet access and investment incentives for broadband service providers»

«Internet access and investment incentives for broadband service providers» «Internet access and investment incentives for broadband service providers» Edmond BARANES Jean-Christophe POUDOU DR n 2011-09 Internet access and investment incentives for broadband service providers

More information

Microeconomics. Lecture Outline. Claudia Vogel. Winter Term 2009/2010. Part III Market Structure and Competitive Strategy

Microeconomics. Lecture Outline. Claudia Vogel. Winter Term 2009/2010. Part III Market Structure and Competitive Strategy Microeconomics Claudia Vogel EUV Winter Term 2009/2010 Claudia Vogel (EUV) Microeconomics Winter Term 2009/2010 1 / 25 Lecture Outline Part III Market Structure and Competitive Strategy 12 Monopolistic

More information

Strategic Investment Dependence and Net Neutrality

Strategic Investment Dependence and Net Neutrality Strategic Investment Dependence and Net Neutrality by Martin Nielsen Discussion Papers on Business and Economics No. 11/2015 FURTHER INFORMATION Department of Business and Economics Faculty of Business

More information

The New Trade Theory. Monopoly and oligopoly in trade. Luca De Benedictis 1. Topic 3. 1 University of Macerata

The New Trade Theory. Monopoly and oligopoly in trade. Luca De Benedictis 1. Topic 3. 1 University of Macerata The New Trade Theory Monopoly and oligopoly in trade Luca De Benedictis 1 1 University of Macerata Topic 3 A new generation of models Main characteristics and insights: Countries do not trade, rms do.

More information

PRIVATE AND SOCIAL INCENTIVES TO DISCRIMINATE IN OLIGOPOLY

PRIVATE AND SOCIAL INCENTIVES TO DISCRIMINATE IN OLIGOPOLY PRIVATE AND SOCIAL INCENTIVES TO DISCRIMINATE IN OLIGOPOLY by Norbert Schulz Universität Würzburg First version 3.08.99 This version 2.09.00 Abstract In an oligopoly model with switching costs firms have

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality

Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality 12-355 November 2012 Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality Jay Pil Choi, Doh-Shin Jeon and Byung-Cheol Kim Internet Interconnection and Network Neutrality Jay Pil Choi Doh-Shin Jeon Byung-Cheol

More information

Network Neutrality and Network Management Regulation: Quality of Service, Price Discrimination, and Exclusive Contracts

Network Neutrality and Network Management Regulation: Quality of Service, Price Discrimination, and Exclusive Contracts IFN Working Paper No. 890, 2011 Network Neutrality and Network Management Regulation: Quality of Service, Price Discrimination, and Exclusive Contracts Nicholas Economides and Joacim Tåg Research Institute

More information

Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection

Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection Jay Pil Choi Doh-Shin Jeon Byung-Cheol Kim July 18, 2013 Abstract We analyze the effect of net neutrality regulation in a two-sided market

More information

Network Neutrality and Congestion Sensitive Content Providers: Implications for Content Variety, Broadband Investment and Regulation

Network Neutrality and Congestion Sensitive Content Providers: Implications for Content Variety, Broadband Investment and Regulation Forthcoming at Information Systems Research manuscript ISR-2011-069 Network Neutrality and Congestion Sensitive Content Providers: Implications for Content Variety, Broadband Investment and Regulation

More information

Online Supplementary Material

Online Supplementary Material Online Supplementary Material The Supplementary Material includes 1. An alternative investment goal for fiscal capacity. 2. The relaxation of the monopoly assumption in favor of an oligopoly market. 3.

More information

The vertical differentiation model in the insurance market: costs structure and equilibria analysis

The vertical differentiation model in the insurance market: costs structure and equilibria analysis The vertical differentiation model in the insurance market: costs structure and equilibria analysis Denis V. Kuzyutin 1, Maria V. Nikitina, Nadezhda V. Smirnova and Ludmila N. Razgulyaeva 1 St.Petersburg

More information

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Elena Del Rey and Laura Romero October 004 Abstract In this paper we investigate the optimal choice of prices and/or exams by universities

More information

Optimal election of qualities in the presence of externalities

Optimal election of qualities in the presence of externalities Optimal election of qualities in the presence of externalities Dolores Garcia Maria Tugores October 2002 Abstract In this paper we obtain the quality and the level of production that a certain sector would

More information

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Chapter 9. Menu pricing Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2010 Chapter

More information

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines No 23 Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines Geza Sapi, Irina Suleymanova June 2011 IMPRINT DICE DISCUSSION PAPER Published by Heinrich

More information

Foreclosure, Entry, and Competition in Platform Markets with Cloud

Foreclosure, Entry, and Competition in Platform Markets with Cloud Foreclosure, Entry, and Competition in Platform Markets with Cloud Mark J. Tremblay Department of Economics Michigan State University E-mail: trembl22@msu.edu August 27, 2015 Abstract Platforms in two-sided

More information

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014) Intermediate Microeconomics (22014) I. Consumer Instructor: Marc Teignier-Baqué First Semester, 2011 Outline Part I. Consumer 1. umer 1.1 Budget Constraints 1.2 Preferences 1.3 Utility Function 1.4 1.5

More information

Technology platforms, such as Microsoft Windows, are the hubs of technology industries. We develop a

Technology platforms, such as Microsoft Windows, are the hubs of technology industries. We develop a MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 52, No. 7, July 2006, pp. 1057 1071 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 06 5207 1057 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0549 2006 INFORMS Two-Sided Competition of Proprietary vs. Open Source

More information

Working Paper Pricing Internet Traffic: Exclusion, Signalling and Screening

Working Paper Pricing Internet Traffic: Exclusion, Signalling and Screening econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Jullien,

More information

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 1 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing In this section we consider how firms compete when there are few sellers an oligopolistic market (from the Greek). Small

More information

Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly

Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University and Department of Economics, McGill University August 8, 009 Abstract Constructing

More information

Please Do not Circulate Preliminary and Incomplete Mixed Bundling and Imperfect Competition

Please Do not Circulate Preliminary and Incomplete Mixed Bundling and Imperfect Competition Abstract A model of two-product, Hotelling duopolists is examined in which firms can engage in mixed bundling. Even though products are independent in consumption, bundled pricing induces complementarity

More information

1 Monopoly Why Monopolies Arise? Monopoly is a rm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. The fundamental cause of monopoly is barriers to entry: A monopoly remains the only seller

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

2012 Advertising Models

2012 Advertising Models Either or both competition: a two-sided theory of advertising with overlapping viewerships Attila Ambrus Emilio Calvano Markus Reisinger September 2012 Keywords: Platform Competition, Two-Sided Markets,

More information

Pricing and Persuasive Advertising in a Differentiated Market

Pricing and Persuasive Advertising in a Differentiated Market Pricing and Persuasive Advertising in a Differentiated Market Baojun Jiang Olin Business School, Washington University in St. Louis, St. Louis, MO 63130, baojunjiang@wustl.edu Kannan Srinivasan Tepper

More information

Net Neutrality, Boon or Bane for Free File Sharing Service? (preliminary draft)

Net Neutrality, Boon or Bane for Free File Sharing Service? (preliminary draft) Net Neutrality, Boon or Bane for Free File Sharing Service? (preliminary draft) Tong Wang Florence School of Regulation, European University Institute June 29, 2012 Abstract In this paper, we establish

More information

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1 1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1 To be included in: Elmar Wolfstetter. Topics in Microeconomics: Industrial Organization, Auctions, and Incentives. Cambridge University Press, new edition,

More information

Knowledge Transfer and Partial Equity Ownership

Knowledge Transfer and Partial Equity Ownership Knowledge Transfer and Partial Equity Ownership Arghya Ghosh and Hodaka Morita School of Economics, UNSW Business School University of New South Wales 2nd ATE Symposium, UNSW, December 2014 Introduction

More information

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Daniel McFadden Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley April 8, 2002 I. This note is concerned with the economics of

More information

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract Interconnection Agreement between Internet Service Providers and the Optimal Policy Intervention: The Case of Cournot-type Competition under Network Externalities Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku

More information

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February 2013. Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February 2013. Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32 Advertising Sotiris Georganas February 2013 Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February 2013 1 / 32 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Main questions about advertising 3 How does advertising work? 4 Persuasive advertising

More information

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009 The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 010 October 009 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 408 The design and e ciency of loyalty rewards Ramon

More information

A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market

A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market Thomas CORTADE LASER-CREDEN, University of Montpellier Abstract: This paper looks at a new body of literature that deals with two-sided

More information

Paul Belleflamme, CORE & LSM, UCL

Paul Belleflamme, CORE & LSM, UCL International Workshop on Supply Chain Models for Shared Resource Management Managing inter- and intra-group externalities on two-sided platforms Paul Belleflamme, CORE & LSM, UCL 22/01/2010 FUSL, Brussels

More information

Why payment card fees are biased against merchants

Why payment card fees are biased against merchants Why payment card fees are biased against merchants Julian Wright November 2010 Abstract I formalize the popular argument that payment card networks such as MasterCard and Visa charge merchants too much

More information

University of Tübingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance No. 76

University of Tübingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance No. 76 University of Tübingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance No. 76 Strategic Investment, Forward Markets and Competition by Markus Aichele Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences www.wiwi.uni-tuebingen.de

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

Working Paper Does retailer power lead to exclusion?

Working Paper Does retailer power lead to exclusion? econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Rey, Patrick;

More information

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1202

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1202 Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1202 Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Carlo Reggiani Tommaso Valletti January 2012 Economics School of Social Sciences The University of Manchester

More information

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly WSG10 7/7/03 4:24 PM Page 145 10 Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly OVERVIEW An oligopoly is an industry comprising a few firms. A duopoly, which is a special case of oligopoly, is an industry consisting

More information

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information Hanna Hałaburda Yaron Yehezkel Working Paper 11-080 Copyright 2011 by Hanna Hałaburda and Yaron Yehezkel Working papers are in draft form. This working

More information

e-book Platform Competition in the Presence of Two-Sided Network Externalities

e-book Platform Competition in the Presence of Two-Sided Network Externalities 2012 45th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences e-book Platform Competition in the Presence of Two-Sided Network Externalities Yabing Jiang Graduate School of Business Administration Fordham

More information

Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-Air and Pay-TV s

Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-Air and Pay-TV s Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-to-Air and Pay-TV s Emilio Calvano CSEF - University of Naples Michele Polo Bocconi University, IEFE and IGIER October 2014 Preliminary and incomplete,

More information

Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design

Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design Dmitri Kuksov kuksov@haas.berkeley.edu University of California, Berkeley August, 2002 Abstract In many cases, buyers must incur search costs to find the

More information

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg Outline Alternative Market Models Wirtschaftswissenschaften Humboldt Universität zu Berlin March 5, 2006 Outline 1 Introduction Introduction Alternative Market Models 2 Game, Reaction Functions, Solution

More information

Why payment card fees are biased against retailers

Why payment card fees are biased against retailers Why payment card fees are biased against retailers Julian Wright June 2012 Abstract I formalize the popular argument that retailers pay too much and cardholders too little to make use of payment card platforms,

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

Frequent flyer programs and dynamic contracting with limited commitment

Frequent flyer programs and dynamic contracting with limited commitment Frequent flyer programs and dynamic contracting with limited commitment Emil Temnyalov March 14, 2015 Abstract I present a novel contract theoretic explanation of the profitability and management of loyalty

More information

Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection

Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Internet Interconnection Jay Pil Choi Doh-Shin Jeon Byung-Cheol Kim March 24, 2014 Abstract We analyze the effect of net neutrality regulation in a two-sided market

More information

IMPLICIT COLLUSION IN DEALER MARKETS WITH DIFFERENT COSTS OF MARKET MAKING ANDREAS KRAUSE Abstract. This paper introduces dierent costs into the Dutta-Madhavan model of implicit collusion between market

More information

Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit

Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit 1) Accountants include costs as part of a firm's costs, while economists include costs. A) explicit; no explicit B) implicit;

More information

Credit card interchange fees

Credit card interchange fees Credit card interchange fees Jean-Charles Rochet Julian Wright October 2009 Abstract We build a model of credit card pricing that explicitly takes into account credit functionality. In the model a monopoly

More information

Compatibility and Product Design in Software Markets Bernd Woeckener Department ofeconomics, University of Tubingen, Mohlstrae 36, 72074 Tubingen, Germany (woeckener@uni-tuebingen.de) Abstract This paper

More information

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.) Chapter Summary Now that you understand the model of a perfectly competitive market, this chapter complicates the

More information

Richard Schmidtke: Two-Sided Markets with Pecuniary and Participation Externalities

Richard Schmidtke: Two-Sided Markets with Pecuniary and Participation Externalities Richard Schmidtke: Two-Sided Markets with Pecuniary and Participation Externalities Munich Discussion Paper No. 2006-19 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Andrea Amelio and Dimitrios Magos ( 1 ) Introduction ( 1 ) This paper offers an economic background for the analysis conducted by the Commission during

More information

POMS Abstract - 020-0196

POMS Abstract - 020-0196 POMS Abstract - 020-0196 Optimal Pricing and Referral Reward Programs under Competition Run H. Niu School of Business and Technology Webster University St. Louis, Missouri, USA Paul R. Messinger School

More information

A Mobile Platform's Monetizing Strategy for Advertising. under Agency Pricing for App Sales. Notre Dame, IN, 46556 5646. Abstract

A Mobile Platform's Monetizing Strategy for Advertising. under Agency Pricing for App Sales. Notre Dame, IN, 46556 5646. Abstract A Mobile Platform's Monetizing Strategy for Advertising under Agency Pricing for App Sales Lin Hao 1 Hong Guo 1 Robert Easley 1 1 Department of Management, Mendoza College of Business, University of Notre

More information

Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives

Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives Jay Pil Choi y Byung-Cheol Kim z August 3, 2008 Abstract This paper analyzes the e ects of net neutrality regulation on investment incentives for Internet service

More information

Why do merchants accept payment cards?

Why do merchants accept payment cards? Why do merchants accept payment cards? Julian Wright National University of Singapore Abstract This note explains why merchants accept expensive payment cards when merchants are Cournot competitors. The

More information

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION FIRST Degree: The firm knows that it faces different individuals with different demand functions and furthermore the firm can tell who is who. In this case the firm extracts

More information

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 How Not to Win a Million Dollars: A Counterexample to a Conjecture of L. Breiman Thomas P. Hayes arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 Abstract Consider a gambling game in which we are allowed to repeatedly

More information

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC MARKET STRUCTURE AND INSIDER TRADING WASSIM DAHER AND LEONARD J. MIRMAN Abstract. In this paper we examine the real and financial effects of two insiders trading in a static Jain Mirman model (Henceforth

More information

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas Price Discrimination: Part 2 Sotiris Georganas 1 More pricing techniques We will look at some further pricing techniques... 1. Non-linear pricing (2nd degree price discrimination) 2. Bundling 2 Non-linear

More information

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds Internet Appendix for A Model of hadow Banking * At t = 0, a generic intermediary j solves the optimization problem: max ( D, I H, I L, H, L, TH, TL ) [R (I H + T H H ) + p H ( H T H )] + [E ω (π ω ) A

More information

Second degree price discrimination

Second degree price discrimination Bergals School of Economics Fall 1997/8 Tel Aviv University Second degree price discrimination Yossi Spiegel 1. Introduction Second degree price discrimination refers to cases where a firm does not have

More information

Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit.

Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit. Collusion. Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit. Price lower and industry output higher than in a monopoly. Firms lose because of non-cooperative behavior : Each

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Aomori Public College 153-4, Yamazaki, Goushizawa, Aomori-city, Aomori 030-0196, Japan March 01 Abstract We discuss the software

More information

Competition and Regulation. Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition

Competition and Regulation. Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition Competition and Regulation Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition Monopoly A monopolist maximizes its profits, choosing simultaneously quantity and prices, taking the Demand as a contraint; The

More information

Access Regulation with Asymmetric Termination Costs

Access Regulation with Asymmetric Termination Costs No 29 Access Regulation with Asymmetric Termination Costs Torben Stühmeier July 2011 IMPRINT DICE DISCUSSION PAPER Published by Heinrich Heine Universität Düsseldorf, Department of Economics, Düsseldorf

More information

Oligopoly and Trade. Notes for Oxford M.Phil. International Trade. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. November 26, 2009

Oligopoly and Trade. Notes for Oxford M.Phil. International Trade. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. November 26, 2009 Oligopoly and Trade Notes for Oxford M.Phil. International Trade J. Peter Neary University of Oxford November 26, 2009 J.P. Neary (University of Oxford) Oligopoly and Trade November 26, 2009 1 / 11 Oligopoly

More information

Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts

Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts Lisa L. Posey * Abstract: With large commercial accounts, a small number of insurers negotiate

More information

A Comparison of the Wholesale Structure and the Agency Structure in Differentiated Markets

A Comparison of the Wholesale Structure and the Agency Structure in Differentiated Markets A Comparison of the Wholesale Structure and the Agency Structure in Differentiated Markets Liang Lu * School of Economics and the Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ,

More information

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 Thursday 22nd NOVEMBER, 12.05-12.55 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II Candidates should attempt

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Andrea Attar Thomas Mariotti François Salanié October 2007 Abstract In order to check the impact of the exclusivity regime on equilibrium allocations,

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives

Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives Jay Pil Choi y Byung-Cheol Kim z March 9, 00 Abstract This paper analyzes the e ects of net neutrality regulation on investment incentives for Internet service

More information

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Overview I. Basic

More information

E-listing As a Competing Mechanism For Search Engine Marketing Success

E-listing As a Competing Mechanism For Search Engine Marketing Success Interplay Between Organic Listing and Sponsored Bidding in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Red McCombs School of Business, The University of Texas at Austin University Station B6500, Austin, Texas, 7872 Phone:

More information

An Analysis of A Mobile Platform's In-App Advertising. Contract under Agency Pricing for App Sales ABSTRACT

An Analysis of A Mobile Platform's In-App Advertising. Contract under Agency Pricing for App Sales ABSTRACT An Analysis of A Mobile Platform's In-App Advertising Contract under Agency Pricing for App Sales Lin Hao 1 Hong Guo 1 Rob Easley 1 1 Mendoza College of Business, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame,

More information

The Prison S Dilemma and Its Connections

The Prison S Dilemma and Its Connections Games Played in a Contracting Environment V. Bhaskar Department of Economics University College London Gower Street London WC1 6BT February 2008 Abstract We analyze normal form games where a player has

More information

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy After reading Chapter 7, MONOPOLY, OLIGOPOLY AND STRATEGY, you should be able to: Define the characteristics of Monopoly and Oligopoly, and explain why the are

More information