Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Prices and Quantities in Health Care Antitrust Damages

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Prices and Quantities in Health Care Antitrust Damages"

Transcription

1 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Prices and Quantities in Health Care Antitrust Damages by R. Forrest McCluer Greylock McKinnon Associates Martha A. Starr American University No January Copyright 2014 by R. Forrest McCluer and Martha A. Starr. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

2 2 Prices and Quantities in Health Care Antitrust Damages R. Forrest McCluer* Greylock Mckinnon Associates Martha A. Starr American University January 2014 Abstract Antitrust analysis conventionally assumes that illegal agreements among competitors raise prices and lower quantities, relative to lawful competition. However, markets for healthcare services have tendencies towards overprovision, which may increase when competition declines. This paper examines this possibility using data from a well-known antitrust case in Wisconsin. We find that, in parts of the state where physician groups illegally divided up markets, costs of physician services rose by about 10% more than they did elsewhere, with about half of this increase due to increased services. This suggests that higher quantities can contribute to healthcare antitrust damages, along with higher prices. Keywords: Antitrust, healthcare, physician services, anticompetitive conduct, damages. JEL Codes: I11, L4, K21, C43 * Please address correspondence to: R. Forrest McCluer, Greylock McKinnon Associates, One Memorial Drive, Suite 1410, Cambridge, MA 02142, fmccluer@gma-us.com, tel: (703) This paper was presented at the 3 rd Biennial Conference of the American Society of Health Economists, at Cornell University, June 20-23, We are grateful to Ana Aizcorbe, Cory Capps, Michael Chernew, Randy Ellis, Ted Frech, Thomas McGuire, Jim Neiberding, Eileen Reed, George Schink, Robert Tollison, and seminar participants at the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis for valuable comments on earlier versions of this work. McCluer worked in support of plaintiffs in the Marshfield Clinic cases. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and cannot be attributed to Greylock McKinnon Associates or any other employee or affiliate thereof. Remaining errors are the responsibility of the authors.

3 I. Introduction A core concern in antitrust analysis is whether an alleged reduction in competition in a given market has increased prices and reduced quantities supplied, causing allocative inefficiencies and a decline in consumer welfare. In their seminal framework linking economic reasoning and antitrust law, Landes and Posner (1981) focused attention on loss of output as the primary cost of the exercise of monopoly power. Easterbrook (1984) expresses a similar view that, if arrangements are anticompetitive, the output of those engaging in them must fall. Going beyond this view, Bork (1978) argued that, because consumer welfare is the proper focus of antitrust analysis, one needs to examine the specifics of a case to determine whether consumers have been harmed by a given set of anti-competitive practices, without assuming that a reduction in quantity has to be involved. 1 By this reasoning, practices that do not reduce or possibly even increase output could be the subject of antitrust scrutiny. For example, vertical price restraints that increase output above the levels that would have been demanded in the absence of restraints can be welfare reducing (Comanor 1985, Blair and Fesmire 1994, Rey and Tiore 2003). 2 Similarly, agreements among producers to restrict or divide markets are treated as illegal per se, regardless of how they affect quantity or price, because they inherently reduce the range of choices that consumers face (ABA 1996:181). Nonetheless, the idea that quantity reductions will be found in cases where firms are engaged in illegal competitive practices remains an expectation, as indicated in the frequently-cited ruling: Unless a contract reduces output in some market, to the detriment of consumers, there is no antitrust problem. 3 Issues of quantity can be especially problematic in antitrust cases related to markets for healthcare services. Consumers receive utility not from healthcare services per se, but rather from the benefits these services provide in terms of maintaining or improving their health (Grossman 2000). As they lack specialized medical knowledge, they need to rely on physicians and other trained professionals to determine the levels and mixes of services that best help to advance their health goals. Yet incentives that physicians face may often cause them to recommend more services or different mixes of services than would be consistent with optimization of social welfare. For one, because patients with health insurance pay only a fraction of the costs of services they receive, physicians acting as their agents may provide more referrals or recommend more tests or treatments that would be warranted if patients faced the full costs of the services they received (Feldstein 1973, Pauly 1986, McGuire 2000). For another, traditional fee-for-service medicine has tended to reinforce tendencies towards overprovision, 1 As Bork (1978: 34) has stated, [t]he goal of the law was clearly defined as the maximization of consumer welfare, and a dynamic principle was built into the rule of reason so that the interpretation of the law could change and adjust in its pursuit of that goal as economic understanding advanced. Others have been more explicit in identifying pure consumer welfare as the basis for antitrust analysis (e.g. Salop 2005). 2 See Gaynor and Vogt (2000) for discussion of vertical restraints in health care. 3 Chicago Professional Sports Limited Partnership v. National Basketball Association (Chicago Prof. Sports Ltd. II), 95 F.3d 593, 597 (7th Cir.1996)).

4 4 as it rewards physicians for providing higher levels of services, rather than for efficiently using resources to maintain and improve patients health (Robinson 2001; Emanuel and Fuchs 2008). From the point of view of antitrust policy, the issue of interest is whether the extent of overprovision in a given healthcare market is exacerbated or attenuated by changes in competition. Economic models allowing for possibilities of overprovision provide ambiguous predictions in this respect. In a model in which patients prefer to receive referrals to specialists, Iverson and Ma (2011) find that reductions in competition in markets for physician services will tend to lower levels of service provision because, if physicians do not have to compete as rigorously to attract and retain patients, they will not cater as much to patients requests for referrals. In contrast, in Allard, Léger and Rochaix s (2009) model in which patients face costs of switching from one physician to another, a decline in competition tends to increase overprovision because under less competitive conditions, physicians have to worry less about losing patients if they provide more services than patients would like. More generally, Ma and McGuire (2002) call attention to the role of provider networks in controlling utilization of healthcare services. In preferred-provider arrangements, health plans build networks of providers who agree to accept discounted payments and controls over utilization (e.g. utilization reviews, pre-admission authorizations, prior approvals, second opinions for costly procedures), in exchange for higher patient volumes from the plan s enrollees. When health plans have strong bargaining power relative to provider groups, they have good ability to insist on adherence to utilization targets, as they can credibly threaten to exclude high-utilization providers from their networks. But when plans have weak bargaining power relative to provider groups (as when the pools of patients they control are small, or there are few good-quality provider groups), they may not be able to credibly threaten to exclude higher-utilization providers from their networks. 4 This model too predicts that overprovision will tend to rise when competition among providers declines, ceteris paribus, by eroding health plans bargaining power relative to that of providers. But overall, the ambiguous predictions from theoretical models as to how changes in competition should be expected to affect levels of services provided in given healthcare markets suggest a need for further theoretical work in this area, as well as empirical investigations of specific cases. In view of this gap in understanding, this paper uses data from a well-known antitrust case from central Wisconsin in which physician groups were known to have illegally divided up markets -- and asks what happened to prices and quantities of physician services in that part of the state as the illegal agreements phased in. The reduction in competition would be expected to increase prices of physician services in the affected areas, relative to comparable areas that were unaffected by them; clearly this represents a central part of the damages experienced by healthcare consumers and third-party payers. But additionally, the plaintiffs in the case alleged that physicians in the area responded to the decline in 4 This parallels the bargaining framework used by the Federal Trade Commission to analyze hospital mergers; see Town and Vistnes (2001) and Capps, Dranove and Satterthwaite (2003). See also Ho (2009) on insurer-provider networks.

5 5 competition in part by increasing the quantities of services they provided to their patients, so that higher output as well as higher prices contributed to damages. This paper reexamines the question of whether output for physician services increased in central Wisconsin when these illegal market-allocation agreements phased in, using data from 40 million health insurance claims in the state in A problem that arises in trying to quantify output of physicians services concerns its heterogeneity, as services range from annual well-child visits to openheart surgery. The paper develops a method for disaggregating charges for physician services into quantity and price components, using a measure of quantity that values services at their average prices during the years covered by the analysis. This method bears some similarities to other work on indexes for prices and quantities in health care (e.g. Berndt et al., 2001; Aizcorbe and Nestoriak 2011), but whereas they are open-ended measures intended to monitor price changes on an ongoing basis, the method here focuses on quantifying effects of illegal conduct on prices and quantities in a given time and place. The next section of the paper describes the case analyzed in the paper, in which Marshfield Clinic, a large multi-specialty group practice known for being a high-quality provider in Wisconsin, played a central role. The third section presents the data to be used and explains the method for disaggregating charge data into price and quantity components. It also describes the difference-in-difference regression models used to compare changes in output and prices in the areas affected by the illegal marketallocation agreements, to those in otherwise similar areas that were not. The fourth section presents empirical results, and a final section concludes. In brief, we find that an important share of the extra increases in costs faced by patients in the part of the state where illegal arrangements were in effect, relative to increases faced by patients elsewhere, were associated with increased provision of services. Estimates from our preferred specification suggest that average annual patient costs rose by about 10% more in the part of the state in which anticompetitive agreements were in effect than they did elsewhere in the state, ceteris paribus, with an increase in the quantity of services provided accounting for about one-half of the extra increase. This underlines the need to consider whether higher quantities, as well as higher prices, may contribute to healthcare antitrust damages. II. The Marshfield Clinic class action suit In the 1990s, a series of lawsuits were brought against the Marshfield Clinic of central Wisconsin, one of the largest private, multi-specialty group practices in the United States. At that time, the clinic employed physicians who practiced at the main clinic in Marshfield and satellite clinics in the surrounding areas. Most of Marshfield Clinics physicians served on the medical staff at St. Joseph's Hospital, a 524-bed tertiary-care teaching institution adjacent to the main clinic. In addition, the Clinic owned and operated its own managed-care organization, Security Health Plan. It also had a

6 6 varied array of business arrangements with other physicians and healthcare providers in the area, aiming to create a regionally integrated healthcare system known for its quality of care. 5 Table 1 provides a brief chronology of the cases against Marshfield Clinic, as background to the issues discussed in the current paper. The initial suit was brought by Blue Cross-Blue Shield of Wisconsin and its HMO, Compcare, charging that Marshfield Clinic and its HMO, Security Health Plan of Wisconsin, were monopolizing physician services, fixing prices, and illegally dividing markets with competitors. At that time, the case raised thorny new legal and conceptual issues related to correct definitions of healthcare markets and valid methods of distinguishing between legal vs. illegal factors contributing to higher healthcare costs. 6 While the jury was persuaded by the charges against Marshfield, the appeals-court judge, distinguished legal thinker Richard Posner, took issue with much of the analysis presented in the first case, overturning most of the initial findings and remanding the case to district court, with instructions to plaintiffs to limit estimates of damages to those associated with illegal division of markets only. Damage estimates presented in the remand phase were in turn rejected by the district-court judge, among other things for failing to distinguish between legal and illegal factors contributing to Marshfield Clinic s higher patient costs. Summary judgment was issued in Marshfield s favor; BCBS appealed unsuccessfully. Subsequent class-action litigation (referred to as Rozema after the named plaintiffs) charged Marshfield Clinic and other healthcare providers with entering into business arrangements that illegally restricted trade and increased costs of physician services for people who lived in an eight-county area of influence (AOI). 7 Defendants in the case in addition to Marshfield Clinic were Security Health Plan, the Marshfield-owned HMO; North Central Health Protection Plan, an HMO based in Wassau; and Rhinelander Medical Center, based in Rhinelander. 8 Figure 1 shows the AOI and the defendants main locations. As evidence in the case established, agreements among these providers aimed to reduce competition between them via such routes as not opening offices in each others territories, not actively marketing in each others areas, and not building specialty practices in places where other providers had already established them. 9 Some of these agreements had started as early as 1978, but evidence presented in the case established that they had expanded in breadth and scope after The Clinic had has continued to grow since then, presently employing some 776 physicians and 6,600 support personnel in 54 locations (Marshfield Clinic 2012). 6 For further discussion of the Marshfield case and the issues it raised, see Troupis (1995), Sage (1997), Haas-Wilson and Gaynor (1998), Greenberg (1998), Coombs (2005), and McCluer and Starr (2013). 7 Counties in the AOI included Clark, Price, Lincoln, Oneida, Marathon, Taylor, Portage, and Wood. Formally, the class constituted people living in the AOI who had acquired physician services in the AOI after July 24, 1992 (as entered in a ruling after expert reports had been submitted). 8 The case originally included another defendant, Rice Clinic located in Stevens Point (Portage County), but the judge ruled there was insufficient evidence of its involvement in illegal agreements. 9 As a Marshfield official wrote of discussions held with Rhinelander in 1991, We do not want to see ourselves knocking heads for the same services for the same patient population (quoted in Judge Crabb, Order and Opinion, Oct. 2, 1997).

7 7 Experts for the plaintiffs argued that these agreements not only enabled physicians to charge relatively high prices for their services, but also to provide higher quantities of services than they would have provided under legal competitive conditions. This possibility had come up in the earlier Marshfield case, but was dismissed by Judge Posner as a strange inversion of the usual logic of cartelization, which is that cartelists drive up the market price by (or with the effect of) restricting their output. 10 In the class-action case, however, the plaintiffs experts developed the argument more fully, both by referring to scholarly research in health economics and by presenting estimates of damages that distinguished between those associated with higher prices and those associated with higher levels of services. 11 While the judge called the inclusion of increased quantity in damages a drastic departure from antitrust economics and unsupported by case law, she did not think it could be dismissed on this grounds alone, and on the contrary viewed the evidence as sufficient for a reasonable jury to conclude that plaintiffs paid more for physician services because of defendants' unlawful conduct (Judge Crabb, Order and Opinion, Oct. 2, 1997). Thus, she declined to grant summary judgment in the case, and it was subsequently settled. 12 IV. Data and methodology The data used for the analysis come from 40 million insurance claims for professional services submitted to Blue Cross-Blue Shield (BCBS) by all subscribers residing in the state of Wisconsin in 1988 to This is the same data as was used for the Rozema class action suit. During these years, BCBS was the largest provider of group health insurance in the state of Wisconsin, having some 10-13% of the statewide market. 14 The claims data report basic information on the patient (age, gender, relationship to the subscriber), the provider, and codes indicating the specific services the patient received. Some 400,000 unique medical procedures associated with physician services are found in the data, where procedures are F.3d 588 (7 th Cir. 1998). Posner conceded that McGuire s argument was a possibility, but thought there [was] no evidence of it. See McCluer and Starr (2013) for discussion. 11 A first expert, H. E. Frech III, argued that moral-hazard problems in healthcare can lead to overprovision of services, with anti-competitive conduct tending to increase utilization. As Judge Crabb summarized his opinion, Dr. Frech states that health care markets are subject to economic forces different from other industries. It is his opinion that most Americans consume a higher-than-optimal level of health care because of the moral hazard created by health insurance. When market competition and managed care are operating properly, they reduce the utilization of physician services. According to Frech, anticompetitive conduct leads to higher utilization (977 F. Supp (W.D. Wis. 1997)). 12 See Associated Press (1997). In the Rozema case, Judge Crabb ordered that Rice Clinic be dropped as a co-conspirator and that patients residing in Portage County be dropped from the class (Judge Crabb, Order and Opinion, October 2, 1997); this ruling came after the econometric analysis was submitted. Damages were computed as 6.9% times the total health care expenditures of residents of the AOI. The case settled for a portion of the estimated damages (Coombs 2005: 188). 13 Cases in which out-of-state residents travelled to Wisconsin to receive medical care are excluded from the analysis to avoid issues of sample-selection bias. 14 Figures from Table E, Office of the Commissioner of Insurance, State of Wisconsin ( ).

8 8 defined as unique combinations of the characteristics of the service: the Current Procedural Terminology (CPT), the standard 5-digit code used to classify physician services for billing purposes; three modifiers of the CPT (type of service, place of service, and number of units of service); the type of provider (medical doctor or osteopath); and the provider s specialty (e.g. general practitioner, radiologist, or thoracic surgeon). The prices in the analysis are the charges submitted to BCBS, not payments made by BCBS; this ensures that measured differences in prices across areas reflect differences in providers charges, rather than features of insurance coverage (e.g. deductibles, copayments, negotiated prices). We use the claims data to compute total real annual costs per patient, then use an index approach to decompose variations in total costs into price and quantity components. The first step is to compute total annual costs of physician services for individual i in year t, : (3) where is the price charged to individual i for service j obtained from provider k in year t, and is the related quantity. Aggregating all charges over each year for individual patients yields 2.26 million individual-year observations for individuals under age (We omit 41,504 records for individuals aged 65 and over from the analysis, given that the vast majority of people in this age group have their primary health insurance coverage through Medicare). While some individuals in the data have records for multiple years, complexities of matching the records imply it is difficult to structure the individual-year records into a complete (imbalanced) panel data set. 16 As a result, we opt to analyze the data as a pooled cross-section sample instead. To take into account general inflation in healthcare costs over the period, all prices are deflated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics consumer price index (CPI) for all medical services (1995=100). Next we take averages of prices for each service j across all individuals i, all providers k, and all years: 15 Note that some individuals in the data were covered under a BCBS plan for only part of the year. We have not tried to convert partial-year records to full-year equivalents, as it is difficult to identify such cases with certainty. 16 For example, some individuals submit claims in early years of the period analyzed and again in later years, but we cannot tell whether they incurred no costs in the intervening years or whether they were not covered by a BCBS plan.

9 9 (4) where we refer to as the index price for service j. Then specific prices paid for a service can be reexpressed as deviations from its index price, permitting us to re-write (3) as: (5) where the term is the deviation from the index price associated with individual i s purchase of service j from provider k in year t. Re-arranging and letting be the total quantity of service j received by individual i in year t (i.e. summing over providers), the individual s total costs of physician services can be decomposed as follows: (6) = (7) The first term, is a constant-price index of the quantity of services received by individual i in year t, where outputs are valued at their index prices. This represents the primary measure of quantity used in our analysis. In effect, holds prices constant at average levels prevailing in the period under investigation, so that increases in over time necessarily come from changes in quantities of services received and/or shifts in the composition of services towards those with higher average prices. 17 The second term,, is a measure of price deviations faced by individual i; it is a weighted average of the differences between the price the individual was charged for a given service at time t and the index price for that service, with weights given by the quantity of the service 17 In this sense, the quantity measure differs from a standard constant-price measure of output, which values quantities at prices from a given base year.

10 10 received by the individual in year t. Thus, can rise over time either because price deviations of the services acquired by individual i have increased and/or because the composition of services has shifted to services with higher deviations. For damage estimation, the key question is whether differential increases in quantities of services contributed to differential increases in costs among patients with given characteristics residing in the AOI, compared to counterparts who lived elsewhere. Table 2 and Figure 2 show averages for these variables for individuals residing in and out of the eightcounty AOI. In , average total annual costs were no higher in the AOI than they were in the rest of the state; thereafter, however, they exceeded them by $ (roughly 6.5 to 11.5%). This is consistent with information presented in the class-action case that the market-allocation agreements in which Marshfield Clinic was involved increased in breadth and scope after In the years when average total annual costs were higher in the AOI than in the rest of the state, the higher quantity of services tended to be more important in contributing to the higher costs than the price deviation, although with some variation in the relative importance of the two factors from year to year. Taking the period as a whole, average annual costs were $84 higher in the AOI than they were elsewhere, where $68 of the difference (or 80.5%) came from the higher quantity index. Of course, there may be socio-demographic differences between the AOI and the rest of the state that contribute to the relatively high quantities of physician services received in the AOI. Notably, because the areas served by Marshfield Clinic tend to be relatively rural, the baseline health of the population may tend to be lower than it is elsewhere due to lower income levels, lower levels of education, different occupational profiles, etc. Similarly, levels of competition among providers tend to be lower in rural areas, so it is possible that the higher price deviations registered in the AOI reflect the naturally higher pricing power of rural healthcare providers, rather than effects of illegal divisions of markets. Thus, we use a regression framework to account for legitimate factors explaining variations in total annual costs, the quantity index, and price deviations across areas. The standard benchmark method of estimating damages estimates a regression of the form: = + + α + (8) where is a vector of factors expected to influence the individual s healthcare costs (e.g. age, gender, type of health insurance, etc.), is a vector of year dummies intended to capture broadbased changes in real healthcare spending, and is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the individual

11 11 lives in the AOI. Then the estimated coefficient α indicates whether total annual costs per patient are higher in the AOI than they are elsewhere, ceteris paribus. To gauge the relative contributions of higher quantities and higher prices to higher charges in the AOI, we can run regressions of the form: = (9) = (10) However, if, and contain unmeasured but lawful sources of variation in costs, quantities and prices across areas and these correlate with, then regression estimates of, and will give biased representations of effects of illegal conduct in the AOI. A common concern in this respect is that the quality of care may vary systematically between physicians in one area and the other, and/or that patients with given observed characteristics may differ in unobserved ways that make their health conditions more complex than those of patients elsewhere, so that differences in costs, quantities and prices between the AOI and ROS reflect hedonic differences in the services received. 18 This problem can be addressed by making use of the fact that, while the data cover the period, the scope of the agreements behind the illegal market allocation broadened after Thus, we can estimate difference-in-difference regressions that in effect take initial differences in levels of the dependent variable between the AOI and ROS to be reflective of persistent unobserved heterogeneities between the two areas; then controlling for other observable factors that may have caused the dependent variable to change between 1988 and 1995, an increase in that variable over that period that is greater in the AOI than it is the ROS is suggestive of an effect of the market allocation. Specifically, we run regressions of the following form: = (16) 18 See McCluer and Starr (2013) for discussion. This issue was more important in the first phase of the Marshfield-related litigation, which compared patient costs between patients who received a majority of their care from Marshfield clinic to otherwise similar patients who received their care from other providers.

12 12 for the three dependent variables; this amounts to including year dummies that differ between the AOI and ROS. Then the test for an effect of the illegal market allocation for a given dependent variable is: ΔΔ = - } - { - } (17) See Abadie (2005) for methodological discussion and McCluer and Starr (2013) for an application using data from the remand phase of the Marshfield case. 19 In principle, some part of the differential increase in quantity in the AOI could have been associated with increases in the quality of care than would have been warranted under an economic calculus of costs, benefits and risks; in this case, the DID estimate of the effect of the illegal market agreement would overstate the anticompetitive increase in quantity. However, in the present case direct review of evidence on the quality of care did not suggest any basis for concern about a possible bias from this source. Notably, at the outset of the period Marshfield Clinic was widely perceived to have a substantial quality advantage over other providers in the state; while it continued to work on improving its procedures and facilities in the period, its efforts were well in line with those of other providers in the state. 20 So while we do not expect there to be bias from differential changes in quality in the present case, the possibility should be investigated in others, given that correct estimation of damages requires all legal sources of differential outcomes across providers or across areas to be accounted for. 21 Table 3 gives definitions of the variables used in the regression analysis along with sample means. Our information on individual characteristics is limited to what is reported on insurance claims, but these cover many of the factors that would be expected to affect use of healthcare services, especially age, gender, marital status, and type of insurance plan (general indemnity, Federal government workers, 19 This differs somewhat from the standard DID specification, which uses a stark division between a before-and-after period to identify the effect of interest (Rubinfeld 2010). In the present case, we favor the more flexible specification implied by (16), given that the illegal market-allocation agreements were known to have phased in at different times in different places within the AOI. Still, for purposes of comparison, we also estimated standard before-and-after DID regressions, using the formal definition of the class period (from 1992 on) as the market allocation period. Results in this case show an increase in total patient costs that is, not surprisingly, somewhat smaller than is the case when 1988 and 1995 are compared (i.e. an increase of $64 from to , vs. $83 from 1988 to 1995); however, the standard method traces a much larger share of this increase to increased quantity (90% vs. 53%). 20 For example, in the remand phase of the trial, BCBS expert Thomas McGuire noted that the share of procedures performed by specialists (rather than primary care physicians) did not rise faster at the Clinic than it did elsewhere, as might be expected if its quality of care was improving at an extraordinary rate. See also McCluer and Starr (2013). 21 Hammer and Sage (2002) and Vogt and Town (2006) suggest that claims of increased quality accompanying increases in market power should be looked at skeptically, as they are not often substantiated by review of clinical outcomes, Moreover Gaynor (2006) finds that quality of care is better favored by competition than concentration.

13 13 etc.). 22 We incorporate effects of age and gender by interacting age ranges with gender; this allows age profiles of health costs, quantities and price deviations to differ between men and women. To account for other differences across areas that may contribute to the higher costs found in the AOI, we include county-level measures of the socio-demographic characteristics of the population, including: the share of the population with a high school education or more, the population density, the unemployment rate, real per capita income, real medical-assistance payments per capita, and birth and death rates. The basic specification closely parallels that which was used in the Rozema class action case. We also estimate a number of alternative specifications, adding explanatory variables and varying the estimation method used. A possibility that came up repeatedly in the Marshfield-related litigation cases was that healthcare prices in given parts of Wisconsin were relatively high because of legal competitive factors, instead of or in addition to illegal market division. First, because ratios of physicians to population are known to be relatively low in areas of low population density, and the AOI is largely rural, this may confer some natural ability to price above marginal costs and/or provide extra services to their patients unrelated to illegal behavior. 23 Because the counties in the AOI all have relatively low population density yet vary in the degree of concentration in the market for physician services, we add the Herfindal-Hirshman index (HHI) to the variables included in the regression analysis. The HHI measures market concentration as the sum of the squared market shares of all providers in the market; specifically, we measure it as the share of all billing events for all providers used by residents of the county. 24 Another issue related to legal competitive factors concerns effects that health-maintenance organizations (HMOs) may have on prices and quantities (Baker 1994, Baker and Corts 1995, Haas- Wilson 2003). On one hand, if a given local market has a well-developed HMO sector, it may tend to act as a check on price increases, as insurance companies may negotiate harder for lower prices to limit patients out of pocket costs and avoid loss of business to managed care. Baker (1994) and Baker and Corts (1995) refer to this as a market discipline effect. In this case, total costs and price deviations may tend to be lower in counties where HMO penetration is higher, ceteris paribus. On the other hand, the more people have substituted into managed care in a given market, the more likely it 22 Identifying information such as name and address was either masked or not made available. 23 As Posner wrote in his opinion on BCBS s appeal (65 F.3d 1406 (7 th Cir.) 1995), If the Marshfield Clinic is a monopolist in any of these areas it is what is called a natural monopolist, which is to say a firm that has no competitors simply because the market is too small to support more than a single firm. If an entire county has only 12 physicians, one can hardly expect or want them to set up in competition with each other. Twelve physicians competing in a county would be competing to provide horse-and-buggy medicine. 24 The HHI is commonly used in analyses of the competitiveness of health care markets (e.g. Lynk 1995, Schneider et al 2008). As discussed in Frech, Langenfeld and McCluer (2004), computing the HHI in terms of the location of the patient rather than the provider avoids issues of sample selection and case mix. We also ran the regressions using HHIs computed from providers shares of the value of total billings rather than the total number; there is no qualitative difference in results, which is not surprising given the high correlation between the two measures (0.95).

14 14 will be that those remaining in traditional indemnity insurance plans are likely to have worse underlying health. Baker (1994) and Baker and Corts (1995) call this as a market segmentation effect. In this case, total costs and quantities may be higher in counties where HMO penetration is high, as the pool of patients remaining outside of the HMO sector will have relatively poor health. To account for these possibilities, the regressions include a measure of HMO penetration, namely, the share of the county s population enrolled in an HMO. A complication is that some of the defendants in the class-action suit were HMOs, including one wholly owned by Marshfield Clinic; consequently, if people enrolled in defendant HMOs were included in the measure of HMO penetration, the degree of competition coming from managed care in the AOI would be overstated. 25 So in computing HMO enrollment for counties in the AOI, we exclude people who were enrolled in Security Health Plan or North Central Health Protection Plan from the penetration rate. V. Empirical results Table 4 presents results from the basic difference-in-difference specification, which controls for sources of persistent unobserved heterogeneities between the AOI and ROS and uses differential changes between the areas to gauge the effects of illegal competitive behavior. Before looking at the comparison of changes in the AOI vs. ROS, it is first valuable to examine the estimated effects of the other explanatory variables, which suggest that the specification captures a number of interesting and/or expected variations across individuals in costs, quantity and price deviations. The results indicate that, for both men and women, total annual spending on physician services rose significantly with age; for example, total costs were $417.6 (=$ ) higher for women in the age age range than for otherwise similar women in the age range, while for men the analogous difference was $ (=$ (-3.2)). This is consistent with a large literature documenting the strong dependence of healthcare costs on age (e.g. Alemayehu and Warner 2004). The increase occurs earlier for women than it does for men, although for men spending rises relatively steeply from age 45 on. 26 In both cases, increases in spending with age are largely due to increases in the quantity of services; estimates for the price-deviation equation show some shift towards relatively more costly services after childhood, but it is modest compared to the increase in quantity. Married subscribers had somewhat lower total spending on physician services than single subscribers, ceteris paribus, which has mostly to do with the lower quantity of services acquired; for example, of the $50.90 difference in spending between married and single subscribers, $48.40 was due to the lower quantity index. This is broadly consistent with clinical evidence that people who have good marriages and good networks of social relations tend to have better health (Cohen 2004, Parker-Pope 2010). Not surprisingly, total spending is substantially and significantly higher for people in high insurance risk-sharing plans, where this is almost entirely due to very high quantity of services. Total 25 As McCrary and Rubinfeld (2009) caution, including covariates that are causally related to the conspiracy on the right-hand side of a regression biases estimates of damages due to the conspiracy. 26 Note that results are for physician services only.

15 15 spending is also relatively high for subscribers enrolled in BCBS s Federal Employee Program, and relatively low for subscribers enrolled in national programs, where in both cases differences in the quantity index are much more important than price deviations. Among the county-level variables, total spending on physician services was relatively low for individuals in counties with relatively high shares of the population with a high school degree or more; the effect is due almost equally to lower quantity and a lower price deviation, although only the latter effect is significant. Ceteris paribus, total spending was relatively high for people living in counties with high population densities, due to both higher quantities and higher prices. Individuals in counties with relatively high unemployment had relatively high total spending, due almost entirely to relatively high quantities of services. This seems to run counter to Ruhm s (2000) finding that recessions are good for your health, although the types of cyclicalities he identifies (e.g. motor vehicle accidents) may affect spending on hospital services more than spending on physicians. Individuals in counties with relatively high per capita income had relatively high spending due to both quantities and prices; in contrast, those in counties with relatively high medical assistance per capita had relatively high spending, due entirely to relatively high price deviations. Relatively high birth and death rates had no significant effect on total spending or the quantity index, but they were associated with relatively low price deviations. Turning to the comparison of changes in the AOI vs. the ROS, the results indicate that, controlling for other factors, total annual spending on physician services in the AOI rose by $303.6 between 1988 and 1995, while it rose by $231.0 in the ROS; the difference between the two of $82.6 is statistically significant. 27 This is consistent with the expectation that the illegal market-allocation agreements boosted spending on physician services. 28 With respect to the source of the increase, the estimates show that both quantities and price deviations rose significantly in both the AOI and the ROS between 1988 and 1995, where the increases in quantities and price deviations were both larger in the AOI than they were in the ROS. Looking at the decomposition of the $82.6 differential increase in total costs in the AOI, the estimates suggest that $49 (59.3%) of this increase came from the greater increase in quantity in the AOI relative to the ROS. 29 This supports the expectation that some part of the illegal market power acquired by physicians in the AOI due to the market-allocation agreements resulted in intensification of service provision, in addition to higher prices. Table 5 shows results incorporating the HHI and HMO penetration variables using alternative specifications. As shown in Panel (B), adding these two variables to the basic DID specification has only modest effects on the estimated effects of being in the AOI. The estimated effect on total 27 Interestingly, this estimate of the effect of the illegal market allocation is higher than in the analogous estimate of $62 from a simple dummy-variable specification [8], suggesting the latter is biased downward rather than up. 28 See also McCluer and Starr (2013) for related results and discussion. 29 In the dummy-variable specification [8], the higher quantity of services contributes a somewhat smaller share (43.2%) of the higher level of total spending on physician services in the AOI, ceteris paribus.

16 16 spending on physician services is virtually unchanged at $82.7 (vs. $82.6 in the basic DID). The quantity index declines from $49.0 to $44.2, while that on the price deviation moves up from $33.5 to $38.5, so that the relative importance of the change in quantity index in the differential change in spending in the AOI is a bit smaller (53.4% vs. 59.3%). Interestingly, controlling for whether a person lived in the AOI, an increase in the HHI was associated with a significant increase in total costs, which was due to a significant increase in the price deviation with no significant change in quantity. This indicates that, at least in Wisconsin during this period, concentration per se was not associated with increased quantity, but rather the business practices and agreements in use in the AOI. 30 The results also show that, ceteris paribus, costs were higher in counties with relatively high HMO enrollments, largely reflecting effects on the price deviation. This finding is more consistent with market segmentation than with market discipline, although in the former case we expected higher costs to reflect higher quantity rather than higher price. Broadly, these results suggest that basic results concerning the differential increases in prices and quantities of physicians services in the AOI are not due to omitted competition-related variables. Conceivably, effects of increases in the HHI on output and prices may be nonlinear: For example, it may only be in highly concentrated markets that further concentration permits anticompetitive increases in output. To test for this possibility, we re-estimate the previous model including a spline for markets with HHIs above 2500, the cut-off between moderately and highly concentrated markets in the current merger guidelines of the U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission (2010). As shown in Panel (C), the results suggest that increases in the HHI in highly concentrated markets have no extra effect on total annual spending on physician services, although this masks some contrasting effects on quantities and prices. For the quantity index, increases in the HHI below 2500 are estimated to lower the quantity of services acquired by a given individual, but above 2500 further increases in concentration tend to raise it; this is consistent with the idea that overprovision of services is not a simple function of the degree of market power, but that situations of highly concentrated market power may encourage it. In contrast, increases in the HHI boost the pricedeviation in markets that are unconcentrated to moderately concentrated, with no further effect in highly concentrated markets. Finally, it has been suggested that comparing measures of spending, quantities and prices for physician services in the AOI to the whole rest of the state of Wisconsin may be inappropriate, given that the AOI mostly covers areas of low population density. Thus, we re-run the analysis confining the sample to individuals in the 60 counties with a population density below 200 residents per square mile; this reduces the sample size to 619,932 individual-year observations. As shown in Panel (D), this has some notable effects on magnitudes of estimated coefficients. It increases the magnitude of the differential increase in total costs in the AOI (from $82.7 to $105.7), although it leaves the 30 In fact, if the regressions are run using observations from the ROS only, the estimated effect of the HHI is positive and significant in the regressions for total costs and the price deviation, but negative in the regression for quantity, although the latter effect is significant at a 10% level only.

17 17 contribution of the quantity index to this increase in the same range (56.4%). This indicates that, if anything, failing to confine the sample to counties with relatively low population densities causes underestimation of the damages associated with acquiring healthcare services in the AOI, not overstatement. In this part of the state, increases in the HHI increase both the quantity index and the price deviation. Here too increases in HMO enrollment tend to boost total costs due a greater price deviation, although the estimated magnitude of the effect is smaller. Altogether, the results in Table 5 confirm that results of the basic specification are robust to incorporation of additional competitionrelated variables and to other plausible changes in specification. VI. Conclusions In sum, our econometric analysis indicates that, in Wisconsin in the period, quantities of physician services rose more quickly in the AOI than they did elsewhere, consistent with the idea that the reduction in competition amongst Marshfield Clinic and its co-conspirators created an environment in which they could increase both prices and quantities of services by more than would have been possible without the anticompetitive agreements. In our preferred difference-in-difference specification (Panel (B) of Table B), which controls for persistent unobserved heterogeneities across areas and for other competition-related factors, real patient costs rose by an extra $82.7 (9.9%) in the AOI between 1988 and 1995, with 53.4% of this increase associated with an extra increase in quantity. With all of our estimates of differential increases in total costs being between $62 and $115, and estimates of the contribution of increased quantity mostly in the 35-60% range, the magnitudes of our preferred estimates are in the middle of these ranges. Again we underline that, although concerns that difference-in-difference estimates of in principle may pick up differential changes in quality of care as well as effects of illegal competitive conduct, in the present case direct review of evidence on changes in the quality of care did not suggest any basis for concern about this potential source of bias in the damage estimates. Taken broadly, our findings illustrate that estimates of the damages due to the illegal market allocation that focused solely on differential increases in prices would have understated the amount of damages by an appreciable amount. The main implication of our findings is that, especially in cases where a service-intensive practice style is a part of the competitive strategy of a provider accused of illegal anticompetitive conduct, methods of damage estimation should not be based on price only, but rather should also consider whether increased quantities of services contributed to the monetary losses experienced by consumers and health insurers. Losses from this source are not entirely missing from the standard damage-estimation method: Because this method multiplies the price differential due to anticompetitive behavior by the actual quantity, and some part of the latter reflects the extra overprovision associated with this behavior, some part of the extra quantity factors into the estimated loss. But to account for the fact that these units would not have been bought at all under legal competitive conditions, the extra quantity of services valued at the competitive benchmark price should also be added in. In the end, it

18 18 is an empirical question whether consumers and/or insurers in a given case are entitled to damages from overprovision of services relative to what they would have bought in the absence of anticompetitive behavior. The method of disaggregating damages from prices and quantities presented in this paper provides a way to check.

19 Figure 1. Area of Influence (AOI) 19

20 20 Figure 2. Trends in average annual costs and contributions from quantity and price (a) costs of health care services Average annual (b) the difference between the AOI and ROS due to quantity and price Decomposition of Note: Values are converted to 1995 dollars using the medical care CPI (1995=100).

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Updated for the 9th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement

More information

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence Jan Tin Commerce Department Abstract This study takes a closer look at the relationship between money demand and the life-cycle motive using panel

More information

Managed Care Penetration and the Earnings of Health Care Workers

Managed Care Penetration and the Earnings of Health Care Workers Managed Care Penetration and the Earnings of Health Care Workers Amy Ehrsam Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper August 2001 Abstract In the last fifteen years one of the

More information

Market Definition Does Not Yield Evidence of Class-Wide Impact

Market Definition Does Not Yield Evidence of Class-Wide Impact Market Definition Does Not Yield Evidence of Class-Wide Impact Dr. Michael D. Noel, Ph.D. & Parker Normann, Ph.D. Edgeworth Economics June 2012 (published version available in the Antitrust Practitioner)

More information

How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January 2004. Jeffrey Greenbaum. Massachusetts Institute of Technology

How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January 2004. Jeffrey Greenbaum. Massachusetts Institute of Technology How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January 2004 Jeffrey Greenbaum Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 jeffreyg@mit.edu

More information

Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance

Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance A Response to Comments Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance James A. Berkovec Glenn B. Canner Stuart A. Gabriel Timothy H. Hannan Abstract This response discusses the

More information

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER David Cutler Harvard University and NBER Patricia Seliger Keenan NBER December

More information

JURY INSTRUCTIONS. 2.4 Willful Maintenance of Monopoly Power

JURY INSTRUCTIONS. 2.4 Willful Maintenance of Monopoly Power JURY INSTRUCTIONS PRELIMINARY INSTRUCTIONS 1. ANTITRUST CLAIMS 2. Elements of Monopoly Claim 2.1 Definition of Monopoly Power 2.2 Relevant Market 2.3 Existence of Monopoly Power 2.4 Willful Maintenance

More information

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Title: A Note on Settlements under the Contingent Fee Method of Compensating Lawyers Author: Polinsky, A. Mitchell, Stanford Law School Rubinfeld, Daniel L., University of California,

More information

CASE 0:12-cv-01019-DSD-AJB Document 72 Filed 03/06/14 Page 1 of 7. UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF MINNESOTA Civil No.

CASE 0:12-cv-01019-DSD-AJB Document 72 Filed 03/06/14 Page 1 of 7. UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF MINNESOTA Civil No. CASE 0:12-cv-01019-DSD-AJB Document 72 Filed 03/06/14 Page 1 of 7 Jeremy Axel, Matthew Mitchell and Keyon Cooley, UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF MINNESOTA Civil No. 12-1019(DSD/AJB) Plaintiffs.

More information

How Sensitive are Low Income Families to Health Plan Prices?

How Sensitive are Low Income Families to Health Plan Prices? American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 100 (May 2010): 292 296 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.100.2.292 The Massachusetts Health Insurance Experiment: Early Experiences How

More information

2019 Healthcare That Works for All

2019 Healthcare That Works for All 2019 Healthcare That Works for All This paper is one of a series describing what a decade of successful change in healthcare could look like in 2019. Each paper focuses on one aspect of healthcare. To

More information

Proposed Statement of Antitrust Enforcement Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations Participating in the Medicare Shared Savings Program

Proposed Statement of Antitrust Enforcement Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations Participating in the Medicare Shared Savings Program Proposed Statement of Antitrust Enforcement Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations Participating in the Medicare Shared Savings Program I. Introduction The Patient Protection and Affordable Care

More information

The expense for hospital room

The expense for hospital room Employee Benefits Hospital Room and Board Benefits An analysis of changes in employer-sponsored health plans between 1979 and 1995 discloses that employers sought to contain rising hospital room and board

More information

A Primer on Ratio Analysis and the CAH Financial Indicators Report

A Primer on Ratio Analysis and the CAH Financial Indicators Report A Primer on Ratio Analysis and the CAH Financial Indicators Report CAH Financial Indicators Report Team North Carolina Rural Health Research and Policy Analysis Center Cecil G. Sheps Center for Health

More information

Antitrust Law & Economics: Exclusionary Behavior, Bundled Discounts, and Refusals to Deal

Antitrust Law & Economics: Exclusionary Behavior, Bundled Discounts, and Refusals to Deal Antitrust Law & Economics: Exclusionary Behavior, Bundled Discounts, and Refusals to Deal Timothy J. Muris Foundation Professor of Law George Mason University School of Law Introduction I ll discuss these

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Fiscal Policy and Management in East Asia, NBER-EASE, Volume 16 Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi

More information

Cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance. By: Joseph E. Johnson, George B. Flanigan, and Daniel T. Winkler

Cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance. By: Joseph E. Johnson, George B. Flanigan, and Daniel T. Winkler Cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance By: Joseph E. Johnson, George B. Flanigan, and Daniel T. Winkler Johnson, J. E., G. B. Flanigan, and D. T. Winkler. "Cost Implications of No-Fault Automobile

More information

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF STATE-MANDATED HEALTH INSURANCE BENEFITS

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF STATE-MANDATED HEALTH INSURANCE BENEFITS THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF STATE-MANDATED HEALTH INSURANCE BENEFITS Robert Sobers The College of New Jersey April 2003 I. INTRODUCTION There are currently 41.2 million Americans without health insurance,

More information

Medicare Advantage Stars: Are the Grades Fair?

Medicare Advantage Stars: Are the Grades Fair? Douglas Holtz-Eakin Conor Ryan July 16, 2015 Medicare Advantage Stars: Are the Grades Fair? Executive Summary Medicare Advantage (MA) offers seniors a one-stop option for hospital care, outpatient physician

More information

Do Gasoline Pricing Laws Affect Prices? It Depends on the Plaintiff

Do Gasoline Pricing Laws Affect Prices? It Depends on the Plaintiff Do Gasoline Pricing Laws Affect Prices? It Depends on the Plaintiff Carson W Bays Economics Department East Carolina University Greenville, NC 27858-4353 252-328-2948 baysc@ecu.edu December 1, 2010 ABSTRACT

More information

Analysis: How Any Willing Provider Makes Health Care More Expensive

Analysis: How Any Willing Provider Makes Health Care More Expensive Analysis: How Any Willing Provider Makes Health Care More Expensive By Paul B. Ginsburg, Ph.D. Norman Topping Chair in Medicine and Public Policy University of Southern California September 23, 2014 Key

More information

Business Cycles and Divorce: Evidence from Microdata *

Business Cycles and Divorce: Evidence from Microdata * Business Cycles and Divorce: Evidence from Microdata * Judith K. Hellerstein 1 Melinda Sandler Morrill 2 Ben Zou 3 We use individual-level data to show that divorce is pro-cyclical on average, a finding

More information

Case: 10-2878 Document: 39 Page: 1 06/07/2011 308084 6. August Term, 2010. Docket Nos. 10-2786-cr(L), 10-2878-cr(CON) Appellee,

Case: 10-2878 Document: 39 Page: 1 06/07/2011 308084 6. August Term, 2010. Docket Nos. 10-2786-cr(L), 10-2878-cr(CON) Appellee, Case: 10-2878 Document: 39 Page: 1 06/07/2011 308084 6 10-2786 (L) USA v. Wolfson UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT August Term, 2010 (Argued: May 24, 2011 Decided: June 7, 2011) UNITED

More information

Medical Bills and Bankruptcy Filings. Aparna Mathur 1. Abstract. Using PSID data, we estimate the extent to which consumer bankruptcy filings are

Medical Bills and Bankruptcy Filings. Aparna Mathur 1. Abstract. Using PSID data, we estimate the extent to which consumer bankruptcy filings are Medical Bills and Bankruptcy Filings Aparna Mathur 1 Abstract Using PSID data, we estimate the extent to which consumer bankruptcy filings are induced by high levels of medical debt. Our results suggest

More information

WHEN ARE SECURITIES CLASS ACTIONS DISMISSED, WHEN DO THEY SETTLE, AND FOR HOW MUCH? PART II

WHEN ARE SECURITIES CLASS ACTIONS DISMISSED, WHEN DO THEY SETTLE, AND FOR HOW MUCH? PART II PROFESSIONAL LIABILITY UNDERWRITING SOCIETY J March As part of our education mission, the PLUS Foundation supports research important to professional liability at seven top insurance universities across

More information

Controlling Health Care Costs Through Limited Network Insurance Plans: Evidence from Massachusetts State Employees

Controlling Health Care Costs Through Limited Network Insurance Plans: Evidence from Massachusetts State Employees Controlling Health Care Costs Through Limited Network Insurance Plans: Evidence from Massachusetts State Employees Jonathan Gruber, MIT and NBER Robin McKnight, Wellesley and NBER Our Setting Massachusetts

More information

United States Court of Appeals

United States Court of Appeals United States Court of Appeals For the First Circuit No. 11-1385 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Appellee, v. ROBERT J. VENTI, Defendant, Appellant. APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT

More information

Relationship of Short Term Rates versus Projected Long Term Rates Characteristics of the Substantive Plan

Relationship of Short Term Rates versus Projected Long Term Rates Characteristics of the Substantive Plan Society of Actuaries Long Term Healthcare Trends Resource Model Practical Issues for Actuaries Prepared by Project Oversight Group Appointed for Development of the Model This document was prepared by:

More information

Going Vertical: The Hospital-Health Insurer Merger. By Christi J. Braun 1 Farrah Short

Going Vertical: The Hospital-Health Insurer Merger. By Christi J. Braun 1 Farrah Short Going Vertical: The Hospital-Health Insurer Merger By Christi J. Braun 1 Farrah Short In today s health care reform environment, efficient health care delivery, stemming soaring health care costs, and

More information

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice Gautam Gowrisankaran Claudio Lucarelli Philipp Schmidt-Dengler Robert Town January 24, 2011 Abstract This paper seeks to

More information

Accountable Care Organizations and Narrow Network Insurance Plans

Accountable Care Organizations and Narrow Network Insurance Plans Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law Commentary Accountable Care Organizations and Narrow Network Insurance Plans Ben Handel University of California, Berkeley Rapid medical care cost growth is one

More information

PREPARED STATEMENT OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. Presented by David P. Wales Deputy Director Bureau of Competition Federal Trade Commission

PREPARED STATEMENT OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. Presented by David P. Wales Deputy Director Bureau of Competition Federal Trade Commission PREPARED STATEMENT OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Presented by David P. Wales Deputy Director Bureau of Competition Federal Trade Commission before the COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE

More information

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY?

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY? AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY? Leemore Dafny, Katherine Ho and Mauricio Varela * On average, U.S. workers fortunate enough to be offered health insurance through

More information

Executive Summary. Specifically, the project gathered both primary and secondary data to meet four main research objectives:

Executive Summary. Specifically, the project gathered both primary and secondary data to meet four main research objectives: Executive Summary The overall goal of the research reported here is to provide an objective and credible assessment of the future workforce needs for lawyers in the state of California through the year

More information

STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION

STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION Lear Competition Note STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION Nov 2013 Econometric techniques can play an important role in damage quantification cases for

More information

HMOs May Be Exposed to State Law Malpractice Actions for Mixed Treatment and Eligibility Decisions. Journal of Pension Benefits Winter 2001

HMOs May Be Exposed to State Law Malpractice Actions for Mixed Treatment and Eligibility Decisions. Journal of Pension Benefits Winter 2001 HMOs May Be Exposed to State Law Malpractice Actions for Mixed Treatment and Eligibility Decisions Journal of Pension Benefits Winter 2001 Tess J. Ferrera Overview Inherent difficulties with prevailing

More information

Do You Have a Case? Truck Accident. ebooklet. Andrew Miller. 201 South 3rd Street Logansport, IN 46947 P: (574) 722-6676. www.starrausten.

Do You Have a Case? Truck Accident. ebooklet. Andrew Miller. 201 South 3rd Street Logansport, IN 46947 P: (574) 722-6676. www.starrausten. Do You Have a Case? Truck Accident ebooklet Andrew Miller 201 South 3rd Street Logansport, IN 46947 P: (574) 722-6676 www.starrausten.com Disclaimer No attempt is made to establish an attorney-client relationship

More information

Remarks on Vertical Restraints Offline & Online. Ali Hortaçsu Department of Economics University of Chicago

Remarks on Vertical Restraints Offline & Online. Ali Hortaçsu Department of Economics University of Chicago Remarks on Vertical Restraints Offline & Online Ali Hortaçsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VR 1.0: Pro-competitive? Vertical contracts and/or integration help align incentives of upstream

More information

The Effects of Unemployment on Crime Rates in the U.S.

The Effects of Unemployment on Crime Rates in the U.S. The Effects of Unemployment on Crime Rates in the U.S. Sandra Ajimotokin, Alexandra Haskins, Zach Wade April 14 th, 2015 Abstract This paper aims to analyze the relationship between unemployment and crime

More information

Reserving Issues for Workers Compensation Managed Care by Susan E. Witcraft, FCAS

Reserving Issues for Workers Compensation Managed Care by Susan E. Witcraft, FCAS Reserving Issues for Workers Compensation Managed Care by Susan E. Witcraft, FCAS 273 Reserving Issues for Workers Compensation Managed Care by Susan E. Witcraft Abstract Managed care is becoming an integral

More information

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia Occasional Studies A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia ACS Income Estimates vs. DC Individual Income Tax Data Jayron Lashgari Office of Revenue Analysis Office of the

More information

DOES A STRONG DOLLAR INCREASE DEMAND FOR BOTH DOMESTIC AND IMPORTED GOODS? John J. Heim, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, New York, USA

DOES A STRONG DOLLAR INCREASE DEMAND FOR BOTH DOMESTIC AND IMPORTED GOODS? John J. Heim, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, New York, USA DOES A STRONG DOLLAR INCREASE DEMAND FOR BOTH DOMESTIC AND IMPORTED GOODS? John J. Heim, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, New York, USA ABSTRACT Rising exchange rates strengthen the dollar and lower

More information

Statements of Antitrust. in Health Care

Statements of Antitrust. in Health Care Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care Issued by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission August 1996 TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction ~ 0 0 1 Statement 1 - Mergers

More information

Rural Primary Care Practices and Managed Care Organizations: Relationships and Risk Sharing

Rural Primary Care Practices and Managed Care Organizations: Relationships and Risk Sharing Rural Primary Care Practices and Managed Care Organizations: Relationships and Risk Sharing Michelle Brasure, Ph.D. Ira Moscovice, Ph.D. Barbara Yawn, M.D. Rural Health Research Center Division of Health

More information

A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF MARYLAND S MEDICAL CHILD CARE CENTERS* David Greenberg. Maryland Institute for Policy Analysis and Research

A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF MARYLAND S MEDICAL CHILD CARE CENTERS* David Greenberg. Maryland Institute for Policy Analysis and Research A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF MARYLAND S MEDICAL CHILD CARE CENTERS* David Greenberg Maryland Institute for Policy Analysis and Research University of Maryland, Baltimore County Prepared for the Office for

More information

Case 3:07-cv-01180-TEM Document 56 Filed 04/27/2009 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT MIDDLE DISTRICT OF FLORIDA JACKSONVILLE DIVISION

Case 3:07-cv-01180-TEM Document 56 Filed 04/27/2009 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT MIDDLE DISTRICT OF FLORIDA JACKSONVILLE DIVISION Case 3:07-cv-01180-TEM Document 56 Filed 04/27/2009 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT MIDDLE DISTRICT OF FLORIDA JACKSONVILLE DIVISION JAMES E. TOMLINSON and DARLENE TOMLINSON, his wife, v. Plaintiffs,

More information

Case 1:14-cv-03113-BMC Document 17 Filed 09/02/14 Page 1 of 7 PageID #: 79 : : : : : : : : : : : :

Case 1:14-cv-03113-BMC Document 17 Filed 09/02/14 Page 1 of 7 PageID #: 79 : : : : : : : : : : : : Case 114-cv-03113-BMC Document 17 Filed 09/02/14 Page 1 of 7 PageID # 79 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK ----------------------------------------------------------- X WILIAN ENCALADA,

More information

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market form Michael Jetter May 23, 2014 Abstract This paper unites theories about growth effects from various trade characteristics, proposing the market

More information

THE EFFECT OF NO-FAULT ON FATAL ACCIDENT RATES

THE EFFECT OF NO-FAULT ON FATAL ACCIDENT RATES -xiii- SUMMARY Thirteen states currently either mandate no-fault auto insurance or allow drivers to choose between no-fault and tort insurance. No-fault auto insurance requires individuals to carry personal

More information

****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the

****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the ****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the opinion will be published in the Connecticut Law Journal

More information

Valuation of Physician Contracts and Structuring Physician Compensation Insights from Recent Judicial Precedent

Valuation of Physician Contracts and Structuring Physician Compensation Insights from Recent Judicial Precedent Health Care Litigation Insights Valuation of Physician Contracts and Structuring Physician Compensation Insights from Recent Judicial Precedent James Rabe, CPA Health care reform continues to motivate

More information

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment by Bret Dickey 1 Jonathan Orszag 2 July 23, 2013 3 1 Bret Dickey is an Executive Vice President with

More information

No. 2--07--1205 Filed: 12-19-08 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS SECOND DISTRICT

No. 2--07--1205 Filed: 12-19-08 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS SECOND DISTRICT Filed: 12-19-08 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS SECOND DISTRICT WESTPORT INSURANCE Appeal from the Circuit Court CORPORATION, of McHenry County. Plaintiff and Counterdefendant-Appellee, v. No. 04--MR--53

More information

2015 IL App (5th) 140227-U NO. 5-14-0227 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FIFTH DISTRICT

2015 IL App (5th) 140227-U NO. 5-14-0227 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FIFTH DISTRICT NOTICE Decision filed 10/15/15. The text of this decision may be changed or corrected prior to the filing of a Petition for Rehearing or the disposition of the same. 2015 IL App (5th 140227-U NO. 5-14-0227

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No. 14-10001 Non-Argument Calendar. D.C. Docket No. 0:13-cv-61759-WPD.

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No. 14-10001 Non-Argument Calendar. D.C. Docket No. 0:13-cv-61759-WPD. Case: 14-10001 Date Filed: 02/14/2014 Page: 1 of 13 [PUBLISH] IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT No. 14-10001 Non-Argument Calendar D.C. Docket No. 0:13-cv-61759-WPD SOUTH FLORIDA

More information

THE ACCOUNTABLE CARE ORGANIZATION (ACO) TRAIN IS LEAVING THE STATION: ARE YOU ON BOARD?

THE ACCOUNTABLE CARE ORGANIZATION (ACO) TRAIN IS LEAVING THE STATION: ARE YOU ON BOARD? UNDER THE MICROSCOPE NOVEMBER 5, 2013 THE ACCOUNTABLE CARE ORGANIZATION (ACO) TRAIN IS LEAVING THE STATION: ARE YOU ON BOARD? ISSUE. A 2006 Institute of Medicine report ( Performance measurement: Accelerating

More information

POLICY NO. 3-80 LEGAL DEFENSE BENEFIT

POLICY NO. 3-80 LEGAL DEFENSE BENEFIT FLORIDA POLICE BENEVOLENT ASSOCIATION, INC. POLICY NO. 3-80 LEGAL DEFENSE BENEFIT BACKGROUND: In order to provide legal defense benefits to the members of Florida P.B.A., the Board of Directors hereby

More information

STATEMENT J. BRUCE MCDONALD DEPUTY ASSISTANT ATTORNEY GENERAL ANTITRUST DIVISION BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE CONCERNING

STATEMENT J. BRUCE MCDONALD DEPUTY ASSISTANT ATTORNEY GENERAL ANTITRUST DIVISION BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE CONCERNING STATEMENT OF J. BRUCE MCDONALD DEPUTY ASSISTANT ATTORNEY GENERAL ANTITRUST DIVISION BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY UNITED STATES SENATE CONCERNING EXAMINING COMPETITION IN GROUP HEALTH CARE PRESENTED

More information

United States District Court

United States District Court Case :0-cv-0-JSW Document Filed 0//00 Page of GOLDENE SOMERVILLE, IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA 0 Plaintiff, No. C 0-0 JSW v. STRYKER ORTHOPAEDICS ET AL, Defendants.

More information

Health Insurance in West Virginia

Health Insurance in West Virginia Cancer Legal Resource Center 919 Albany Street Los Angeles, CA 90015 Toll Free: 866.THE.CLRC (866.843.2572) Phone: 213.736.1455 TDD: 213.736.8310 Fax: 213.736.1428 Email: CLRC@LLS.edu Web: www.disabilityrightslegalcenter.org

More information

Click to edit Master title style

Click to edit Master title style Click to edit Master title style BASIC PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS FOR COMPETITION LAW Lino Briguglio University of Malta Economic principles.1 Competition as a desirable condition In mainstream Microeconomics,

More information

A&E Briefings. Indemnification Clauses: Uninsurable Contractual Liability. Structuring risk management solutions

A&E Briefings. Indemnification Clauses: Uninsurable Contractual Liability. Structuring risk management solutions A&E Briefings Structuring risk management solutions Spring 2012 Indemnification Clauses: Uninsurable Contractual Liability J. Kent Holland, J.D. ConstructionRisk, LLC Professional consultants are judged

More information

Challenging EEOC Conciliation Charges

Challenging EEOC Conciliation Charges Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Challenging EEOC Conciliation Charges Law360, New

More information

HEALTH PLAN POWER AND PRACTICES

HEALTH PLAN POWER AND PRACTICES HEALTH PLAN POWER AND PRACTICES Arthur Lerner Crowell & Moring LLP Antitrust in Healthcare American Health Lawyers Association American Bar Association Sections of Antitrust Law and Health Law May 12-13,

More information

Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition?

Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition? December 2009 (Release 1) Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition? Richard Schmalensee Massachusetts Institute of Technology & LECG www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy

More information

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY?

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY? AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY? Leemore Dafny, Katherine Ho and Mauricio Varela * On average, U.S. workers fortunate enough to be offered health insurance through

More information

A CONSUMERS GUIDE TO INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE IN ARIZONA

A CONSUMERS GUIDE TO INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE IN ARIZONA A CONSUMERS GUIDE TO INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE IN ARIZONA Published by the Arizona Department of Insurance Janet Napolitano, Governor Charles R. Cohen, Director of Insurance August 2003 1 Table of Contents

More information

By Email and Courier. April 18, 2016

By Email and Courier. April 18, 2016 By Email and Courier April 18, 2016 The Honorable William Baer (Acting) Associate Attorney General United States Department of Justice 950 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W. Washington, DC 20530 Dear Associate

More information

Life & Health Insurance Advisor

Life & Health Insurance Advisor Life & Health Insurance Advisor MRCT Benefits Plus is a comprehensive employee benefits, wellness and Human Resources consulting firm offering a variety of financial services to businesses and individuals

More information

FRCP and Physician Testimony: Treating Physicians, Experts, and Hybrid Witnesses

FRCP and Physician Testimony: Treating Physicians, Experts, and Hybrid Witnesses May, 2011 FRCP and Physician Testimony: Treating Physicians, Experts, and Hybrid Witnesses The US Court of Appeals, Ninth Circuit, rules on these matters in the case of Goodman v. Staples the Office Superstore,

More information

Where Have All the Good Jobs Gone?

Where Have All the Good Jobs Gone? Where Have All the Good Jobs Gone? John Schmitt and Janelle Jones July 2012 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite 400 Washington, D.C. 20009 202-293-5380 www.cepr.net

More information

Ninth Circuit Interprets DMCA Safe Harbor in Favor of Service Providers Like Veoh. By Yuo-Fong C. Amato, Associate

Ninth Circuit Interprets DMCA Safe Harbor in Favor of Service Providers Like Veoh. By Yuo-Fong C. Amato, Associate Ninth Circuit Interprets DMCA Safe Harbor in Favor of Service Providers Like Veoh By Yuo-Fong C. Amato, Associate The Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals recently upheld summary judgment and a Rule 12(b)(6)

More information

Reports or Connecticut Appellate Reports, the

Reports or Connecticut Appellate Reports, the ****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the opinion will be published in the Connecticut Law Journal

More information

In the Technology-Driven, File Sharing Era, Copyright Protection Remains Alive and Well As a Tool to Combat Active Inducements to Infringe

In the Technology-Driven, File Sharing Era, Copyright Protection Remains Alive and Well As a Tool to Combat Active Inducements to Infringe In the Technology-Driven, File Sharing Era, Copyright Protection Remains Alive and Well As a Tool to Combat Active Inducements to Infringe On June 27, 2005, the Supreme Court in Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios

More information

2016 IL App (4th) 150142-UB NO. 4-15-0142 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FOURTH DISTRICT

2016 IL App (4th) 150142-UB NO. 4-15-0142 IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FOURTH DISTRICT NOTICE This order was filed under Supreme Court Rule 23 and may not be cited as precedent by any party except in the limited circumstances allowed under Rule 23(e(1. 2016 IL App (4th 150142-UB NO. 4-15-0142

More information

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation Louis Kaplow * Abstract In a recent article, I demonstrated that, under standard simplifying assumptions, it is possible

More information

No. THE STATE OF TEXAS IN THE DISTRICT COURT OF. PLAINTIFF, v. TRAVIS COUNTY, TEXAS

No. THE STATE OF TEXAS IN THE DISTRICT COURT OF. PLAINTIFF, v. TRAVIS COUNTY, TEXAS No. THE STATE OF TEXAS IN THE DISTRICT COURT OF PLAINTIFF, v. TRAVIS COUNTY, TEXAS ALLIED WORLD ASSURANCE COMPANY HOLDINGS, LTD, and its JUDICIAL DISTRICT insurance subsidiaries, including ALLIED WORLD

More information

DEFINITIONS OF HEALTH INSURANCE TERMS

DEFINITIONS OF HEALTH INSURANCE TERMS DEFINITIONS OF HEALTH INSURANCE TERMS In February 2002, the Federal Government s Interdepartmental Committee on Employment-based Health Insurance Surveys approved the following set of definitions for use

More information

Districts Costs on the Rise (Figure 1)

Districts Costs on the Rise (Figure 1) $1, Districts Costs on the Rise (Figure 1) The gap between the insurance cost to school districts and the cost to private-sector employers increased from 12 percent in 24 to 26 percent by 212. 9, 8, 7,

More information

An Analysis of the Health Insurance Coverage of Young Adults

An Analysis of the Health Insurance Coverage of Young Adults Gius, International Journal of Applied Economics, 7(1), March 2010, 1-17 1 An Analysis of the Health Insurance Coverage of Young Adults Mark P. Gius Quinnipiac University Abstract The purpose of the present

More information

The Uninsured s Hidden Tax on Health Insurance Premiums in California: How Reliable Is the Evidence?

The Uninsured s Hidden Tax on Health Insurance Premiums in California: How Reliable Is the Evidence? The Uninsured s Hidden Tax on Health Insurance Premiums in California: How Reliable Is the Evidence? John F. Cogan, Matthew Gunn, Daniel P. Kessler, Evan J. Lodes The basic premise behind many recent California

More information

Comments Qualified Health Plan Model Contract Updated Redline (4-22-13)

Comments Qualified Health Plan Model Contract Updated Redline (4-22-13) Making Sense of Health Insurance Oversight in California kelchpolicy.com Comments Qualified Health Plan Model Contract Updated Redline (4-22-13) The Health Insurance Alignment Project (Project) has reviewed

More information

COURT OF APPEALS OF WISCONSIN PUBLISHED OPINION PLAINTIFFS-APPELLANTS, DEFENDANT-RESPONDENT, DEFENDANT.

COURT OF APPEALS OF WISCONSIN PUBLISHED OPINION PLAINTIFFS-APPELLANTS, DEFENDANT-RESPONDENT, DEFENDANT. 2000 WI App 171 COURT OF APPEALS OF WISCONSIN PUBLISHED OPINION Case No.: 99-0776 Complete Title of Case: RONNIE PROPHET AND BADON PROPHET, V. PLAINTIFFS-APPELLANTS, ENTERPRISE RENT-A-CAR COMPANY, INC.,

More information

The effect of physician hospital affiliations on hospital prices in California

The effect of physician hospital affiliations on hospital prices in California Journal of Health Economics 25 (2006) 29 38 The effect of physician hospital affiliations on hospital prices in California Federico Ciliberto a,, David Dranove b a Department of Economics, University of

More information

This article presents a simple framework

This article presents a simple framework Net flows in the U.S. labor market, 990 200 Except in the most recent recession, net flows were from unemployment to employment (even in previous recessions), from employment to not in the labor force

More information

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT OF OHIO HAMILTON COUNTY, OHIO

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT OF OHIO HAMILTON COUNTY, OHIO IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT OF OHIO HAMILTON COUNTY, OHIO TINA R. SAID (Deceased), and STEVEN M. SAID (Widower/Claimant), Plaintiffs-Appellees/Cross- Appellants, vs. ADMINISTRATOR,

More information

Can You Trust A Certificate Of Insurance?

Can You Trust A Certificate Of Insurance? Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Can You Trust A Certificate Of Insurance? Law360,

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Prescription Drugs as a Starting Point for Medicare Reform Testimony before the Senate Budget Committee

Prescription Drugs as a Starting Point for Medicare Reform Testimony before the Senate Budget Committee Prescription Drugs as a Starting Point for Medicare Reform Testimony before the Senate Budget Committee Marilyn Moon The nonpartisan Urban Institute publishes studies, reports, and books on timely topics

More information

How To Calculate Export Earnings

How To Calculate Export Earnings Do Jobs In Export Industries Still Pay More? And Why? by David Riker Office of Competition and Economic Analysis July 2010 Manufacturing and Services Economics Briefs are produced by the Office of Competition

More information

the Code of Civil Procedure (Code) (735 ILCS 5/2-619 (West 2004)) of their claim that

the Code of Civil Procedure (Code) (735 ILCS 5/2-619 (West 2004)) of their claim that FIRST DIVISION 05/21/07 No. 1-05-2368 BERNARD VILLANUEVA and LISA VILLANUEVA, Plaintiffs-Appellants, v. TOYOTA MOTOR SALES, U.S.A., INC., and GROSSINGER CITY AUTOCORP, INC., d/b/a Grossinger City Toyota,

More information

Much Ado About Injury: Making Sense Of FTAIA Circuit Split

Much Ado About Injury: Making Sense Of FTAIA Circuit Split Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Much Ado About Injury: Making Sense Of FTAIA Circuit

More information

OPINION Richard B. Klein DATE: June 14, 2001. Plaintiff, Patricia Daniels, filed this lawsuit on behalf of

OPINION Richard B. Klein DATE: June 14, 2001. Plaintiff, Patricia Daniels, filed this lawsuit on behalf of PATRICIA DANIELS, p/n/g of : PHILADELPHIA COUNTY RODERICK STERLING, a minor : COURT OF COMMON PLEAS : TRIAL DIVISION v. : June Term, 1996 : HOSPITAL OF PHILADELPHIA : NO. 2450 COLLEGE OF OSTEOPATHIC :

More information

SUPREME COURT OF MISSOURI en banc

SUPREME COURT OF MISSOURI en banc SUPREME COURT OF MISSOURI en banc MORRIS JONES and ) PAMELA BROWN, ) ) Appellants/Cross-Respondents, ) ) vs. ) No. SC89844 ) MID-CENTURY INSURANCE CO., ) ) Respondent/Cross-Appellant. ) Appeal from the

More information

The Reallocation of Compensation in Response to Health Insurance Premium Increases

The Reallocation of Compensation in Response to Health Insurance Premium Increases The Reallocation of Compensation in Response to Health Insurance Premium Increases DANA P. GOLDMAN NEERAJ SOOD ARLEEN A. LEIBOWITZ WR-107 March 2003 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE REALLOCATION OF COMPENSATION

More information

Managed care has attracted considerable interest as a possible way to

Managed care has attracted considerable interest as a possible way to DataWatch Potential Impact Of Managed Care On National Health Spending by Verdon S. Staines Abstract: Illustrative estimates suggest that if all acute health care services were delivered through staff-

More information

An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements

An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements

More information