Efficient Market Management - naked Credit Default swaps (CDS), and investor Risk

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Efficient Market Management - naked Credit Default swaps (CDS), and investor Risk"

Transcription

1 Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? Agostino Capponi Martin Larsson Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract We develop a tractable partial equilibrium model to analyze the impact on the bond market generated by a ban on naked credit default swaps. We demonstrate that such a ban will have a negligible impact on the borrowing costs if CDS speculators are risk averse and take positions which are small relatively to the amount of debt outstanding. We find that the ban only excludes from the market moderately pessimistic investors, and induces the most pessimistic to implement their strategy on the short side of the bond market. Despite the sovereign debtor benefits from the reduced yields on the issued bonds, he will suffer from a diminished borrowing capacity after the ban. Such findings suggest that regulators should consider other measures to reduce instability arising from excessive speculation in derivatives markets. Keywords Partial Equilibrium sovereign debt credit default swaps trading restrictions JEL Classification D5 E4 E5 Agostino Capponi gratefully acknowledges the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET), which supported his research under the grant number IN Martin Larsson gratefully acknowledges funding from the European Research Council under the European Union s Seventh Framework Programme (FP/ ) / ERC Grant Agreement n POLYTE. A. Capponi Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD, acappon1@jhu.edu M. Larsson Swiss Finance Institute, Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne, Lausanne, Switzerland martin.larsson@epfl.ch

2 2 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson 1 Introduction The recent financial crisis has shown that derivative instruments, while allowing for efficient hedging and risk transfer, can also pose serious threats to financial stability. Governmental and regulator authorities have blamed derivatives, especially over-the-counter credit derivatives, to have contributed to making the financial system more complex and opaque, see Gordy and Willemann (2010), and exacerbated the market panic during the crisis. Most recently, a number of policy makers and regulator authorities have expressed concerns regarding sophisticated market players entering uncovered or naked positions in credit default swaps (CDS). Such portfolio positions, where an investor purchases CDS protection without holding the commensurate amount of the underlying bond instrument, is viewed by critics as a way to speculate on the health of the particular entity. This has been claimed to be responsible for raising the borrowing costs of many issuers of government debt, such as Greece, and worried regulators that naked CDS could pose a systemic risk to the overall economy. For this reason, a decision to reduce, and in some extreme cases ban outright the use of this practice, has been taken. 1 This also initiated a debate among economists regarding whether a ban on naked sovereign CDS should be imposed. Portes (2010) and Soros (2009) argued in favor of it, claiming that naked speculation causes a rise in CDS prices, and consequently increases the cost of funding of the underlying sovereign entity. On the other hand, influential researchers such as Duffie (2010) and Jarrow (2010) argued against the ban, claiming that it reduces market liquidity and raises trading execution costs, thereby lowering the quality of information contained in CDS prices, see also Gorton (2010). Our paper belongs to the stream of literature studying the impact of credit default swaps on financial stability. Sovereign CDS trading may affect bond prices in two ways. Firstly, it may introduce feedback effects affecting the fundamentals of the reference country and consequently impact the primary market for bond issuance. This aspect has been partly addressed by existing literature, some of which surveyed next. Secondly, it has been questioned whether CDS trading restrictions can affect the price of sovereign bonds in the secondary market. This question has recently received significant attention, given the expressed concerns that short positions on credit risk through naked CDS can be detrimental for market stability. Our goal is to make a first step towards providing a complete analysis to answer such a question. To this purpose, we develop a tractable partial equilibrium model, where investors with heterogenous default beliefs and mean-variance preferences can trade two credit risky securities, namely a bond and a credit default swap, both referenc- 1 The German Chancellor Angela Merkel effectuated a ban on naked short-selling of Euro bonds on May 25, 2010, as well as prohibited naked CDS on bonds of European governments and short-selling of shares in ten major German financial institutions. A similar action was taken by the EU, who banned naked CDS on sovereign debt with a regulation adopted on November 15, 2011.

3 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 3 ing the same entity. It is partial because we do not consider the interaction of the CDS market with other market activities, such as the cross-hedging use of CDS by investors holding other risky assets characterized by various degrees of correlation with the risk of sovereign debt. Our results indicate that naked CDS speculation would only have a negligible impact on the underlying bond price if CDS manipulators take positions not exceeding significantly the amount of outstanding debt. Notice that this is indeed the case for the financially weaker Eurozone sovereigns, where the aggregate net CDS positions represent small fractions of their respective amounts of debt outstanding. 2 Such conclusions are also in line with empirical findings of Duffie (2010), who does not see any significant relationship between amounts of CDS referencing Greece, Italy, Ireland, Spain, Portugal and the borrowing costs of these sovereigns. Moreover, they are consistent with the evidence reported by Ashcraft et al (2009), showing that on average bond prices are not impacted by CDS trading activities. Although the ban has been introduced to remedy the instability caused by excessive speculation in financially distressed periods, we demonstrate that this is not the case if investors are pessimistic and risk averse. As we illustrate later in the paper, the ban would only exclude some moderately pessimistic investors from the market, those for which the expected gain from a short bond position is now swamped by the larger transaction cost. Highly pessimistic investors will still implement their activity on the short side of the bond market. The prohibition of naked CDS may therefore have a marginal effect on changes in bond prices, and at the same time can impact the liquidity of the CDS market by reducing the number of participants. Moreover, despite the fact that after the ban the sovereign debtor benefits from reduced yields on the issued bonds, he would still suffer from a diminished borrowing capacity, and ultimately see his expected wealth decrease. Previous research by Bolton and Oehmke (2011) demonstrates that CDS have important ex-ante commitment benefits because they increase investment and eliminate strategic default, but also show that creditors generally tend to overinsure, thus resulting in an empty creditor problem, see also Hu and Black (2008) for related analysis, and Subrahmanyam et al (2012) for an empirical illustration. Ashcraft et al (2009) show that, perhaps counter-intuitively, the firms that have benefited the most from CDSs are the safest and less exposed to default risk. Indeed, for such firms, the CDS is more liquid and they tend to pay lower interest once CDSs are written on their bonds. Che and Sethi (2012) show that naked credit default swaps can have a significant effect on borrowing costs and likelihood of default. They develop a mechanism according to which pessimists about future prospects of the borrower would buy naked protection 2 In the case of Greece, the aggregate of the net CDS positions held in the entire market has remained well under 3% of the total amount of Greek debt outstanding. Furthermore, Duffie (2010) documents that since 2008 there was never an increase in aggregate CDS positions on Greece that was more than 0.18% of Greek debt outstanding.

4 4 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson from those who are more optimistic, asking them to post cash collateral to eliminate counterparty risk. Such collateral is financed by a third class of investors who shift the terms of financing against the borrower, and for a given borrowing requirement ask for larger bond issue and smaller bond price. When only covered credit default swaps are allowed, such investors become less pessimistic and consequently the terms of lending are shifted in favor of the borrower, thus resulting in a smaller bond issue and larger bond price. Our model is designed to capture empirical features, which are typical of sovereign CDS markets. According to statistics reported in (IMF 2010, Annex 1.2), dealers in the sovereign CDS market are net sellers of credit protection and do so for hedging purposes, while investors (real money and hedge funds) are net buyers of protection. Although dealers represents about 90% of the sovereign CDS markets, with investors only accounting for the remaining 10%, we consider the case where they have a equal share of the CDS market, in order to assess the impact of CDS speculation on the bond market under scenarios of extreme speculation. More specifically, we assume that investors can only buy credit default swaps, while market makers can only sell CDS. An investor who wishes to go long credit risk may do so by purchasing the bond security, while an investor who wants to short credit can do so by either buying (possibly naked) CDS or by short-selling the bond security. We remark, however, that the model we develop is general and can be used to analyze the price impact that trading restrictions in credit derivatives market would have on (not necessarily sovereign) bond markets. Both bond and CDS trades require the intermediation of market makers, whose main function is to provide liquidity to the market. In the sovereign bond market, most market participants have a dual role as market makers and investors (see Table 1 in Cheung et al (2005)). In our model, we therefore let bond trades happen directly across investors, without explicitly modeling the intermediation. In contrast, there are few market participants willing to meet the high demand for sovereigns CDS, as argued above. Moreover, Austin and Miller (2011) demonstrate that traders in the CDS market generally do not have market making responsibilities. To this purpose, we consider the stylized situation where there is only one market maker in the CDS market. CDS market makers typically hedge their exposure. As documented in Boone et al (2010), in the sovereign case this is generally done using either government bonds, or offsetting CDS transactions. However, in times of crisis, the rarity of market makers or investors willing to sell protection can make the bond a more attractive hedging instrument. 3 Our model aims to capture this by requiring the CDS market maker to maintain a riskless position by perfectly hedging his CDS exposure using sovereign bonds. We additionally assume that he has a competitive advantage deriving from the possibility to short-sell bonds at low cost, and strategically set the CDS premium to maximize his wealth. 3 We also remark that, although the equity options market can be used to hedge corporate credit exposure approximately, this is much harder to do for sovereign credit exposure.

5 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 5 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the model and provides some preliminary results. Section 3 recovers the optimal strategies of the investors, taking prices as fixed. Section 4 analyzes the market maker activity, while Section 5 recovers the equilibrium prices of the securities in the model. We perform a comparative statics analysis in Section 6 to assess the economic implications of our findings and the impact of the ban on the bond market. 2 The model We consider an economy where three assets trade. There are two credit sensitive assets, and one risk-free asset. The risky assets are the defaultable bond, and a credit default swap written on that bond. The risk-free asset is used as the numeraire, meaning the unit in which all payoffs will be measured. We assume that the risk-free asset pays no interest. There are two time periods, t = 0 and t = 1. The following table gives the prices and payoff structure of the two risky assets, whose prices will be determined endogenously in our partial equilibrium model. Asset Price at t = 0 Payoff at t = 1 Defaultable bond P b 1 {no default} CDS P c 1 {default} There is clearly a redundancy in this system of payoffs: in the absence of trading restrictions, simultaneous holding of one unit of the defaultable bond and of the CDS is equivalent to holding one unit of the risk-free asset. However, we will also assume that there is a cost associated with short-selling the defaultable bond. This will ultimately induce pessimistic market participants (i.e., agents perceiving a high default probability) to bet on default by investing in the CDS. This short-selling cost will be described momentarily. There are n + 1 agents in the economy, each endowed with an initial wealth w i. Agents 1,..., n are investors who maximize mean-variance utility over the absolute return on their portfolios. The investors are heterogeneous both regarding their attitude towards risk, and their beliefs concerning the probability of default. They can invest in all the assets, but are not allowed to hold a short position in the CDS. This is the function of the market maker, which is the zeroth agent i = 0. The market maker is required to maintain a riskless position (so in particular there will be no counterparty risk in this model), as well as meeting the demand for CDS. Therefore, we have market

6 6 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson segmentation with respect to the CDS asset: investors are only allowed to stay on the long side, while the market maker can only stay on the short side of the market. In our market, therefore, there are two ways for the investors of being short credit risk: (1) short-selling the bond security, and (2) buying the credit default swap. Since the market maker s portfolio is riskless, his wealth at t = 1 is deterministic. Due to his monopoly power with the respect to CDS asset, he can set the price P c of the CDS in such a way to maximize his wealth, while taking into account how his choice will affect investor demand. In this sense, the market maker has some market power, because he correctly accounts for the impact his choice of P c has on CDS demand, but he acts as a price taker with respect to the defaultable bond (that is, he regards P b as fixed). As already mentioned, there is a short-selling cost associated with the defaultable bond. Specifically, the market maker pays an amount δ for every bond he sells short. For the investors, the per-bond cost is δ. In our model, the short-selling costs are exogenous deadweight losses, as they only dissipate part of the total welfare without causing wealth redistribution. We refer the reader to Duffie (1996) for endogenous models of short-selling costs, and to Bongaerts et al (2011) for the impact of short-selling costs on asset liquidity, in equilibrium models with zero net supply assets. We assume that 0 < δ < δ, and the fact that it is cheaper for the market maker to short-sell bonds is what allows him to profit on the CDS market: investors who wish to bet on default will try to avoid the higher cost δ by instead purchasing the CDS. This will remain beneficial even if the market maker charges a premium strictly higher than δ (but no higher than δ.) Finally, since our goal is to study the impact of banning naked CDS positions, we will also consider this additional constraint. More precisely, we look at two different versions of the model: one that is as described above; and one where we impose the additional restriction that any long position in the CDS must be accompanied by a long position of at least equal size in the bond. Before proceeding further, we introduce some notation. We denote by q i = (qi b, qc i, qr i ) the vector of quantities held by the i-th agent. Here, qb i and qc i are the quantities held in the defaultable bond and CDS, while qi r is the quantity held in the risk-free asset. Further, we write P = (P b, P c, 1), where P b and P c are the prices of a single unit of defaultable bond and CDS, respectively, which will be determined in equilibrium, while the third component is the price of a single unit of the numeraire asset (which is one by definition). We now describe the preferences and beliefs of the investors, i = 1,..., n, as well as the optimization problem they face. Investor i seeks to determine a vector q i of quantities that he wishes to hold for each of the assets. His aim is

7 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 7 to solve min q γ i 2 q Σ i q µ i q s.t. P q + δ (q b ) = w i q c 0, where x = max( x, 0) denotes the negative part, and Σ i and µ i denote the covariance matrix and mean vector of the payoffs. 4 If we let π i = P i [default] be the i th investor s subjective probability that the reference entity defaults, the covariance matrix and expected payoffs are given by π i (1 π i ) π i (1 π i ) Σ i = π i (1 π i ) π i (1 π i ) 0 = π i (1 π i ) and µ i = 1 π i π i. 1 In particular, the subjective default probabilities π i and the risk-aversion parameters γ i completely characterize the preferences of the investors. It will be convenient to label them from the most optimistic to the most pessimistic, so that 0 < π 1 π 2 π n < 1. When the ban on naked CDS positions is in place, the investors have to adhere to the following additional constraint: (q b ) + q c (naked CDS ban), where x + = max(x, 0) denotes positive part. The market maker s budget constraint is of the same form as the investors, except that his short-selling cost for the bond is δ. If his portfolio quantities are denoted q 0 = (q b 0, q c 0, q r 0), the budget constraint is P q 0 + δ(q b 0) = w 0. Moreover, the requirement that his portfolio be riskless and that he meet the CDS demand yields the restrictions n q0 b = q0 c and q0 c = qi c. 4 We can work with payoffs instead of absolute returns. Indeed, the latter are given by the payoffs minus the expected payoffs, hence have the same covariances. Moreover, since the budget constraint is binding, the total expected absolute return is µ i q w i, and we change nothing by dropping the constant term w i from the objective function. The budget constraint is binding due to the existence of the risk-free asset. i=1

8 8 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson The defaultable bond is in fixed positive supply, denoted by α, while the credit default swap asset is available in zero net supply. The supply of the numeraire asset, β, is endogenously given by aggregate feasibility: the aggregate expenditure plus the short-selling costs incurred must equal the aggregate initial wealth netted of the position in the numeraire asset. Thus, the market clearing conditions are given by αp b + δ(q b 0) + δ n i=1 n qi b = α (1) i=0 (q b i ) + β = w, (2) where w = w 0 + w w n is the aggregate wealth. We make the following mild assumptions. Market with deep pockets. The market is sufficiently rich, i.e. it has enough initial aggregate wealth w that all transactions can be financed using the wealth inside the system. In other words, the aggregate net supply β of the numeraire asset is positive. Sufficient heterogeneity. The market is sufficiently heterogeneous in terms of beliefs and risk preferences that trades are triggered, and the system is well functioning. One of our goals is to provide conditions on the model primitives under which these conditions are satisfied. To this end, we develop a number of preliminary results, which will be used later to characterize the behavior of investors in equilibrium. We start with the following Lemma, whose proof is reported in Appendix A. Lemma 1 The market maker s final wealth is given by w 0 + ( P b + P c 1 δ ) n qi c. (3) Before computing optimal quantities and prices, it is useful to characterize the participation constraints. Indeed, trading will only take place if both sides of the market are able to extract positive surplus: for the market maker, this means that the price of the CDS has to be large enough to compensate the short-selling costs that he will incur for perfectly hedging his exposure via short-sale of bonds. For the investor, the price of the CDS cannot be too high, otherwise he could achieve the same objective of going short credit risk by short-selling bonds even if this comes with the short-selling cost δ. The next lemma fully characterizes the participation constraints. Lemma 2 (i) If P b + P c 1 > δ, then no investor buys the CDS. i=1

9 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 9 (ii) In equilibrium, the market maker may restrict his choice of P c to satisfy δ P b + P c 1 δ. Any other choice of P c results in a final wealth less than or equal to w 0. (iii) If P b + P c 1 < δ and naked CDS positions are allowed, then no investor has a short position in the bond. The proof of this lemma is reported in Appendix A. The following is a trivial but useful bound on the bond price P b, whose proof is reported in Appendix A. Lemma 3 In any equilibrium, P b < 1. In view of Lemma 2, it is reasonable to restrict attention to equilibria in which the participation constraint (condition of Lemma 2(ii)) is satisfied. Moreover, when naked CDS positions are allowed, we conjecture that no investor takes a short position in the bond. The above condition does not directly guarantee this because, when P b +P c 1 = δ, the investors are indifferent between shortselling the bond and purchasing the CDS. Notice that investors can profit both from activities in the bond and CDS market, while the market maker profits exclusively from selling CDS protection. Consequently, we naturally allow for a tie-breaking benefit offered by the market maker to induce investors wishing to short credit to purchase CDS protection. Hence, Ansatz. In equilibrium, the market maker chooses P c so that δ P b + P c 1 δ. (4) Moreover, when naked CDS positions are allowed, all investors have nonnegative bond positions: qi b 0, i = 1,..., n. We notice that deviation from this Ansatz would result in the market maker setting the CDS price so as to decrease the level of his initial wealth after implementing his protection selling activity (see Lemma 2). As he knows that market participants will always prefer the CDS security over a short bond position if P b +P c 1 δ, then it is natural to restrict attention to equilibria where this Ansatz is satisfied. 3 Optimal investor quantities This section derives the optimal quantities of securities held by investors, taking prices as fixed. We solve the investor optimization problem when naked protection is allowed in Section 3.1, and when the ban is imposed in Section 3.2.

10 10 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson 3.1 Naked CDS allowed Under our Ansatz, all bond positions are nonnegative in the case where naked CDS positions are allowed. No short-selling costs are therefore incurred, so the budget constraint for the i th investor simply becomes q P = w i. Substituting for q r in the objective function yields the new objective f i (q b, q c ) = γ i 2 π i(1 π i )(q b q c ) 2 + π i (q b q c ) q b ( w i q b P b q c P c), which is minimized subject to q b 0, q c 0. We expect that typical speculators would compare their beliefs about the default probability with the market estimates resulting from bond and CDS prices. They would then decide to implement their speculation activity in the bond or in the CDS market, taking into account the outcome of this comparison and the banning restriction, when the latter is in place. The following result shows that this is indeed the case by giving the optimal quantities, and indicating how they depend on the relation between the prevailing market prices and the investor beliefs. Proposition 1 Under the assumption of no short bond positions, no short CDS positions, and P b + P c > 1, the optimal quantities q i of investor i are unique, and given as follows: (i) If π i < P c and 1 π i P b, then q b i = (ii) If π i P c, then 1 ( 1 πi P b), qi c = 0. (5) γ i π i (1 π i ) q b i = 0, q c i = (iii) If π i < P c and 1 π i < P b, then 1 γ i π i (1 π i ) (π i P c ). (6) q b i = 0, q c i = 0. (7) The optimal holding in the risk-free asset, qi r, is then given via the budget constraint. The proof of Proposition 1 is reported in Appendix B. The three investor types corresponding to case (i) (iii) in Proposition 1 can be interpreted, respectively, as optimistic, pessimistic, and what one may call bearish. The pessimistic investor (type (ii)) believes that default is more likely than recognized by the CDS market, and thus finds the CDS attractive. From the point of view of the

11 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 11 optimistic investor (type (i)), the CDS is overpriced, but the survival probability is larger than priced by the bond market. As such, he finds the bond an attractive instrument. The bearish investor (type (iii)) views both the bond and the CDS as overpriced, and therefore does not invest in either. Instead he puts all his wealth in the risk-free asset. To simplify terminology, when we refer to an investor as optimistic, it will be understood that he holds a strictly positive quantity of bonds. Similarly, pessimistic investors hold strictly positive quantities of CDS. 3.2 Naked CDS banned When naked CDS positions are no longer allowed, the conclusion of Lemma 2(iii) is no longer valid. The budget constraint of investor i is therefore This leads to the objective function P q + δ (q b ) = w i. f i (q b, q c ) = γ i 2 π i(1 π i )(q b q c ) 2 +π i (q b q c ) q b ( w i q b P b q c P c δ (q b ) ). We can now characterize the optimal quantities in this case. Proposition 2 Under the assumption of no short CDS positions, no naked CDS positions, and P b + P c > 1, the optimal quantities q i of investor i are unique, and given as follows: (i) If 1 π i P b, then q b i = 1 ( 1 πi P b), qi c = 0. (8) γ i π i (1 π i ) (ii) If P b δ < 1 π i < P b, then q b i = 0, q c i = 0. (9) (iii) If 1 π i P b δ, then qi b 1 ( = P b δ ) 1 + π i, γ i π i (1 π i ) q c i = 0. (10) The optimal holding in the risk-free asset, q i r, is then given via the budget constraint.

12 12 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson The proof of Proposition 2 is reported in Appendix B. Remark. When the naked CDS ban is imposed, the investor types change. The condition in (i) is now enough to yield an optimistic investor who invests in the defaultable bond. If the condition is violated, the investor will no longer go long the bond, and as a consequence of the naked CDS ban, will not invest in the CDS. However, he may decide to short sell the bond. This happens when he perceives default to be so likely that the short selling cost does not deter him from going short. If the investor decides to hold zero quantity of the defaultable bond (case (ii) in Proposition 2), we call him moderately pessimistic. If, instead, he decides to go short in the defaultable bond (case (iii) in Proposition 2), we call him highly pessimistic. 4 The market maker The market maker chooses a portfolio q 0 = (q b 0, q c 0, q r 0) and the CDS premium P c, such that his final wealth is maximized, his portfolio is riskless, his budget constraint is satisfied, and he meets the investors demand for CDS. As already mentioned, he acts as a price taker with respect to the defaultable bond, and therefore treats P b as fixed. We first consider the setup where naked CDS positions are allowed, and then discuss the case when the ban is introduced. We start with the general case of n investors, and then specialize it to the case n = Naked CDS allowed Suppose there is no ban on naked CDS. By Proposition 1, we have q c i = 1 γ i π i (1 π i ) (π i P c ) + for i = 1,..., n. Substituting this into the expression for the final wealth of the market maker, see (3), and recalling Lemma 2(ii), we see that the market maker chooses P c as a solution to max x 0 { (x + P b 1 δ ) n i=1 (π i x) + γ i π i (1 π i ) : δ x + P b 1 δ }. (11) The optimal value is the profit, i.e. the amount by which the market maker s final wealth exceeds w 0. In order for the market maker to be active, there must be at least one investor who buys the bond (long credit), and another investor who buys the CDS (short credit). Indeed, if there were no investors buying protection, the market

13 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 13 maker would not have any function and simply deposit all his wealth in the risk-free asset. If, instead, there were no investors buying the bond security, then the market maker would not be able to maintain his riskless position, as no investor would buy the bonds that he is short-selling to hedge his credit exposure. The following lemma establishes this intuitive result, and thus allows one to reduce the number of scenarios to consider with respect to investor types (optimistic, pessimistic, or bearish). The proof is reported in Appendix C. Lemma 4 Suppose that, in equilibrium, the market maker acts in such a way that his final wealth is strictly greater than w 0. Then there is necessarily at least one optimistic and at least one pessimistic investor. We now focus attention on the case of two investors, n = 2, with π 1 < π 2. In this setting, the market maker s optimization problem becomes tractable and can be solved explicitly. By Lemma 4 we know that there must be one optimistic and one pessimistic investor in equilibrium. It is then clear that i = 1 will be the optimistic investor, and i = 2 the pessimistic one. We then have the following proposition, proven in Appendix C. Proposition 3 Let n = 2, assume that naked CDS positions are allowed, and suppose that 1 π 2 < P b δ < 1 + π 2. (12) Then, in equilibrium, the market maker s optimal choice of P c is strictly positive and given by ( δ P P c b ) + (1 + π 2 ) = min, δ P b + 1. (13) 2 If (12) fails, the market maker s final wealth is necessarily at most w 0. Proposition 3 indicates that in determining the CDS price the market maker will give equal weight 1 2 to (1) the minimum selling price 1 P b + δ needed to ensure that he profits from his protection selling activity, and (2) the subjective probability π 2 of the pessimistic investor. When the latter probability is high, the pessimistic investor will have higher incentive to purchase protection and hence the market maker can increase the price further. 4.2 Naked CDS banned Let us now consider what happens when the CDS ban is introduced. According to Proposition 2, there will be no CDS holding whenever P b + P c > 1. On the other hand, as shown in Section 2, choosing P c so that this inequality fails is worse for the market maker than simply investing all his wealth in the

14 14 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson risk-free asset. This will indeed be the case, given the market maker s budget constraint and the requirement that he hold a riskless portfolio. Therefore, the price of the CDS will not be uniquely determined when the naked CDS ban is in force. We only know that it certainly could not be low enough for the CDS to become an attractive investment; this would at the very least require P b + P c 1, which would be inconsistent with the optimal choice on the side of the market maker. 5 Equilibrium market prices We compute the equilibrium prices of the securities, along with the endogenous supply of the numeraire asset. When naked positions are allowed, this amounts to computing the price of the defaultable bond and of the credit default swap, whereas in the case where naked protection is banned, the price of the CDS will not be uniquely determined, given that no trade takes place (see Proposition 2). Throughout the section, we assume two investors and one market maker. 5.1 Naked CDS allowed The following result gives necessary and sufficient conditions on (P b, P c ), in terms of the model primitives, guaranteeing that they correspond to a wellbehaved equilibrium. Proposition 4 In order for strictly positive prices (P b, P c ) to generate an equilibrium where the Ansatz of Section 2 is satisfied and the market maker has a final wealth strictly greater than w 0, the following conditions are necessary and sufficient: as well as δ < P b + P c 1 δ, (14) π 1 < P c, 1 π 1 > P b, π 2 > P c, (15) P b γ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ) 1 π 2 < P b δ < 1 + π 2, (16) P c γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) = 1 γ 1 π 1 1 γ 2 (1 π 2 ) α (17) and ( δ P P c b ) + (1 + π 2 ) = min, δ P b + 1. (18) 2

15 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 15 The proof of Proposition 4 is reported in Appendix D. From Eq. (15) we obtain that 1 π 1 + π 2 > P b + P c. Using Eq. (14), we deduce that π 2 π 1 > δ. (19) Eq. (17) states that the price of the bond measured in units of risk weighted variance of the default belief of the optimistic investor equals the price of the CDS measured in units of risk weighted variance of the default belief of the pessimistic investor plus an adjustment factor. Such a factor is decreasing in the risk weighted default probabilities perceived by the optimistic and pessimistic investor, and obviously decreasing in the bond supply, given that higher supply contributes to decreasing the price of each bond unit. Remark 1 Eq. (17) shows that P c is an affine function of P b. This function is unbounded and strictly increasing, whereas the right side of Eq. (18) is an unbounded strictly decreasing function of P b. The system (17) (18) thus has a solution with P b > 0 if and only if ( ) 1 δ γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) min π2, δ > α + 2 γ 2 (1 π 2 ) 1. γ 1 π 1 This solution is unique. Through elementary but cumbersome verifications of the conditions in Proposition 4 (which may be done with the help of software packages such as Mathematica), it can be checked that, if there is sufficient heterogeneity in the sense that π 2 π 1 > δ and 0 < α < ᾱ := π 2 π 1 δ γ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ), then the equilibrium prices are positive and given as follows. Define the relative risk-weighted variance as ν = γ 2π 2 (1 π 2 ) γ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ), (20) and set Then we have δ = δ 1 + ν 1 + 2ν + ν ( ) π 2 π 1 αγ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ) ν (i) If δ > δ and α < α, then P b = 1 [ ( 1 δ + γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) + 2 ) ] 2α 1 + 2ν γ 2 π 2 γ 1 π 1 (21) P c = 1 [ ] π 2 + αγ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) + ν(π 1 + π 2 + δ). (22) 1 + 2ν

16 16 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson (ii) If δ < δ δ and α > 0, then P b = ν [ δ + γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) ( ) ] α γ 2 π 2 γ 1 π 1 (23) P c = δ + 1 P b (24) In both cases, the endogenous supply β of the numeraire asset is given by β = w αp b δ ( π 2 P c). γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) If the aggregate wealth w is large enough to make β > 0, then the market with deep pockets assumption made in Section 2 is satisfied. Remark 2 Eq. (6) indicates that the number of CDS units purchased by the pessimistic investor decreases as the price of the CDS increases. From (24), we can see that as the short selling costs incurred by the investors get higher, the price of the CDS rises. All this suggests that in an environment where transaction costs are high, investors will be more reluctant to purchase the CDS, resulting in a diminished speculation activity. This is in the same spirit as the Tobin tax, introduced in the foreign exchange market on all spot conversions of one currency into another, to reduce volatility induced by exchange rate speculation. We notice that the bond price and CDS premium are continuous in δ. Indeed, at δ = δ the bond prices given by Eq. (21) and (23) coincide, and the CDS prices given by Eq. (22) and (24) coincide. 5.2 Naked CDS banned The following result is the analog of Proposition 4 for the case with naked CDS ban. We continue to consider the case of one market maker and two investors. Proposition 5 Assume naked CDS positions are banned. In order for strictly positive prices (P b, P c ) to generate an equilibrium where the Ansatz of Section 2 is satisfied and where there is one optimistic and one moderately pessimistic investor, the following conditions are necessary and sufficient: P b = (1 π 1 )(1 αγ 1 π 1 ) and α < 1 γ 1, (25) and P b δ < 1 π 2 < P b, (26) δ P b + P c 1 δ. (27)

17 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 17 The proof of Proposition 5 is reported in Appendix D. Proposition 6 Assume naked CDS positions are banned. In order for strictly positive prices (P b, P c ) to generate an equilibrium where the Ansatz of Section 2 is satisfied and where there is one optimistic and one highly pessimistic investor, the following conditions are necessary and sufficient: ( ) P b 1 γ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ) + 1 γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) and = δ + γ 1 π 1 γ 2 π 2 γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) α > 0, (28) 1 π 1 > P b, 1 π 2 < P b δ, (29) δ P b + P c 1 δ. (30) The proof of Proposition 6 is reported in Appendix D. Remark 3 Note that the CDS price P c is not uniquely determined in the case with naked CDS ban. We only get the bounds in (27) respectively (30). Similarly to Section 5.1, one can verify the conditions in Propositions 5 and 6, under the following sufficient heterogeneity condition: π 2 π 1 > δ and 0 < α < ᾱ := π 2 π 1 γ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ). Defining the relative risk-weighted variance ν as in (20), and δ = π 2 π 1 αγ 1 π 1 (1 π 1 ), we have that the equilibrium price of the defaultable security is then positive and given as follows. (i) If α < α and δ δ, then P b = (1 π 1 )(1 αγ 1 π 1 ) (31) and the endogenous supply β of the numeraire asset is given by β = w + α(1 π 1 ) (αγ 1 π 1 1) (ii) If δ < δ < δ and α > 0, then P b = ν [ δ + γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 ) ( ) ] α γ 2 π 2 γ 1 π 1 (32) and the endogenous supply β of the numeraire asset is given by β = w αp b δ ) (P b δ 1 + π 2. γ 2 π 2 (1 π 2 )

18 18 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson In addition, if the aggregate wealth w is large enough to make β > 0, the market with deep pockets assumption made in Section 2 is satisfied. As expected the bond price P b is continuous with respect to δ. Indeed, it can be checked that at δ, where the investor switches from highly to moderately pessimistic, the bond prices from Eq. (31) and (32) coincide. 6 Comparative Statics Analysis We evaluate the economic implications of the results derived in the previous sections. We remark that the quantities of bonds purchased by the optimist equal the amount of bonds issued plus the magnitude of the market-maker s short position: some optimistic investors own real bonds issued by the sovereign debtor, and some are counterparties to the market maker. Results are presented under two different scenarios. A normal scenario where π 1 = 0.01 and π 2 = 0.1, and a crisis scenario, where π 1 = 0.05 and π 2 = Denote by W1 N and W2 N the optimal wealth of the optimistic and pessimistic investor, respectively, at the end of the period in the regime where naked CDS are allowed. Then, the subjective expected wealth positions of the two investors, given their own beliefs, are given by E [ π1 W1 N ] = w1 + q1( b 1 π 1 P b), E π2 [ W N 2 ] = w2 + q c 2( π 2 P c), where q1 b and q2 c are given, respectively, by Eq. (5) and (6), and P b and P c are given by Eq. (21) (22), or Eq. (23) (24), depending on the values of δ, δ, and α. Similarly, let W1 NN and W2 NN denote the optimal wealths when naked CDS positions are banned. Then E [ π1 W1 NN ] = w1 + q1( b 1 π 1 P b), E [ π2 W2 NN ] = w2 + q2( b 1 π 2 P b) δ (q2) b, where q b 1 and q b 2 are now given by Eq. (8) (10), as determined in Proposition 2, and P b is given by Eq. (31) or (32). Next, we provide a numerical study to measure the predictive power of the model in the case when a ban on naked CDS purchases is introduced. Some of our findings lead to testable implications which may be validated further through a detailed empirical study. We leave this for future research. Testable Implication 1: The ban has small impact if the size of net outstanding CDS contracts is smaller than the bond supply.

19 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? Normal Crisis CDS positions / bond supply Percentage Change Normal Crisis Bond supply α Fig. 1 The left panel shows the ratio of CDS positions purchased by the pessimist to the total bond supply. The right panel shows the percentage change in bond price after the ban. The parameter settings are γ 1 = 0.2, γ 2 = 0.1, δ = 0.05, δ = 0.2, α = 5. Figure 1 demonstrates that the ban is most effective when the number of CDS units purchased by the pessimist is significantly higher than the bond supply. As the CDS market becomes thinner, the bond price is only mildly affected by the ban, and it experiences percentages increase of only 1% when the purchased CDS units amount to 10% of the total bond supply. The figure also shows that the ban induces the largest bond price appreciation during crisis regimes, when a higher number of naked CDS units are traded. If we consider that among the twenty largest sovereign CDS markets, the share of net notional CDS outstanding to risky government debt averages to about 2%, without exceeding 7% in any country (see also Figure 1.38 in IMF (2010)), then we can safely conclude that such a ban would not achieve his presumed objective of reducing the borrowing costs of sovereign entities. Testable Implication 2: A ban on naked CDS does not reduce credit speculation. Figure 2 shows that naked CDS positions would be replaced by short bond positions, unless the short-selling costs become too high. Indeed, if the investor is highly pessimistic, he will not be refrained from taking short positions in the bond market when the ban is imposed. As he moves from moderately to highly pessimistic, the short-selling costs will become of minor concern to him, and he will start shorting bonds. The number of shorted units becomes approximately equal to his holdings of naked CDS before the ban, when bond short selling costs are not prohibitive (see left panel of Figure 2), or his default likelihood is large enough (right panel of Figure 2). The figure also reveals that the speculative impact of naked CDS holdings is larger during crisis periods. During these times, the pessimistic investor will tolerate higher short-selling costs before reducing the size of his short bond position, initially equal to the size of naked CDS holdings. However, when the cost becomes too high relative to his default belief, extra increases in short-selling costs will be coupled with a reduction in his bond position (such a reduction will occur at a slower rate than in a normal regime).

20 20 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson 3 8 δ 1 = δ 1 = Naked CDS Short Bond Positions Normal Crisis Naked CDS Short Bond Positions δ π 2 Fig. 2 The left panel shows the difference between naked CDS positions (before ban) and short bond positions after the ban as a function of bond short-selling costs. The right panel shows how the same quantity varies with respect to π 2, when π 1 = The parameter settings are γ 1 = 0.1, γ 2 = 0.1, δ = 0.05, α = Expected wealth change Pessimist Normal Pessimist Crisis Optimist Normal Optimist Crisis Expected wealth Change Optimist Normal Optimist Crisis Pessimist Normal Pessimist Crisis δ γ 2 Fig. 3 The subjective expected wealths of optimistic and pessimistic investors. The left panel reports these quantities with respect to δ 1, γ 2 = The right panel reports the same quantities with respect to γ 2, δ = 0.1. The other parameters are set to γ 1 = 0.01, δ = 0.05, α = 5. Testable Implication 3: Both investors experience a trading loss after the ban. As the ban shuts moderately pessimistic investors out of the market, the sovereign debtor would benefit from it by paying lower interest rates when he sells bonds. However, he would also suffer a diminished capacity to borrow, as he needs to borrow the security in the repo market which yields him a cost. This appears evidently from Figure 3, where it is shown that during crisis regimes, the pessimistic investor wants to be short on credit after the ban, and thus takes positions in the bond market. However, the incurred short-selling costs dominate the advantageous increase of interest rate implied by the ban, and yield him a trading loss. The optimistic investor will also be affected by the ban, because he is forced to sell bonds at lower yields. Consistently with Figure 4, the ban has no impact on trading profits of investors, if the pessimist is highly risk averse. As explained earlier, he would replace his naked CDS holdings in full with short bond positions after the ban. Hence, the same

21 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? Percentage change Normal Crisis Naked CDS Short Bond Positions Normal Crisis γ γ 2 Fig. 4 The left panel reports the percentage change in bond price with respect to γ 2. The right panel reports the difference between naked CDS positions (before ban) and short bond positions after the ban as a function of γ 2. The parameter settings are γ 1 = 0.1, δ 1 = 0.1, δ = 0.05, α = 5. downward pressure on the bond price will be exerted before and after the ban, and the profits realized by the investors would not be altered. We conclude our study by analyzing the sensitivity of the ban to the risk aversion levels of the investors. Next, we list and discuss the two main findings. The ban has no impact if the pessimist is risk averse. Figure 4 shows that pessimistic investors who are less risk averse will be exposed to higher levels of default risk after the ban, i.e. they will take a smaller number of short bond positions relatively to the number of naked CDS holdings held before the ban. Hence, the amount of speculation on credit will experience the highest drop after the ban, and consequently the bond price will exhibit the highest appreciation. Notice, however, that such an appreciation never exceeds 2%. As the investor becomes more risk averse, he increases his level of short credit exposure on the bond market till shorting a number of bonds equal to the number of naked CDS units before the ban. When this happens, the same pressure on the bond price will be exerted under both regimes, and the ban will have no effect. We further notice that the largest percentage increase occurs during a crisis regime, even if the investor is only roughly four units long on credit risk as opposed to being over twelve units long as in the normal regime. This shows that the price impact caused by the ban is non-linear and higher when the levels of naked CDS speculations are larger. The ban has the largest impact if the optimist is sufficiently risk averse. When the optimist is more risk tolerant, then his strong appetite for risk will induce him to buy bonds at higher prices. Hence, the market maker can use his competitive advantage, and set up smaller CDS prices so to induce the pessimist to purchase a high number of naked CDS units. However, this will not have a noticeable downward impact on the bond price, as the less riskaverse optimist will be willing to purchase the bonds shorted by the market

22 22 Agostino Capponi, Martin Larsson Percentage change Normal Crisis Naked CDS Short Bond Positions Normal Crisis γ γ Normal Crisis CDSPrice γ 1 Fig. 5 The left panel reports the percentage change in bond price with respect to γ 1. The right panel reports the difference between naked CDS positions (before ban) and short bond positions after the ban as a function of γ 1. The parameter settings are γ 2 = 0.1, δ 1 = 0.1, δ = 0.05, α = 5. maker at higher prices. As he becomes more risk averse, even if the pessimist reduces his level of naked CDS speculation, the bonds shorted by the market maker will be purchased at lower prices. Therefore, after the ban, the bond will experience a higher appreciation. Clearly, when the optimistic becomes highly risk averse, the market maker will have to increase the price of the CDS, as each shorted bond will be paid less. Consequently, there will be a very small number of naked CDS positions to hedge, and the net amount of long bond units will be approximately the same before and after the ban. When this occurs, the impact of the ban becomes negligible. All these effects are visible in Figure 5. 7 Conclusions We have proposed a partial equilibrium model to evaluate the impact of a ban on naked credit default swaps. Our model identifies two types of investors, pessimistic and optimistic, trading bonds bilaterally, and CDS with a market maker who maintains a riskless position. We have solved for the optimal strategies of the investors as well as for the equilibrium prices, both in the regime where naked protection is allowed and in the regime where it is not.

23 Will banning naked CDS impact bond prices? 23 We find that if the CDS market has a smaller size than the bond market, then the ban will have a minor impact on the price of the reference bond. This suggests that manipulation through demand-based price pressure is potentially viable only for corporate or sovereign issuers, where the CDS market is significantly larger than the bond market. Since this is not the case for the ten largest Euro-zone sovereign entities, our analysis suggests that the ban would not achieve its intended objective of reducing borrowing costs. We have shown that if short-selling costs are not too prohibitive, risk averse pessimists would not be discouraged from the ban and implement their short-credit strategy with short bond positions after the ban. We also find that the sovereign debtor would not have a net benefit from the ban. Although he would obtain a gain by paying lower interest rates when selling bonds, he would also suffer a diminished capacity to borrow, which ultimately lowers his trading profits. Considering the important role played by CDS prices in leading bond prices, see Fontana and Scheicher (2010), and the evidence that spread variation is linked to fundamentals, see IMF (2010), our analysis suggests that such a restriction in the CDS market would not be beneficial. Regulators should thus explore alternative avenues to improve financial stability in derivatives market, for example imposing high collateral requirements to risky entities, or requiring central clearing houses for OTC transactions, see also Duffie et al (2010) and Duffie and Zhu (2011). Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Gabriele Camera for very useful discussions improving the quality of this manuscript. A Proofs related to Section 2 Proof (Lemma 1) Since the market maker s portfolio is riskless, and since he meets the investors demand for CDS (and the CDS is available in zero net supply), the final wealth of the market maker is n q01 b {no default} + q01 c {default} + q0 r = q0 r qi c. Moreover, noting that qi c constraint gives 0 (i = 1,..., n) since investors cannot sell CDS, the budget i=1 w 0 = q0 b P b + δ q0 b 1 {q0 b<0} + qc 0 P c + q0 r ( n ) ( = qi c δ P b P c) + q0 r i=1 ( n ) ( = q0 r n ) ( ) qi c + qi c δ P b P c + 1. i=1 i=1 The final wealth can thus be written as n q0 r ( ) qi c = w n 0 δ P b P c + 1 qi c, i=1 i=1

Is there a case for banning short speculation in sovereign bond markets?

Is there a case for banning short speculation in sovereign bond markets? Is there a case for banning short speculation in sovereign bond markets? DARRELL DUFFIE Graduate School of Business Stanford University I address whether speculation in credit default swaps is likely to

More information

Response by Swedish authorities to the European Commission s public consultation on short selling

Response by Swedish authorities to the European Commission s public consultation on short selling Ministry of Finance Financial Institutions and Markets Fi2010/3634 10-5913 Financial Stability Department 2010-560-AFS European Commission Internal Markets and Services DG Financial Institutions markt-g3-consultations@ec.europa.eu

More information

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r). Chapter 4 Put-Call Parity 1 Bull and Bear Financial analysts use words such as bull and bear to describe the trend in stock markets. Generally speaking, a bull market is characterized by rising prices.

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS PROBLEM SETS 1. There is little hedging or speculative demand for cement futures, since cement prices are fairly stable and predictable. The trading activity necessary to support

More information

United States House of Representatives. Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises

United States House of Representatives. Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises United States House of Representatives Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises Credit Default Swaps on Government Debt: Potential Implications of the Greek Debt

More information

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Kang Shi The Chinese University of Hong Kong Juanyi Xu Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Simon Fraser University November

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

The economics of sovereign debt restructuring: Swaps and buybacks

The economics of sovereign debt restructuring: Swaps and buybacks The economics of sovereign debt restructuring: Swaps and buybacks Eduardo Fernandez-Arias Fernando Broner Main ideas The objective of these notes is to present a number of issues related to sovereign debt

More information

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds Internet Appendix for A Model of hadow Banking * At t = 0, a generic intermediary j solves the optimization problem: max ( D, I H, I L, H, L, TH, TL ) [R (I H + T H H ) + p H ( H T H )] + [E ω (π ω ) A

More information

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model These notes consider the single-period model in Kyle (1985) Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica 15,

More information

CHAPTER 6 RISK AND RISK AVERSION

CHAPTER 6 RISK AND RISK AVERSION CHAPTER 6 RISK AND RISK AVERSION RISK AND RISK AVERSION Risk with Simple Prospects Risk, Speculation, and Gambling Risk Aversion and Utility Values Risk with Simple Prospects The presence of risk means

More information

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Options These notes consider the way put and call options and the underlying can be combined to create hedges, spreads and combinations. We will consider the

More information

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements How credit analysts view and use the financial statements Introduction Traditionally it is viewed that equity investment is high risk and bond investment low risk. Bondholders look at companies for creditworthiness,

More information

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04) 24 e. Currency Futures In a currency futures contract, you enter into a contract to buy a foreign currency at a price fixed today. To see how spot and futures currency prices are related, note that holding

More information

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology March 24, 2005 1 Introduction The purchase of an options contract gives the buyer the right to buy call options contract or sell put options contract some

More information

Introduction, Forwards and Futures

Introduction, Forwards and Futures Introduction, Forwards and Futures Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 (Hull chapters: 1,2,3,5) Liuren Wu Introduction, Forwards & Futures Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 35

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Credit Lectures 26 and 27

Credit Lectures 26 and 27 Lectures 26 and 27 24 and 29 April 2014 Operation of the Market may not function smoothly 1. Costly/impossible to monitor exactly what s done with loan. Consumption? Production? Risky investment? Involuntary

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

Introduction to Futures Contracts

Introduction to Futures Contracts Introduction to Futures Contracts September 2010 PREPARED BY Eric Przybylinski Research Analyst Gregory J. Leonberger, FSA Director of Research Abstract Futures contracts are widely utilized throughout

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Web. Chapter FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND MARKETS

Web. Chapter FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND MARKETS FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND MARKETS T Chapter Summary Chapter Web he Web Chapter provides an overview of the various financial institutions and markets that serve managers of firms and investors who invest

More information

Forwards, Swaps and Futures

Forwards, Swaps and Futures IEOR E4706: Financial Engineering: Discrete-Time Models c 2010 by Martin Haugh Forwards, Swaps and Futures These notes 1 introduce forwards, swaps and futures, and the basic mechanics of their associated

More information

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures In the previous chapter we study financial forward and futures contracts and we concluded that are all alike. Each commodity forward, however, has some unique

More information

A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand. April 2005. Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East Lansing, MI 48824

A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand. April 2005. Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East Lansing, MI 48824 A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand April 2005 Donald J. Meyer Jack Meyer Department of Economics Department of Economics Western Michigan University Michigan State University Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

EC372 Bond and Derivatives Markets Topic #5: Options Markets I: fundamentals

EC372 Bond and Derivatives Markets Topic #5: Options Markets I: fundamentals EC372 Bond and Derivatives Markets Topic #5: Options Markets I: fundamentals R. E. Bailey Department of Economics University of Essex Outline Contents 1 Call options and put options 1 2 Payoffs on options

More information

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging 1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging 1.1 Dividends Since we are now in a continuous time framework the dividend paid out at time t (or t ) is given by dd t = D t D t, where as before D denotes

More information

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS PROBLEM SETS 1. (e). (b) A higher borrowing is a consequence of the risk of the borrowers default. In perfect markets with no additional

More information

General Risk Disclosure

General Risk Disclosure General Risk Disclosure Colmex Pro Ltd (hereinafter called the Company ) is an Investment Firm regulated by the Cyprus Securities and Exchange Commission (license number 123/10). This notice is provided

More information

Option Value of Cash. Jialin Yu Columbia Business School. April 20, 2010

Option Value of Cash. Jialin Yu Columbia Business School. April 20, 2010 Option Value of Cash Jialin Yu Columbia Business School April 20, 2010 Motivation Positive price-volume correlation Low market is illiquid market (Shleifer & Vishny (92)) e.g., US S&P/Case-Shiller home

More information

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 422 March 2009 Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Monika Piazzesi Stanford University and National

More information

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3 MØA 155 PROBLEM SET: Summarizing Exercise 1. Present Value [3] You are given the following prices P t today for receiving risk free payments t periods from now. t = 1 2 3 P t = 0.95 0.9 0.85 1. Calculate

More information

A Theory of Capital Structure, Price Impact, and Long-Run Stock Returns under Heterogeneous Beliefs

A Theory of Capital Structure, Price Impact, and Long-Run Stock Returns under Heterogeneous Beliefs A Theory of Capital Structure, Price Impact, and Long-Run Stock Returns under Heterogeneous Beliefs Onur Bayar College of Business, University of Texas at San Antonio Thomas J. Chemmanur Carroll School

More information

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics Session IX: Stock Options: Properties, Mechanics and Valuation Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo Module: Economics of Financial Markets MSc. Financial Economics Department of Economics, City University, London Stock

More information

Practice set #4 and solutions

Practice set #4 and solutions FIN-465 Derivatives (3 credits) Professor Michel Robe Practice set #4 and solutions To help students with the material, seven practice sets with solutions will be handed out. They will not be graded: the

More information

Regulation and Bankers Incentives

Regulation and Bankers Incentives Regulation and Bankers Incentives Fabiana Gómez University of Bristol Jorge Ponce Banco Central del Uruguay May 7, 2015 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract We formally analyze and compare the effects of

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Lecture 1: Asset Allocation

Lecture 1: Asset Allocation Lecture 1: Asset Allocation Investments FIN460-Papanikolaou Asset Allocation I 1/ 62 Overview 1. Introduction 2. Investor s Risk Tolerance 3. Allocating Capital Between a Risky and riskless asset 4. Allocating

More information

January 2011 Supplement to Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options The February 1994 version of the booklet entitled Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options (the Booklet ) is amended

More information

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS William L. Silber HOW TO PREPARE FOR THE MID- TERM: 1. Study in a group 2. Review the concept questions in the Before and After book 3. When you review the questions listed below,

More information

Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs

Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs Submitted to Management Science manuscript Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs Panos Kouvelis, Wenhui Zhao Olin Business School, Washington University, St. Louis,

More information

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs. OPTIONS THEORY Introduction The Financial Manager must be knowledgeable about derivatives in order to manage the price risk inherent in financial transactions. Price risk refers to the possibility of loss

More information

CHAPTER 23: FUTURES, SWAPS, AND RISK MANAGEMENT

CHAPTER 23: FUTURES, SWAPS, AND RISK MANAGEMENT CHAPTER 23: FUTURES, SWAPS, AND RISK MANAGEMENT PROBLEM SETS 1. In formulating a hedge position, a stock s beta and a bond s duration are used similarly to determine the expected percentage gain or loss

More information

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Andrea Attar Thomas Mariotti François Salanié October 2007 Abstract In order to check the impact of the exclusivity regime on equilibrium allocations,

More information

CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS AND CREDIT RISK PRICING MELİH SAZAK

CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS AND CREDIT RISK PRICING MELİH SAZAK CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS AND CREDIT RISK PRICING MELİH SAZAK MSc Finance Cass Business School City University London 2012 1. Introduction Credit default swap (CDS), a type of over-the-counter derivative, is

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. ECON 4110: Sample Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Economists define risk as A) the difference between the return on common

More information

How a thoughtful FX strategy can give Fund Managers a competitive edge

How a thoughtful FX strategy can give Fund Managers a competitive edge How a thoughtful FX strategy can give Fund Managers a competitive edge Executive summary Each alternative investment fund takes a different approach to its investment strategy, but the ultimate goals are

More information

Managers Directive AIFs. Issued :

Managers Directive AIFs. Issued : Information page Alternative Investment Fund Managers Directive AIFMs managing leveraged AIFs Issued : 7t May 2013 Table of Contents 1. Introduction... 3 2. General provisions applicable to AIFs using

More information

Choice under Uncertainty

Choice under Uncertainty Choice under Uncertainty Part 1: Expected Utility Function, Attitudes towards Risk, Demand for Insurance Slide 1 Choice under Uncertainty We ll analyze the underlying assumptions of expected utility theory

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index

Sensex Realized Volatility Index Sensex Realized Volatility Index Introduction: Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility. Realized

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS 1. a. The closing price for the spot index was 1329.78. The dollar value of stocks is thus $250 1329.78 = $332,445. The closing futures price for the March contract was 1364.00,

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable

Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable by Paul Kupiec 1 This Draft: October 2013 Abstract In a stylized model of a financial intermediary, risk managers can expend effort

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Chapter 16: Financial Risk Management

Chapter 16: Financial Risk Management Chapter 16: Financial Risk Management Introduction Overview of Financial Risk Management in Treasury Interest Rate Risk Foreign Exchange (FX) Risk Commodity Price Risk Managing Financial Risk The Benefits

More information

(Legislative acts) REGULATIONS

(Legislative acts) REGULATIONS 24.3.2012 Official Journal of the European Union L 86/1 I (Legislative acts) REGULATIONS REGULATION (EU) No 236/2012 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 14 March 2012 on short selling and

More information

Chapter 5 Option Strategies

Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 4 was concerned with the basic terminology and properties of options. This chapter discusses categorizing and analyzing investment positions constructed by meshing puts

More information

Dimitri Vayanos and Pierre-Olivier Weill: A Search-Based Theory of the On-the-Run Phenomenon

Dimitri Vayanos and Pierre-Olivier Weill: A Search-Based Theory of the On-the-Run Phenomenon Dimitri Vayanos and Pierre-Olivier Weill: A Search-Based Theory of the On-the-Run Phenomenon Presented by: András Kiss Economics Department CEU The on-the-run phenomenon Bonds with almost identical cash-flows

More information

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet Econ 497 Barry W. Ickes Spring 2007 Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet 1. (25%) Consider a portfolio, c, comprised of a risk-free and risky asset, with returns given by r f and E(r p ), respectively. Let y be the

More information

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider This paper studies household beliefs during the recent US housing boom. The first part presents

More information

Should Banks Trade Equity Derivatives to Manage Credit Risk? Kevin Davis 9/4/1991

Should Banks Trade Equity Derivatives to Manage Credit Risk? Kevin Davis 9/4/1991 Should Banks Trade Equity Derivatives to Manage Credit Risk? Kevin Davis 9/4/1991 Banks incur a variety of risks and utilise different techniques to manage the exposures so created. Some of those techniques

More information

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Question 5.1. Four different ways to sell a share of stock that has a price S(0) at time 0. Question 5.2. Description Get Paid at Lose Ownership of Receive Payment

More information

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income 2. Forwards, Options, and Hedging This lecture covers the basic derivatives contracts: forwards (and futures), and call and put options. These basic contracts are

More information

The University of Texas Investment Management Company Derivative Investment Policy

The University of Texas Investment Management Company Derivative Investment Policy Effective Date of Policy: August 12, 2010 Date Approved by U. T. System Board of Regents: August 12, 2010 Date Approved by UTIMCO Board: July 14, 2010 Supersedes: approved August 20, 2009 Purpose: The

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 8 Issue 1 Spring 2003 Article 7 12-2003 A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales Robert Dubil San Jose State University Follow this and additional

More information

Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition

Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition by Jeff Madura 1 12 Market Microstructure and Strategies Chapter Objectives describe the common types of stock transactions explain how stock transactions

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

Answers to Concepts in Review

Answers to Concepts in Review Answers to Concepts in Review 1. Puts and calls are negotiable options issued in bearer form that allow the holder to sell (put) or buy (call) a stipulated amount of a specific security/financial asset,

More information

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series RGEA Universidade de Vigo http://webs.uvigo.es/rgea Working Paper Series A Market Game Approach to Differential Information Economies Guadalupe Fugarolas, Carlos Hervés-Beloso, Emma Moreno- García and

More information

ARE YOU TAKING THE WRONG FX RISK? Focusing on transaction risks may be a mistake. Structural and portfolio risks require more than hedging

ARE YOU TAKING THE WRONG FX RISK? Focusing on transaction risks may be a mistake. Structural and portfolio risks require more than hedging ARE YOU TAKING THE WRONG FX RISK? Focusing on transaction risks may be a mistake Structural and portfolio risks require more than hedging Companies need to understand not just correlate the relationship

More information

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING OPTION PRICING Options are contingency contracts that specify payoffs if stock prices reach specified levels. A call option is the right to buy a stock at a specified price, X, called the strike price.

More information

Chapter 17 Corporate Capital Structure Foundations (Sections 17.1 and 17.2. Skim section 17.3.)

Chapter 17 Corporate Capital Structure Foundations (Sections 17.1 and 17.2. Skim section 17.3.) Chapter 17 Corporate Capital Structure Foundations (Sections 17.1 and 17.2. Skim section 17.3.) The primary focus of the next two chapters will be to examine the debt/equity choice by firms. In particular,

More information

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow EIEF October 9 202 Use a risk averse market making model to investigate. [Microstructural determinants of volatility, liquidity and

More information

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Credible iscovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Warren F. Schwartz Abraham L. Wickelgren Abstract: This paper introduces the option to conduct discovery into a model of settlement bargaining

More information

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011. Two-State Options John Norstad j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011 Abstract How options are priced when the underlying asset has only two possible

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Problem Set 9 Solutions Problem Set 9 s 1. A monopoly insurance company provides accident insurance to two types of customers: low risk customers, for whom the probability of an accident is 0.25, and high risk customers, for

More information

1 Portfolio mean and variance

1 Portfolio mean and variance Copyright c 2005 by Karl Sigman Portfolio mean and variance Here we study the performance of a one-period investment X 0 > 0 (dollars) shared among several different assets. Our criterion for measuring

More information

CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS

CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS 1 CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS (f) 1 The three step valuation process consists of 1) analysis of alternative economies and markets, 2) analysis of alternative industries

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION S PUBLIC CONSULTATION RELATING TO

EUROPEAN COMMISSION S PUBLIC CONSULTATION RELATING TO Identification No.: 09245221105-30 12 July 2010 EUROPEAN COMMISSION S PUBLIC CONSULTATION RELATING TO SHORT SELLING - FBF RESPONSE (English Version) The French Banking Federation (hereinafter FBF) is the

More information

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk A. Research on Information Acquisition in Markets and Agency Issues Between Investors and Financial Intermediaries An important dimension of the workings of financial markets

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper)

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research

More information

Mark-to-Market Accounting and Cash-in-the-Market Pricing

Mark-to-Market Accounting and Cash-in-the-Market Pricing Mark-to-Market Accounting and Cash-in-the-Market Pricing Franklin Allen Wharton School University of Pennsylvania allenf@wharton.upenn.edu Elena Carletti Center for Financial Studies University of Frankfurt

More information

General Forex Glossary

General Forex Glossary General Forex Glossary A ADR American Depository Receipt Arbitrage The simultaneous buying and selling of a security at two different prices in two different markets, with the aim of creating profits without

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*: Problem 1. Consider a risky asset. Suppose the expected rate of return on the risky asset is 15%, the standard deviation of the asset return is 22%, and the risk-free rate is 6%. What is your optimal position

More information

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

Practice Set #4 and Solutions. FIN-469 Investments Analysis Professor Michel A. Robe Practice Set #4 and Solutions. What to do with this practice set? To help students prepare for the assignment and the exams, practice sets with solutions

More information

The Impact of Short-Selling Constraints on Financial Market Stability

The Impact of Short-Selling Constraints on Financial Market Stability The Impact of Short-Selling Constraints on Financial Market Stability Mikhail Anufriev Jan Tuinstra 5th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance University of Technology, Sydney 6

More information

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 15 Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. Introduction: Objectives and Notation III. No Arbitrage Pricing Bound IV. The Binomial

More information

Rethinking Fixed Income

Rethinking Fixed Income Rethinking Fixed Income Challenging Conventional Wisdom May 2013 Risk. Reinsurance. Human Resources. Rethinking Fixed Income: Challenging Conventional Wisdom With US Treasury interest rates at, or near,

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Emilia Matei 1005056 EC372 Term Paper. Topic 3 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes and Merton method of modelling derivatives prices was first introduced

More information

Practice Problems on the Capital Market

Practice Problems on the Capital Market Practice Problems on the Capital Market 1- Define marginal product of capital (i.e., MPK). How can the MPK be shown graphically? The marginal product of capital (MPK) is the output produced per unit of

More information

Lesson 5. Risky assets

Lesson 5. Risky assets Lesson 5. Risky assets Prof. Beatriz de Blas May 2006 5. Risky assets 2 Introduction How stock markets serve to allocate risk. Plan of the lesson: 8 >< >: 1. Risk and risk aversion 2. Portfolio risk 3.

More information

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang AFM 472 Midterm Examination Monday Oct. 24, 2011 A. Huang Name: Answer Key Student Number: Section (circle one): 10:00am 1:00pm 2:30pm Instructions: 1. Answer all questions in the space provided. If space

More information