Uniform Tail Asymptotics for the Stochastic Present Value of Aggregate Claims in the Renewal Risk Model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Uniform Tail Asymptotics for the Stochastic Present Value of Aggregate Claims in the Renewal Risk Model"

Transcription

1 Uniform Tail Asymptotics for the Stochastic Present Value of Aggregate Claims in the Renewal Risk Model Qihe Tang [a], Guojing Wang [b];, and Kam C. Yuen [c] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, The University of Iowa 24 Schae er Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA [b] Department of Mathematics, Suzhou University Suzhou 256, PR China [c] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, The University of Hong Kong Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong December 25, 29 Abstract Consider an insurer who is allowed to make risk-free and risky investments. The price process of the investment portfolio is described as a geometric Lévy process. We study the tail probability of the stochastic present value of future aggregate claims. When the claim-size distribution is of Pareto type, we obtain a simple asymptotic formula which holds uniformly for all time horizons. The same asymptotic formula holds for the nite-time and in nite-time ruin probabilities. Restricting our attention to the so-called constant investment strategy, we show how the insurer adjusts his investment portfolio to maximize the expected terminal wealth subject to a constraint on the ruin probability. Keywords: Asymptotics; Constant investment strategy; Lévy process; Portfolio optimization; Regular variation; Ruin probability; Uniformity. Mathematics Subject Classi cation: Primary 9B3; Secondary 6G5, 6K5, 9B28 Introduction Consider the renewal risk model in which successive claims, X ; X 2 ; : : :, form a sequence of independent, identically distributed (i.i.d.), and nonnegative random variables with generic Corresponding author: Guojing Wang.

2 random variable X and common distribution F on [; ), and their arrival times, 2, constitute a renewal counting process N t = # fn = ; 2; : : : : n tg ; t : For later use, we write = and =. To avoid triviality, throughout the paper, we assume that is a nonnegative random variable non-degenerate at. The amount of aggregate claims up to time t appears to be a compound sum of the form XN t S t = X k ; t ; (.) where the summation over an empty set of indices produces a value of. Suppose that the insurer is allowed to make risk-free and risky investments. The price process of the investment portfolio is described as a geometric Lévy process fe Rt ; t g; that is to say, fr t ; t g is a Lévy process which starts with, has independent and stationary increments, and is stochastically continuous. This assumption on price processes is widely used in mathematical nance. We refer the reader to the monograph of Cont and Tankov (24) and a recent survey paper of Paulsen (28). See also Paulsen (993, 22), Paulsen and Gjessing (997), Wang and Wu (2), Kalashnikov and Norberg (22), Cai (24), and Yuen et al. (24, 26), among others. For the general theory of Lévy processes, see Sato (999), Cont and Tankov (24), and Applebaum (24). As usual, we assume that all sources of randomness, fx ; X 2 ; : : :g, fn t ; t g, and fr t ; t g, are mutually independent. The stochastic present value of future aggregate claims up to time t can be expressed as D t = e R s ds s = X X k e R k ( k t); t : (.2) In this paper, we shall focus on the tail probability of D t and aim at a simple asymptotic formula which holds uniformly for all time horizons. We shall also pursue applications of our result to ruin theory. The rest of the paper consists of three sections. Section 2 presents our rst main result after recalling some preliminaries; Section 3 shows applications of this result to the calculation of the nite-time and in nite-time ruin probabilities and to a portfolio optimization problem with a constraint on the nite-time ruin probability; and Section 4 proves the results after presenting a series of lemmas. 2 Preliminaries and Main Result Throughout the paper, we assume that the Lévy process fr t ; t g in (.2) is right continuous with left limit with Lévy triplet (r; 2 ; ), where < r <, are two constants and is a measure on ( ; ), called the Lévy measure, satisfying (fg) = 2

3 and R (y2 ^ )(dy) <. Let ER >, so that R t drifts to almost surely as t. The Laplace exponent for fr t ; t g is de ned as If (z) is nite, then and (z) = log Ee zr ; z 2 ( ; ): (2.) (z) = 2 2 z 2 rz + Z e zy + zy ( ;) (y) (dy); Ee zrt = e t(z) < ; t ; see, for example, Proposition 3.4 of Cont and Tankov (24). We refer the reader to Cont and Tankov (24) and Klüppelberg and Kostadinova (28) for explicit expressions for the Laplace exponent () for some commonly used Lévy processes. Recall the renewal function of the renewal counting process fn t ; t g, de ned as X t = EN t = Pr ( k t) ; t : (2.2) In particular, if fn t ; t g is a Poisson process with intensity >, then t = t; and if follows a (2; ) distribution, then t = t=2 e 2t =4. More general examples of the renewal counting process fn t ; t g allowing explicit forms of the renewal function t can be found in Asmussen (23, pages 88 and 48). Denote by the set of all t for which < t. With t = infft : Pr ( t) > g, it is clear that [t; ]; if Pr ( = t) > ; = (t; ]; if Pr ( = t) = : For notational convenience, we write T = [; T ] \ for every xed T 2. We shall assume that the claim-size distribution F is regularly varying tailed, hence heavy tailed; that is, F (x) = F (x) > holds for all x and there is some constant, < <, such that the relation F (xy) lim x F (x) = y (2.3) holds for all y >. We use F 2 R to signify the regularity property in (2.3) and use R to denote the union of all R over the range < <. The class R contains a lot of popular distributions such as Pareto, Burr, Loggamma, and t distributions. Hereafter, all limit relationships are for x unless stated otherwise. For two positive functions a() and b(), we write a(x). b(x) if lim sup a(x)=b(x), a(x) & b(x) if lim inf a(x)=b(x), and a(x) b(x) if both. Furthermore, for two positive bivariate functions a(; ) and b(; ), we say that the asymptotic relation a(x; t) b(x; t) holds uniformly for t in a nonempty set if lim sup a(x; t) x b(x; t) = : t2 3

4 Clearly, the asymptotic relation a(x; t) b(x; t) holds uniformly for t 2 if and only if a(x; t) lim sup sup x t2 b(x; t) and lim inf inf a(x; t) x t2 b(x; t) ; which mean that the relations a(x; t). b(x; t) and a(x; t) & b(x; t), respectively, hold uniformly for t 2. We are now ready to state the main result of this paper: Theorem 2.. Consider the insurance risk model introduced in Section in which the claimsize distribution F belongs to the class R for some < < and the Laplace exponent of the Lévy process fr t ; t g satis es ( ) < for some >. Then, it holds uniformly for all t 2 that Pr (D t > x) F (x) (2.4) Taking t = in relation (2.4) yields a more transparent asymptotic formula: Ee () Pr (D > x) F (x) Ee : () Roughly speaking, the condition ( ) < in Theorem 2. means that the impact of the insurance claims dominates that of the nancial uncertainty. This is also con rmed by relation (2.4), which shows that the tail probability of the claim-size distribution determines the exact decay rate while the nancial uncertainty and the claim frequency only contribute to the coe cient of the asymptotic formula. From (2.) it is easy to verify that (z) is convex in z for which (z) is nite. Since () =, we see that the condition ( ) < implies that (z) < for all z 2 (; ]. In addition, by Jensen s inequality, the condition ( ) < implies that ER >. Hence, R t drifts to almost surely as t. As shown in Lemma 4.2 below, relation (2.4) with xed t 2 is an easy consequence of the one-dimensional version of Theorem 2. given in Resnick and Willekens (99). However, it is much harder to prove the claimed uniformity of relation (2.4), which is in essence the scienti c value of the present work. Note that the result of Resnick and Willekens (99) has recently been extended in many ways by Goovaerts et al. (25), Wang and Tang (26), Zhang et al. (29), and Chen and Yuen (29). Therefore, starting with these extended results, it should be possible and routine, but rather laborious, to further extend Theorem 2. to a somewhat broader class of heavy-tailed distributions (for example, the class of distributions with extended regularly varying tails), and to the case that claim sizes possess a certain dependence structure (for example, pairwise asymptotic independence). We shall not pursue such extensions in this paper. However, it would be interesting to establish results similar to Theorem 2. in the presence of certain dependence structures among the sources of randomness, fx ; X 2 ; : : :g, fn t ; t g, and fr t ; t g. 4

5 3 Applications to Ruin Theory 3. Finite- and In nite-time Ruin Probabilities Consider an insurance business commencing at time with initial wealth x. The cash ow of premiums less claims is modeled as a compound renewal process with the form C t = ct S t ; t ; (3.) where c is a xed rate of premium payment and fs t ; t g is a compound renewal process given in (.). Recall that the price process of the investment portfolio is the geometric Lévy process fe Rt ; t g. Thus, the wealth process of the insurer is described as U t = e x Rt + e R s dc s ; t : (3.2) As usual, de ne the ruin time of this risk model as T (x) = inf ft > : U t < j U = xg ; with the convention that inf? =. Then, the probability of ruin by a nite time t is and the probability of ultimate ruin is (x; t) = Pr (T (x) t) ; (x; ) = Pr (T (x) < ) : Yuen et al. (24, 26) studied the in nite-time ruin probability and related quantities of this renewal risk model. For the special case that fn t ; t g is a Poisson process, following their approach, it is not hard to establish an integro di erential equation and an integral equation for the in nite-time ruin probability. We shall not extend such a discussion here as we are mainly interested in the asymptotic behavior of the nite-time and in nite-time ruin probabilities. Theorem 3.. Consider the insurance risk model introduced above. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., it holds uniformly for all t 2 that (x; t) F (x) In particular, putting t = gives (3.3) Ee () (x; ) F (x) : (3.4) () Ee Paulsen (22) obtained relation (3.4) for the special case that fn t ; t g is a Poisson process and fr t ; t g is a Brownian motion with positive drift; see Proposition 4. of 5

6 Paulsen (22). The reader is also referred to Heyde and Wang (29) for a result for the nite-time ruin probability similar to (3.3) but with a xed-time horizon and fn t ; t g being a Poisson process. Due to the uniformity of relation (3.3), we can easily derive an explicit asymptotic expression for the Laplace transform of the ruin time T (x). Corollary 3.. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., it holds for every r that Ee (() Ee rt (x) (T (x)<) F (x) : (3.5) (() r) Ee Proof. When r =, relation (3.5) coincides with relation (3.4). Thus, we only need to consider r >. For this case the indicator (T (x)<) in (3.5) can be eliminated. By the uniformity of relation (3.3), we have Z Z Ee rt (x) = r (x; t)e rt dt rf (x) e ()s d s e rt dt: Using Fubini s theorem to interchange the order of integrals, Z Z Z e ()s d s e rt dt = e rt dt e ()s d s = r Therefore, (3.5) holds. s r) Z 3.2 Portfolio Optimization with a Constraint on Ruin e (() r)s d s : It is commonly acknowledged that risky investments may impair the insurer s solvency just as severely as large claims do; see Kalashnikov and Norberg (22) and Tang and Tsitsiashvili (23). Frolova et al. (22) also pointed out that disasters may arrive during the period when the market value of assets is low and the company will not be able to cover losses by selling these assets. In this section, we consider a so-called constant investment portfolio and determine the optimal investment strategy that maximizes the insurer s expected terminal wealth and maintains the insurer s solvency. Such optimization problems have been considered by several authors; see, for example, Schmidli (22), Paulsen (23), and Kostadinova (27). For simplicity, we assume that a nancial market consists of two assets, which can be traded continuously. One of them is a risk-free asset with price process satisfying dp () t = r P () t dt; t > ; with P () = and r >, while the other is a risky asset with price process satisfying dp () t = P () t dq t ; t > ; (3.6) with P () = and fq t ; t g being a Lévy process with Lévy triplet (r Q ; 2 Q ; Q), as described in Section 2. Suppose that the insurer continuously invests a constant fraction 6

7 2 [; ] of his wealth in the risky asset and keeps the remaining wealth in the risk-free asset. This constant investment strategy is commonly used in mathematical nance and actuarial science; see, for example, Björk (998), Emmer et al. (2), Emmer and Klüppelberg (24), Kostadinova (27), and Klüppelberg and Kostadinova (28). The price process of this investment portfolio satis es the stochastic di erential equation dp () t = P () t dq () t ; t > ; (3.7) with P () = and Q () t = ( )r t + Q t for t. From Theorem 4. of Cont and Tankov (24) (see also Proposition. of Sato (999)), the Lévy triplet of the Lévy process fq () t ; t g is given by 8 < : r = ( )r + r Q + R y ( ;)(y) (y) (dy); 2 = 2 2 Q ; (A) = Q (fx : x 2 Ag) for every Borel set A; where = fx : jxj < g. Hence, by Proposition 8.22 of Cont and Tankov (24) or Theorem 37 in Chapter 2 of Protter (25), we solve (3.7) to get where P () t = e R() t ; t ; R () t = ( )r t + Q t 2 2 Q 2 t + X with Q s = Q s Q s. The solution P () t exponential of the Lévy process fq () t (24), the Lévy triplet of fr () t 8 < : <st (ln( + Q s ) Q s ) ; given above is recognized as the stochastic ; t g. By Proposition 8.22 of Cont and Tankov ; t g is given by r = r R ln( + y) ( ;)(ln( + y)) y ( ;) (y) (dy); 2 = 2 ; (A) = (fy : ln( + y) 2 Ag) for every Borel set A: Using the Lévy triplet of fq t ; t g, one obtains the Laplace exponent of fr () t ; t g as (z) = Z Qz 2 ( )r + r Q Q y Q (dy) z + Z (( + y) z ) Q (dy); (3.8) provided that the second integral in (3.8) is nite. Note that Q (( ; ]) = since the price process fp () t ; t g in (3.6) is positive. It follows from (3.8) that where = r Q r + R y Q (dy). ( ) = r + ; (3.9) 7

8 Consider a xed-time horizon t >, say t = 5. Our goal is to determine a value 2 [; ] that maximizes the expected value of the terminal wealth = e R() t x + e R() s dc s ; (3.) U () t subject to the following constraint on the ruin probability: (x; t ) = Pr inf U s () < st U = x p; (3.) where fc t ; t g is given in (3.) and p is some small positive number, say p = 5%. Let the conditions of Theorem 3. hold, and let > so that the i.i.d. claims have a nite mean = EX. Simple calculation gives EU () t = xe ( )t + e ( )(t s) d (cs s ) : (3.2) Since there is usually no closed-form expression for (x; t ) available, we use its approximation given in (2.4); that is to say, we replace (3.) by (x; t ) F (x) e ()s d s p: (3.3) For given x >, >, t >, and < p <, de ne = : 2 [; ] and F (x) e ()s d s p : Suppose? 6= f : () < g. Every 2 is called an admissible investment strategy. With > given, we see from (3.8) that (), as a function of, is convex in 2 [; ] with () = r <. Hence, is a closed interval in [; ]. Let = [a x ; b x ] [; ]. To simplify the optimization problem, we assume that s is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure; that is to say, there exists a nonnegative and measurable function s such that s = R s udu for s 2 [; ). We further assume that the relation c s (3.4) holds almost everywhere for s 2 [; ). Relation (3.4) can be interpreted as the safety loading condition of the insurance portfolio. It is veri able for many interesting cases, for example, when follows an exponential distribution or a (2; ) distribution. Under (3.4), the expectation EU () t, as expressed in (3.2), is increasing in ( ). Hence, the optimization problem becomes maximizing ( ) subject to 2 : (3.5) From (3.9), we see that ( ) is increasing in 2 [; ] when > and decreasing in 2 [; ] when <. Hence, if >, the solution to (3.5) is = b x ; (3.6) 8

9 while if <, the solution to (3.5) is = a x : (3.7) When =, however, ( ) = r does not depend on. Thus, every admissible strategy 2 could be used as a solution to (3.5). Nevertheless, in order to reduce uncertainty from the risky asset, we may choose (3.7) as the solution. The optimization solutions (3.6) and (3.7) are intuitively clear. The condition > means that the expected return rate of the risky asset is higher than that of the risk-free asset. Hence, as (3.6) shows, the insurer will invest as much as he is allowed in the risky asset. The optimization solution (3.7) can be explained in a similar way. Moreover, we have the following observation. In modern portfolio theory, the quantity 2 Q, which is the volatility when fq t ; t g is a Brownian motion with drift, is often used to measure the risk of the risky asset. Recall relation (3.8) and the de nition of. Clearly, () is increasing in 2 Q. Hence, both a x and b x are decreasing in 2 Q, meaning that the riskier the risky asset is, the less the insurer will invest in it. 4 Proofs 4. Lemmas Let us rst recall some properties of distributions with regularly varying tails. By Theorem.5.2 of Bingham et al. (987), the convergence in relation (2.3) is uniform over ["; ) for every xed " > ; that is to say, lim sup x y2[";) F (xy) F (x) y = : (4.) By Theorem.5.6 of Bingham et al. (987), the well-known Potter s bounds for distributions in the class R are stated as follows. If F 2 R for some < <, then for arbitrarily xed b > and " >, there exists some x > such that, for all x; y x, b (y=x) +" ^ (y=x) " F (y) F (x) b (y=x) +" _ (y=x) " : (4.2) For arbitrarily xed < < < <, by xing the variable y to x and " < ( ) ^ ( ) in (4.2), we see that F (x) = o x ; x = o F (x) : (4.3) Let X and Y be two independent random variables with X following a distribution F 2 R for some < < and Y being a nonnegative random variable satisfying EY < for some >. Then, for every xed M, with x > given in (4.2), we have Pr (XY > x; Y > M) lim x F (x) = lim x Pr (XY > x; Y 2 (M; x=x ] [ (x=x ; )) F (x) = EY (Y >M) ; (4.4) 9

10 where we used the dominated convergence theorem guaranteed by (4.2) in dealing with the rst part corresponding to Y 2 (M; x=x ], and used Markov s inequality and the second relation of (4.3) in dealing with the second part. Relation (4.4) with M = is well known, and is usually referred to as Breiman s theorem; see Breiman (965). The following result is the one-dimensional version of Theorem 2. of Resnick and Willekens (99): Lemma 4.. Consider the randomly weighted sum S (W ) = X W k X k ; where fx ; X 2 ; : : :g is a sequence of i.i.d. nonnegative random variables with common distribution F 2 R for some < <, and fw ; W 2 ; : : :g is another sequence of nonnegative random variables independent of fx ; X 2 ; : : :g. We have Pr S (W ) > x F (x) if one of the following assumptions holds:. < < and for some < " < ^ ( ), X 2. < and for some < " <, X EWk ; E W +" k _ W " k < ; X E W +" k _ W " +" k < : Lemma 4.2. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., relation (2.4) holds for every xed t 2. Proof. We apply Lemma 4. to the series D t given in (.2). For < <, we choose some < " < ^ ( ) ^ ( ) so that X E e (+")R k _ e ( Z X E e (+")Rs + e ( = Ee(+") Ee + Ee( ") (+") Ee < : ")R k ( k t) ( ") ")Rs Pr ( k 2 ds)

11 Similarly, for <, we choose some < " < ^ ( ) to justify that X Therefore, by Lemma 4., Pr (D t > x) F (x) E e (+")R k _ e ( ")R k +" ( k t) < : X Ee R k ( k t) = F (x) This proves that relation (2.4) holds for every xed t 2. Lemma 4.3. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., for every xed T 2, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that Pr Xe R (t) > x F (x) e s() Pr ( 2 ds) : (4.5) Proof. Conditioning on, we have Pr Xe R (t) > x = Pr Xe Rs > x Pr ( 2 ds) : For an arbitrarily xed large number M >, according to (jr s j M), (R s > M), and (R s < M), we split the right-hand side of the above into three parts as I (x; t) + I 2 (x; t) + I 3 (x; t). By relation (4.), it holds uniformly for all t 2 that I (x; t) = F (x) = F (x) Pr Xe Rs > x; jr s j M Pr ( 2 ds) Ee Rs (jrsjm) Pr ( 2 ds) e s() Pr ( 2 ds) F (x) Ee Rs (jrsj>m) Pr ( 2 ds) : Thus, it su ces to show that the terms I 2 (x; t), I 3 (x; t), and the last term above, denoted as I 4 (x; t), are negligible for large M >, uniformly for all t 2 T, in comparison to F (x) R t e s() Pr ( 2 ds). More precisely, we are going to prove that, for j = 2; 3; 4, For I 2 (x; t), we have lim sup M I 2 (x; t) = lim sup x I j (x; t) sup t2 T F (x) R t = : (4.6) e s() Pr ( 2 ds) Pr Xe Rs > x; R s > M Pr ( 2 ds) Pr Xe M > x Pr ( t) e M F (x) Pr ( t) :

12 Trivially, Pr ( t) e T () This proves relation (4.6) with j = 2. For I 3 (x; t), we have e s() Pr ( 2 ds) : (4.7) I 3 (x; t) = Pr Xe Rs > x; R s < M Pr ( 2 ds) Pr Xe inf st R s > x; inf s < st M Pr ( t) : (4.8) Note that, for all T and x > x >, Pr inf s > x Pr sup R s > st st x Pr ( R T > x x ) ; see the lemma of Willekens (987). This, together with Ee R T = e T () <, implies that Ee inf st R s < : Hence, applying (4.4) to (4.8), it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that I 3 (x; t). Ee inf st R s (infst R s< M) F (x) Pr ( t) : This, together with (4.7), proves relation (4.6) with j = 3. Finally, for I 4 (x; t), by Hölder s inequality, Ee Rs (jrsj>m) Pr ( 2 ds) Ee R s = Pr (jrs j > M) Pr sup st jr s j > M = Pr ( t) : = Pr ( 2 ds) Hence, by (4.7), relation (4.6) with j = 4 holds and we conclude the proof. Lemma 4.4. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., for every xed T 2 and n = ; 2; : : :, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x F (x) e s() Pr ( k 2 ds) : Proof. By Lemma 4.3, it su ces to prove that, uniformly for all t 2 T, Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x : (4.9) 2

13 We rst prove the lower-bound version of relation (4.9). Clearly, Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x Pr n[ X k e R k ( k t) > x Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x X k<jn Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x; X j e R j ( j t) > x : Thus, it remains to verify that the second term above is negligible, uniformly for all t 2 T, in comparison to the rst term. Actually, for arbitrarily xed k < j n and M >, Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x; X j e R j ( j t) > x Pr X k e Rs > x; e Rs X j e R j +R k ( j t) > x; e Rs x k = s Pr ( k 2 ds) M + Pr e Rs > x Pr ( k 2 ds) M = I (x; t) + I 2 (x; t): Note that e Rs and e R j +R k in I (x; t) conditional on ( k = s) are independent. It holds for arbitrarily xed " > and all large M > that I (x; t) Pr X j sup e Rs > M Pr X k e Rs > x Pr ( k 2 ds) st " Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x : For I 2 (x; t), by Markov s inequality, the second relation of (4.3), relation (4.7), and Lemma 4.3, we have I 2 (x; t) x Ee R s Pr ( k 2 ds) M x Pr ( k t) M = o()f (x) e s() Pr ( k 2 ds) = o() Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x : Therefore, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x; X j e R j ( j t) > x = o() Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x : (4.) We next prove the upper-bound version of relation (4.9). For arbitrarily xed < <, we 3

14 derive Pr Pr + Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x n[ X k e R k ( k t) > x x X k e R k ( k t) > x; = I 3 (x; t) + I 4 (x; t): n[ X k e R k ( k t) > x ; n n\ X k e R k ( k t) x x By Lemma 4.3, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that I 3 (x; t) Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x x ( ) Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x : Thus, it remains to verify that I 4 (x; t) is negligible, uniformly for all t 2 T, in comparison to I 3 (x; t). Indeed, we have I 4 (x; t) k e R k ( k t) > x n ; X X j e R j ( j t) > xa X k6=jn = o() j2f;:::;ngnfkg Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x n ; X je R j ( j t) > x n Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x ; where in the last step we used relation (4.) and Lemma 4.3. This ends the proof. Lemma 4.5. Under the conditions of Theorem 2., for every xed T 2, it holds for every " >, for all large n, and uniformly for all t 2 T that X Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x. "F (x) k=n+ Proof. Choose some > such that ( ) >. Then, X Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x + k=n+ X Pr e Rs X k e R k +Rn ( k t) > x; e Rs x k=n+ Pr e Rs > x Pr ( n 2 ds) = I (x; t) + I 2 (x; t): n = s Pr ( n 2 ds) 4

15 For I (x; t), note that, by Lemma 4.2, it holds uniformly for all s t 2 T that X Pr X k e R k +Rn ( k t) > x n = s = Pr (D t s > x) k=n+ Pr (D T > x) F (x) Z T e u() d u : Thus, by further conditioning on e Rs, it can be shown that, uniformly for all t 2 T, I (x; t). Pr Xe Rs > x; e Rs x Z T e u() d u Pr ( n 2 ds) T F (x) T Pr Xe Rs > x Pr ( n 2 ds) F (x) T Pr ( n t) ; e s() Pr ( n 2 ds) where in the third step we used Lemma 4.3. Following the proof of Lemma 5.3 of Tang (24), we have lim sup EN t (Nt>n) = : (4.) n t2 T t Therefore, it holds for all large n and uniformly for all t 2 T that I (x; t). "F (x) By Markov s inequality and the second relation of (4.3), it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that This ends the proof. I 2 (x; t) x ( x ( ) ) = o()f (x) Ee R s Pr ( n 2 ds) e s() d s Lemma 4.6. Let Z be an exponential functional of a Lévy process fr t ; t g de ned as Z = Then, we have the following two results: Z e Rt dt: (4.2). Z < almost surely if and only if R t almost surely as t ; 2. If > and () <, then EZ <. Proof. See Subsection 2. of Maulik and Zwart (26). 5

16 4.2 Proof of Theorem 2. By Lemma 4.2, relation (2.4) holds for every xed t 2. We formulate the proof of the uniformity into two steps. First, we establish the local uniformity of relation (2.4); that is, for arbitrarily xed T 2, relation (2.4) holds uniformly for all t 2 T. For arbitrarily xed < < and n = ; 2; : : :, we have Pr (D t > x) Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x = I (x; t) + I 2 (x; t): x + Pr X X k e R k ( k t) > x k=n+ By Lemma 4.4, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that I (x; t). ( ) F (x) By Lemma 4.5, for arbitrarily xed " >, it holds for all large n and uniformly for all t 2 T that I 2 (x; t). " F (x) (4.3) It follows that, uniformly for all t 2 T, Pr (D t > x). ( ) + " F (x) By the arbitrariness of " and, we prove that, uniformly for all t 2 T, Pr (D t > x). F (x) The corresponding lower bound can be constructed in a similar way. Actually, by Lemma 4.4, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that Pr (D t > x) Pr X k e R k ( k t) > x F (x) e s() d s X k=n+ F (x) Ee n() Pr ( k 2 ds) Since Ee n() tends to as n, it follows that, uniformly for all t 2 T, Pr (D t > x) & F (x) 6

17 Next, we extend the uniformity of relation (2.4) to. For arbitrarily xed < " <, choose some large T 2 such that Z e s() d s " Z T T Let t 2 [T; ] and apply (4.4) and Lemma 4.2. On the one hand, (4.4) Pr (D t > x) Pr (D > x) F (x) and on the other hand, Z e s() d s ( + ")F (x) e s() d s ; Pr (D t > x) Pr (D T > x) F (x) Z T + " F (x) + " F (x) e s() d s Z e s() d s By these two estimates and the arbitrariness of ", we see that relation (2.4) holds also uniformly for all t 2 [T; ]. 4.3 Proof of Theorem 3. Substituting (3.) into (3.2) yields that, for every t 2, Z s (x; t) = Pr x + c e Ru du D s < ; (4.5) inf st where s t is understood as s < when t =. Therefore, it follows immediately from Theorem 2. that, uniformly for all t 2, (x; t) Pr (D t > x). F (x) It remains to derive the corresponding uniform asymptotic lower bound for (x; t). Still start from (4.5) and let T 2 be arbitrarily xed. It holds for arbitrarily xed > and all T t that (x; t) Pr D t c Z Pr (D t > ( + )x) e Ru du > x By Theorem 2., it holds uniformly for all t 2 that Pr c Z Pr (D t > ( + )x) ( + ) F (x) 7 e Ru du > x : (4.6)

18 By Markov s inequality, Pr c Z e Ru du > x Z x E e Ru du ; c where the niteness of E R e Ru du is guaranteed by Lemma 4.6. Substituting these two estimates into (4.6) and using the arbitrariness of, we see that, uniformly for all T t, (x; t) & F (x) (4.7) We now focus on the uniformity of (4.7) over t 2 T. Clearly, Z Nt (x; t) Pr D Nt c e Ru du > x X Z k = Pr X k e R k c e Ru du ( k t) > x : k It follows that, for arbitrarily xed > and n = ; 2; : : :, (x; t) Pr X k e R k ( k t) > ( + 2)x Pr c Pr c X k=n+ Z k k e Ru du ( k t) > x Z k k e Ru du ( k t) > x = I (x; t) I 2 (x; t) I 3 (x; t): (4.8) By Lemma 4.4, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that I (x; t) ( + 2) F (x) e s() Pr ( k 2 ds) ( + 2) Ee n() F (x) Introduce a random variable Z independent of fr t ; t g, fn t ; t g and equal in distribution to R e Rt dt. By Lemma 4.6, EZ <. Hence, by Markov s inequality and the second relation of (4.3), Pr(Z > x) = o(f (x)). It holds uniformly for all t 2 T that Z k I 2 (x; t) Pr e Ru du ( k t) > x k cn Z s Pr e Ru du > x Pr ( k 2 ds) cn Pr Z > x Pr ( k t) cn = o()f (x) 8

19 For arbitrarily xed < " <, further introduce a nonnegative random variable Z " independent of fr t ; t g, fn t ; t g and with tail given by Pr (Z " > x) = "F (x) _ Pr(Z > x); x : Hence, Pr (Z " > x) "F (x) and the distribution of Z " belongs to the class R too. Clearly, X Z k I 3 (x; t) Pr ce Rn ( nt) e (Ru Rn) du > x k=n+ k = Pr Ze Rn ( nt) > x c Pr Z " e Rn ( nt) > x : c By Lemma 4.3, it holds uniformly for all t 2 T that I 3 (x; t). Pr Z " > x e s() Pr ( n 2 ds). "c F (x) c Substituting these estimates into (4.8), we obtain that, uniformly for all t 2 T, (x; t) & ( + 2) Ee n() "c F (x) By the arbitrariness of, ", and n, relation (4.7) holds uniformly for all t 2 T. Acknowledgments. The authors would like to thank the anonymous referee for his/her careful reading and useful comments. Qihe Tang acknowledges support of the 28 Old Gold Summer Fellowship from the University of Iowa, Guojing Wang acknowledges support of the Natural Science Foundation of Jiangsu Province (Grant No: KB2855), and Kam C. Yuen acknowledges support of a research grant from the University of Hong Kong. References [] Applebaum, D. Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 24. [2] Asmussen, S. Ruin Probabilities. World Scienti c, London, 23. [3] Bingham, N. H.; Goldie, C. M.; Teugels, J. L. Regular Variation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 987. [4] Björk, T. Arbitrage Theory in Continuous Time. Oxford University Press, New York, 998. [5] Breiman, L. On some limit theorems similar to the arc-sin law. Theory Prob. Appl. (965)

20 [6] Cai, J. Ruin probabilities and penalty functions with stochastic rates of interest. Stochastic Process. Appl. 2 (24), no., [7] Chen, Y.; Yuen, K. C. Sums of pairwise quasi-asymptotically independent random variables with consistent variation. Stoch. Models 25 (29), no., [8] Cont, R.; Tankov, P. Financial Modelling with Jump Processes. Chapman & Hall/CRC, Boca Raton, FL, 24. [9] Emmer, S.; Klüppelberg, C. Optimal portfolios when stock prices follow an exponential Lévy process. Finance Stoch. 8 (24), no., [] Emmer, S.; Klüppelberg, C.; Korn, R. Optimal portfolios with bounded capital at risk. Math. Finance (2), no. 4, [] Frolova, A.; Kabanov, Y.; Pergamenshchikov, S. In the insurance business risky investments are dangerous. Finance Stoch. 6 (22), no. 2, [2] Goovaerts, M. J.; Kaas, R.; Laeven, R. J. A.; Tang, Q.; Vernic, R. The tail probability of discounted sums of Pareto-like losses in insurance. Scand. Actuar. J. (25), no. 6, [3] Heyde, C. C.; Wang, D. Finite-time ruin probability with an exponential Lévy process investment return and heavy-tailed claims. Adv. in Appl. Probab. 4 (29), no., [4] Kalashnikov, V.; Norberg, R. Power tailed ruin probabilities in the presence of risky investments. Stochastic Process. Appl. 98 (22), no. 2, [5] Klüppelberg, C.; Kostadinova, R. Integrated insurance risk models with exponential Lévy investment. Insurance Math. Econom. 42 (28), no. 2, [6] Kostadinova, R. Optimal investment for insurers when the stock price follows an exponential Lévy process. Insurance Math. Econom. 4 (27), no. 2, [7] Maulik, K.; Zwart, B. Tail asymptotics for exponential functionals of Lévy processes Stochastic Process. Appl. 6 (26), no. 2, [8] Paulsen, J. Risk theory in a stochastic economic environment. Stochastic Process. Appl. 46 (993), no. 2, [9] Paulsen, J. On Cramér-like asymptotics for risk processes with stochastic return on investments. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2 (22), no. 4, [2] Paulsen, J. Optimal dividend payouts for di usions with solvency constraints. Finance Stoch. 7 (23), no. 4, [2] Paulsen, J. Ruin models with investment income. Probab. Surv. 5 (28), [22] Paulsen, J.; Gjessing, H. K. Ruin theory with stochastic return on investments. Adv. in Appl. Probab. 29 (997), no. 4,

21 [23] Protter, P. E. Stochastic Integration and Di erential Equations. Second edition. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 25. [24] Resnick, S. I.; Willekens, E. Moving averages with random coe cients and random coe cient autoregressive models. Comm. Statist. Stochastic Models 7 (99), no. 4, [25] Sato, K. Lévy Processes and In nitely Divisible Distributions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 999. [26] Schmidli, H. On minimizing the ruin probability by investment and reinsurance. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2 (22), no. 3, [27] Tang, Q. Uniform estimates for the tail probability of maxima over nite horizons with subexponential tails. Probab. Engrg. Inform. Sci. 8 (24), no., [28] Tang, Q.; Tsitsiashvili, G. Precise estimates for the ruin probability in nite horizon in a discrete-time model with heavy-tailed insurance and nancial risks. Stochastic Process. Appl. 8 (23), no. 2, [29] Wang, D.; Tang, Q. Tail probabilities of randomly weighted sums of random variables with dominated variation. Stoch. Models 22 (26), no. 2, [3] Wang, G.; Wu, R. Distributions for the risk process with a stochastic return on investments. Stochastic Process. Appl. 95 (2), no. 2, [3] Willekens, E. On the supremum of an in nitely divisible process. Stochastic Process. Appl. 26 (987), no., [32] Yuen, K. C.; Wang, G.; Ng, K. W. Ruin probabilities for a risk process with stochastic return on investments. Stochastic Process. Appl. (24), no. 2, [33] Yuen, K. C.; Wang, G.; Wu, R. On the renewal risk process with stochastic interest. Stochastic Process. Appl. 6 (26), no., [34] Zhang, Y.; Shen, X.; Weng, C. Approximation of the tail probability of randomly weighted sums and applications. Stochastic Process. Appl. 9 (29), no. 2,

UNIFORM ASYMPTOTICS FOR DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN DEPENDENT RISK MODELS

UNIFORM ASYMPTOTICS FOR DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN DEPENDENT RISK MODELS Applied Probability Trust 2 October 2013 UNIFORM ASYMPTOTICS FOR DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN DEPENDENT RISK MODELS YANG YANG, Nanjing Audit University, and Southeast University KAIYONG WANG, Southeast

More information

Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks

Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks 1 Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks Yang Yang School of Mathematics and Statistics, Nanjing Audit University School of Economics

More information

Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment

Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment Appl. Math. J. Chinese Univ. 21, 25(2: 29-216 Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment JIANG Tao Abstract. Under the assumption that the claim size is subexponentially

More information

A Uniform Asymptotic Estimate for Discounted Aggregate Claims with Subexponential Tails

A Uniform Asymptotic Estimate for Discounted Aggregate Claims with Subexponential Tails 12th International Congress on Insurance: Mathematics and Economics July 16-18, 2008 A Uniform Asymptotic Estimate for Discounted Aggregate Claims with Subexponential Tails XUEMIAO HAO (Based on a joint

More information

Asymptotics for a discrete-time risk model with Gamma-like insurance risks. Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong

Asymptotics for a discrete-time risk model with Gamma-like insurance risks. Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong Asymptotics for a discrete-time risk model with Gamma-like insurance risks Yang Yang 1,2 and Kam C. Yuen 3 1 Department of Statistics, Nanjing Audit University, Nanjing, 211815, China 2 School of Economics

More information

FULL LIST OF REFEREED JOURNAL PUBLICATIONS Qihe Tang

FULL LIST OF REFEREED JOURNAL PUBLICATIONS Qihe Tang FULL LIST OF REFEREED JOURNAL PUBLICATIONS Qihe Tang 87. Li, J.; Tang, Q. Interplay of insurance and financial risks in a discrete-time model with strongly regular variation. Bernoulli 21 (2015), no. 3,

More information

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS NICOLE BÄUERLE AND STEFANIE GRETHER Abstract. In this short note we prove a conjecture posed in Cui et al. 2012): Dynamic mean-variance problems in

More information

EXTREMES ON THE DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN A TIME DEPENDENT RISK MODEL

EXTREMES ON THE DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN A TIME DEPENDENT RISK MODEL EXTREMES ON THE DISCOUNTED AGGREGATE CLAIMS IN A TIME DEPENDENT RISK MODEL Alexandru V. Asimit 1 Andrei L. Badescu 2 Department of Statistics University of Toronto 100 St. George St. Toronto, Ontario,

More information

Bias in the Estimation of Mean Reversion in Continuous-Time Lévy Processes

Bias in the Estimation of Mean Reversion in Continuous-Time Lévy Processes Bias in the Estimation of Mean Reversion in Continuous-Time Lévy Processes Yong Bao a, Aman Ullah b, Yun Wang c, and Jun Yu d a Purdue University, IN, USA b University of California, Riverside, CA, USA

More information

POISSON PROCESS AND INSURANCE : AN INTRODUCTION 1

POISSON PROCESS AND INSURANCE : AN INTRODUCTION 1 POISSON PROCESS AND INSURANCE : AN INTRODUCTION S.RAMASUBRAMANIAN Statistics and Mathematics Unit Indian Statistical Institute 8th Mile, Mysore Road Bangalore - 560059. Abstract: Basic aspects of the classical

More information

Corrected Diffusion Approximations for the Maximum of Heavy-Tailed Random Walk

Corrected Diffusion Approximations for the Maximum of Heavy-Tailed Random Walk Corrected Diffusion Approximations for the Maximum of Heavy-Tailed Random Walk Jose Blanchet and Peter Glynn December, 2003. Let (X n : n 1) be a sequence of independent and identically distributed random

More information

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses Michael R. Powers[ ] Temple University and Tsinghua University Thomas Y. Powers Yale University [June 2009] Abstract We propose a

More information

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com In this Note we derive the Black Scholes PDE for an option V, given by @t + 1 + rs @S2 @S We derive the

More information

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Date: January 8, 2013. Duration: 3 hours. This is a closed-book exam. The exam does not use scrap cards. Simple calculators are allowed. The questions

More information

The Black-Scholes Formula

The Black-Scholes Formula FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Black-Scholes Formula These notes examine the Black-Scholes formula for European options. The Black-Scholes formula are complex as they are based on the

More information

Optimisation Problems in Non-Life Insurance

Optimisation Problems in Non-Life Insurance Frankfurt, 6. Juli 2007 1 The de Finetti Problem The Optimal Strategy De Finetti s Example 2 Minimal Ruin Probabilities The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation Two Examples 3 Optimal Dividends Dividends in

More information

14.451 Lecture Notes 10

14.451 Lecture Notes 10 14.451 Lecture Notes 1 Guido Lorenzoni Fall 29 1 Continuous time: nite horizon Time goes from to T. Instantaneous payo : f (t; x (t) ; y (t)) ; (the time dependence includes discounting), where x (t) 2

More information

Biinterpretability up to double jump in the degrees

Biinterpretability up to double jump in the degrees Biinterpretability up to double jump in the degrees below 0 0 Richard A. Shore Department of Mathematics Cornell University Ithaca NY 14853 July 29, 2013 Abstract We prove that, for every z 0 0 with z

More information

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Sun and Chen Journal of Uncertainty Analysis and Applications (215) 3:11 DOI 1.1186/s4467-15-35-7 RESEARCH Open Access Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Jiajun Sun 1 and Xiaowei

More information

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS 1. Introduction All of the options that we have considered thus far have been of the European variety: exercise is permitted only at the termination of the contract. These

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2015 B. Goldys and M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market

More information

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance Author: Yiyang Yang Advisor: Pr. Xiaolin Li, Pr. Zari Rachev Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics State University of New York at Stony Brook October 2, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction

More information

Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO

Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO R. L. Johnson and C. J. Neugebauer The main result says that a non-negative BMO-function w, whose reciprocal is also in BMO, belongs to p> A p,and

More information

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models A Comparison of Option Pricing Models Ekrem Kilic 11.01.2005 Abstract Modeling a nonlinear pay o generating instrument is a challenging work. The models that are commonly used for pricing derivative might

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

1. (First passage/hitting times/gambler s ruin problem:) Suppose that X has a discrete state space and let i be a fixed state. Let

1. (First passage/hitting times/gambler s ruin problem:) Suppose that X has a discrete state space and let i be a fixed state. Let Copyright c 2009 by Karl Sigman 1 Stopping Times 1.1 Stopping Times: Definition Given a stochastic process X = {X n : n 0}, a random time τ is a discrete random variable on the same probability space as

More information

WHEN DOES A RANDOMLY WEIGHTED SELF NORMALIZED SUM CONVERGE IN DISTRIBUTION?

WHEN DOES A RANDOMLY WEIGHTED SELF NORMALIZED SUM CONVERGE IN DISTRIBUTION? WHEN DOES A RANDOMLY WEIGHTED SELF NORMALIZED SUM CONVERGE IN DISTRIBUTION? DAVID M MASON 1 Statistics Program, University of Delaware Newark, DE 19717 email: davidm@udeledu JOEL ZINN 2 Department of Mathematics,

More information

Elements of probability theory

Elements of probability theory 2 Elements of probability theory Probability theory provides mathematical models for random phenomena, that is, phenomena which under repeated observations yield di erent outcomes that cannot be predicted

More information

Mathematical Finance

Mathematical Finance Mathematical Finance Option Pricing under the Risk-Neutral Measure Cory Barnes Department of Mathematics University of Washington June 11, 2013 Outline 1 Probability Background 2 Black Scholes for European

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES Contents 1. Random variables and measurable functions 2. Cumulative distribution functions 3. Discrete

More information

NUMERICAL FINITE HORIZON RUIN PROBABILITIES IN THE CLASSICAL RISK MODEL WITH STOCHASTIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS

NUMERICAL FINITE HORIZON RUIN PROBABILITIES IN THE CLASSICAL RISK MODEL WITH STOCHASTIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS NUMERICAL FINITE HORIZON RUIN PROBABILITIES IN THE CLASSICAL RISK MODEL WITH STOCHASTIC RETURN ON INVESTMENTS Lubasi Simataa M.Sc. (Mathematical Modelling) Dissertation University Of Dar es Salaam June,

More information

Representation of functions as power series

Representation of functions as power series Representation of functions as power series Dr. Philippe B. Laval Kennesaw State University November 9, 008 Abstract This document is a summary of the theory and techniques used to represent functions

More information

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula 2.1 Binomial Trees We consider a financial market consisting of a bond B t = B(t), a stock S t = S(t), and a call-option C t = C(t), where the

More information

Hedging of Life Insurance Liabilities

Hedging of Life Insurance Liabilities Hedging of Life Insurance Liabilities Thorsten Rheinländer, with Francesca Biagini and Irene Schreiber Vienna University of Technology and LMU Munich September 6, 2015 horsten Rheinländer, with Francesca

More information

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011

arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 How Not to Win a Million Dollars: A Counterexample to a Conjecture of L. Breiman Thomas P. Hayes arxiv:1112.0829v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011 Abstract Consider a gambling game in which we are allowed to repeatedly

More information

36 CHAPTER 1. LIMITS AND CONTINUITY. Figure 1.17: At which points is f not continuous?

36 CHAPTER 1. LIMITS AND CONTINUITY. Figure 1.17: At which points is f not continuous? 36 CHAPTER 1. LIMITS AND CONTINUITY 1.3 Continuity Before Calculus became clearly de ned, continuity meant that one could draw the graph of a function without having to lift the pen and pencil. While this

More information

2.3 Convex Constrained Optimization Problems

2.3 Convex Constrained Optimization Problems 42 CHAPTER 2. FUNDAMENTAL CONCEPTS IN CONVEX OPTIMIZATION Theorem 15 Let f : R n R and h : R R. Consider g(x) = h(f(x)) for all x R n. The function g is convex if either of the following two conditions

More information

Heavy-tailed insurance portfolios: buffer capital and ruin probabilities

Heavy-tailed insurance portfolios: buffer capital and ruin probabilities Heavy-tailed insurance portfolios: buffer capital and ruin probabilities Henrik Hult 1, Filip Lindskog 2 1 School of ORIE, Cornell University, 414A Rhodes Hall, Ithaca, NY 14853, USA 2 Department of Mathematics,

More information

Large Insurance Losses Distributions

Large Insurance Losses Distributions Vicky Fasen and Claudia Klüppelberg Abstract Large insurance losses happen infrequently, but they happen. In this paper we present the standard distribution models used in fire, wind storm or flood insurance.

More information

LECTURE NOTES IN MEASURE THEORY. Christer Borell Matematik Chalmers och Göteborgs universitet 412 96 Göteborg (Version: January 12)

LECTURE NOTES IN MEASURE THEORY. Christer Borell Matematik Chalmers och Göteborgs universitet 412 96 Göteborg (Version: January 12) 1 LECTURE NOTES IN MEASURE THEORY Christer Borell Matematik Chalmers och Göteborgs universitet 412 96 Göteborg (Version: January 12) 2 PREFACE These are lecture notes on integration theory for a eight-week

More information

FIRST YEAR CALCULUS. Chapter 7 CONTINUITY. It is a parabola, and we can draw this parabola without lifting our pencil from the paper.

FIRST YEAR CALCULUS. Chapter 7 CONTINUITY. It is a parabola, and we can draw this parabola without lifting our pencil from the paper. FIRST YEAR CALCULUS WWLCHENW L c WWWL W L Chen, 1982, 2008. 2006. This chapter originates from material used by the author at Imperial College, University of London, between 1981 and 1990. It It is is

More information

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Jirô Akahori, Yuji Hishida and Maho Nishida Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, Ritsumeikan University 1-1-1 Nojihigashi, Kusatsu, Shiga 525-8577, Japan E-mail: {akahori,

More information

7: The CRR Market Model

7: The CRR Market Model Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney MATH3075/3975 Financial Mathematics Semester 2, 2015 Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein

More information

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model D. Düvelmeyer Technische Universität Chemnitz, Fakultät für Mathematik, 09107 Chemnitz, Germany Abstract In this paper we discuss

More information

A Model of Optimum Tariff in Vehicle Fleet Insurance

A Model of Optimum Tariff in Vehicle Fleet Insurance A Model of Optimum Tariff in Vehicle Fleet Insurance. Bouhetala and F.Belhia and R.Salmi Statistics and Probability Department Bp, 3, El-Alia, USTHB, Bab-Ezzouar, Alger Algeria. Summary: An approach about

More information

The Exponential Distribution

The Exponential Distribution 21 The Exponential Distribution From Discrete-Time to Continuous-Time: In Chapter 6 of the text we will be considering Markov processes in continuous time. In a sense, we already have a very good understanding

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

Lectures 5-6: Taylor Series

Lectures 5-6: Taylor Series Math 1d Instructor: Padraic Bartlett Lectures 5-: Taylor Series Weeks 5- Caltech 213 1 Taylor Polynomials and Series As we saw in week 4, power series are remarkably nice objects to work with. In particular,

More information

How To Price A Call Option

How To Price A Call Option Now by Itô s formula But Mu f and u g in Ū. Hence τ θ u(x) =E( Mu(X) ds + u(x(τ θ))) 0 τ θ u(x) E( f(x) ds + g(x(τ θ))) = J x (θ). 0 But since u(x) =J x (θ ), we consequently have u(x) =J x (θ ) = min

More information

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion P. Coolen-Schrijner, F.P.A. Coolen Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Durham, Durham, DH1 3LE, UK e-mail: Pauline.Schrijner@durham.ac.uk

More information

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes Dmitry Kramkov, Carnegie Mellon University Based on a paper with Mihai Sirbu from Columbia University Math Finance Seminar,

More information

Stationary random graphs on Z with prescribed iid degrees and finite mean connections

Stationary random graphs on Z with prescribed iid degrees and finite mean connections Stationary random graphs on Z with prescribed iid degrees and finite mean connections Maria Deijfen Johan Jonasson February 2006 Abstract Let F be a probability distribution with support on the non-negative

More information

Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves

Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves Abstract: This paper presents a model for an insurance company that controls its risk and dividend

More information

arxiv:1502.06681v2 [q-fin.mf] 26 Feb 2015

arxiv:1502.06681v2 [q-fin.mf] 26 Feb 2015 ARBITRAGE, HEDGING AND UTILITY MAXIMIZATION USING SEMI-STATIC TRADING STRATEGIES WITH AMERICAN OPTIONS ERHAN BAYRAKTAR AND ZHOU ZHOU arxiv:1502.06681v2 [q-fin.mf] 26 Feb 2015 Abstract. We consider a financial

More information

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Phoebus J. Dhrymes 1 July 2012 1 c Phoebus J. Dhrymes, 2012. Preliminary material; not to be cited or disseminated without the author s permission. 2 Contents

More information

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS Denis Bell University of North Florida Modelling Stock Prices Example American Express In mathematical finance, it is customary to model a stock price by an (Ito) stochatic

More information

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t. LECTURE 7: BLACK SCHOLES THEORY 1. Introduction: The Black Scholes Model In 1973 Fisher Black and Myron Scholes ushered in the modern era of derivative securities with a seminal paper 1 on the pricing

More information

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures IEOR E4706: Financial Engineering: Discrete-Time Asset Pricing Fall 2005 c 2005 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures We now apply martingale pricing theory to the

More information

Risk-Free Assets. Case 2. 2.1 Time Value of Money

Risk-Free Assets. Case 2. 2.1 Time Value of Money 2 Risk-Free Assets Case 2 Consider a do-it-yourself pension fund based on regular savings invested in a bank account attracting interest at 5% per annum. When you retire after 40 years, you want to receive

More information

Conditional Tail Expectations for Multivariate Phase Type Distributions

Conditional Tail Expectations for Multivariate Phase Type Distributions Conditional Tail Expectations for Multivariate Phase Type Distributions Jun Cai Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo Waterloo, ON N2L 3G1, Canada jcai@math.uwaterloo.ca

More information

Lectures on Stochastic Processes. William G. Faris

Lectures on Stochastic Processes. William G. Faris Lectures on Stochastic Processes William G. Faris November 8, 2001 2 Contents 1 Random walk 7 1.1 Symmetric simple random walk................... 7 1.2 Simple random walk......................... 9 1.3

More information

No: 10 04. Bilkent University. Monotonic Extension. Farhad Husseinov. Discussion Papers. Department of Economics

No: 10 04. Bilkent University. Monotonic Extension. Farhad Husseinov. Discussion Papers. Department of Economics No: 10 04 Bilkent University Monotonic Extension Farhad Husseinov Discussion Papers Department of Economics The Discussion Papers of the Department of Economics are intended to make the initial results

More information

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options he Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options Paul J Atzberger Comments should be sent to: atzberg@mathucsbedu Introduction In this article we shall discuss the Black-Scholes-Merton approach to determining

More information

A Martingale System Theorem for Stock Investments

A Martingale System Theorem for Stock Investments A Martingale System Theorem for Stock Investments Robert J. Vanderbei April 26, 1999 DIMACS New Market Models Workshop 1 Beginning Middle End Controversial Remarks Outline DIMACS New Market Models Workshop

More information

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model 1 第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model Outline 有 关 股 价 的 假 设 The B-S Model 隐 性 波 动 性 Implied Volatility 红 利 与 期 权 定 价 Dividends and Option Pricing 美 式 期 权 定 价 American

More information

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1 Chapter 3 Continuity In this chapter we begin by defining the fundamental notion of continuity for real valued functions of a single real variable. When trying to decide whether a given function is or

More information

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Ralf Korn 1 and L. C. G. Rogers 2 Abstract In the Black-Scholes model, any dividends on stocks are paid continuously, but in reality dividends

More information

ON SOME ANALOGUE OF THE GENERALIZED ALLOCATION SCHEME

ON SOME ANALOGUE OF THE GENERALIZED ALLOCATION SCHEME ON SOME ANALOGUE OF THE GENERALIZED ALLOCATION SCHEME Alexey Chuprunov Kazan State University, Russia István Fazekas University of Debrecen, Hungary 2012 Kolchin s generalized allocation scheme A law of

More information

OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS

OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS ONDERZOEKSRAPPORT NR 8904 OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS BY M. VANDEBROEK & J. DHAENE D/1989/2376/5 1 IN A OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS By Martina Vandebroek

More information

Chapter 7 Nonlinear Systems

Chapter 7 Nonlinear Systems Chapter 7 Nonlinear Systems Nonlinear systems in R n : X = B x. x n X = F (t; X) F (t; x ; :::; x n ) B C A ; F (t; X) =. F n (t; x ; :::; x n ) When F (t; X) = F (X) is independent of t; it is an example

More information

LogNormal stock-price models in Exams MFE/3 and C/4

LogNormal stock-price models in Exams MFE/3 and C/4 Making sense of... LogNormal stock-price models in Exams MFE/3 and C/4 James W. Daniel Austin Actuarial Seminars http://www.actuarialseminars.com June 26, 2008 c Copyright 2007 by James W. Daniel; reproduction

More information

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity G. P. Kiesmüller, A.G. de Kok, S. Dabia Faculty of Technology Management, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, P.O. Box 513,

More information

where N is the standard normal distribution function,

where N is the standard normal distribution function, The Black-Scholes-Merton formula (Hull 13.5 13.8) Assume S t is a geometric Brownian motion w/drift. Want market value at t = 0 of call option. European call option with expiration at time T. Payout at

More information

Wald s Identity. by Jeffery Hein. Dartmouth College, Math 100

Wald s Identity. by Jeffery Hein. Dartmouth College, Math 100 Wald s Identity by Jeffery Hein Dartmouth College, Math 100 1. Introduction Given random variables X 1, X 2, X 3,... with common finite mean and a stopping rule τ which may depend upon the given sequence,

More information

9.2 Summation Notation

9.2 Summation Notation 9. Summation Notation 66 9. Summation Notation In the previous section, we introduced sequences and now we shall present notation and theorems concerning the sum of terms of a sequence. We begin with a

More information

STOCK LOANS. XUN YU ZHOU Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management, The Chinese University of Hong Kong 1.

STOCK LOANS. XUN YU ZHOU Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management, The Chinese University of Hong Kong 1. Mathematical Finance, Vol. 17, No. 2 April 2007), 307 317 STOCK LOANS JIANMING XIA Center for Financial Engineering and Risk Management, Academy of Mathematics and Systems Science, Chinese Academy of Sciences

More information

ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION. E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska

ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION. E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska Pliska Stud. Math. Bulgar. 22 (2015), STUDIA MATHEMATICA BULGARICA ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska Smirnov (1949) derived four

More information

3. ARTÍCULOS DE APLICACIÓN

3. ARTÍCULOS DE APLICACIÓN 3. ARTÍCULOS DE APLICACIÓN SOME PROBABILITY APPLICATIONS TO THE RISK ANALYSIS IN INSURANCE THEORY Jinzhi Li College of Science Central University for Nationalities, China Shixia Ma School of Sciences Hebei

More information

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 28: 25 32, 2003 c 2003 The Geneva Association On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance CHU-SHIU LI Department of Economics, Feng Chia

More information

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas The Black-Scholes pricing formulas Moty Katzman September 19, 2014 The Black-Scholes differential equation Aim: Find a formula for the price of European options on stock. Lemma 6.1: Assume that a stock

More information

Duality of linear conic problems

Duality of linear conic problems Duality of linear conic problems Alexander Shapiro and Arkadi Nemirovski Abstract It is well known that the optimal values of a linear programming problem and its dual are equal to each other if at least

More information

From Binomial Trees to the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formulas

From Binomial Trees to the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formulas Lecture 4 From Binomial Trees to the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formulas In this lecture, we will extend the example in Lecture 2 to a general setting of binomial trees, as an important model for a single

More information

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory Journal of Uncertain Systems Vol.3, No.1, pp.3-10, 2009 Online at: www.jus.org.uk Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory aoding Liu Uncertainty Theory Laboratory, Department of Mathematical Sciences

More information

Master s Theory Exam Spring 2006

Master s Theory Exam Spring 2006 Spring 2006 This exam contains 7 questions. You should attempt them all. Each question is divided into parts to help lead you through the material. You should attempt to complete as much of each problem

More information

Probability Generating Functions

Probability Generating Functions page 39 Chapter 3 Probability Generating Functions 3 Preamble: Generating Functions Generating functions are widely used in mathematics, and play an important role in probability theory Consider a sequence

More information

Stochastic Inventory Control

Stochastic Inventory Control Chapter 3 Stochastic Inventory Control 1 In this chapter, we consider in much greater details certain dynamic inventory control problems of the type already encountered in section 1.3. In addition to the

More information

An example for a closed-form solution for a system of linear partial di erential equations

An example for a closed-form solution for a system of linear partial di erential equations An example for a closed-form solution for a system of linear partial di erential equations Tobias Nagel (a) and Klaus Wälde (a,b), (a) University of Mainz (a,b) CESifo, Université Catholique de Louvain,

More information

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology March 24, 2005 1 Introduction The purchase of an options contract gives the buyer the right to buy call options contract or sell put options contract some

More information

LOGNORMAL MODEL FOR STOCK PRICES

LOGNORMAL MODEL FOR STOCK PRICES LOGNORMAL MODEL FOR STOCK PRICES MICHAEL J. SHARPE MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD 1. INTRODUCTION What follows is a simple but important model that will be the basis for a later study of stock prices as

More information

MATH 425, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS.

MATH 425, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS. MATH 45, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS. Exercise. a Is the operator L defined on smooth functions of x, y by L u := u xx + cosu linear? b Does the answer change if we replace the operator L by the operator

More information

Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab

Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab Monte Carlo Simulation: IEOR E4703 Fall 2004 c 2004 by Martin Haugh Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab 1 Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation 1.1 Why use simulation?

More information

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics Chapter 7 Metric Spaces A metric space is a set X that has a notion of the distance d(x, y) between every pair of points x, y X. The purpose of this chapter is to introduce metric spaces and give some

More information

Four Derivations of the Black-Scholes Formula by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com

Four Derivations of the Black-Scholes Formula by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com Four Derivations of the Black-Scholes Formula by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volota.com In this note we derive in four searate ways the well-known result of Black and Scholes that under certain

More information

THE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM TORONTO

THE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM TORONTO THE CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM DANIEL RÜDT UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO MARCH, 2010 Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Mathematical Background 3 3 The Central Limit Theorem 4 4 Examples 4 4.1 Roulette......................................

More information

Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial

Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial Alexei Deviatov and Neil Wallace y October 10th, 2000 Abstract A probabilistic version of lump-sum money creation is studied in a random matching

More information

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena Department of Computer Science State University of New York Stony Brook, NY 11794 4400 http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

More information

Notes on metric spaces

Notes on metric spaces Notes on metric spaces 1 Introduction The purpose of these notes is to quickly review some of the basic concepts from Real Analysis, Metric Spaces and some related results that will be used in this course.

More information

Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling

Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling EE384Y Project Final Report Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling Xiangheng Liu Department of Electrical Engineering Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305 Email: liuxh@systems.stanford.edu Abstract Load

More information

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Name: While every attempt was made to be complete in the types of problems given below, we make no guarantees about the completeness of the problems. Specifically,

More information

Do option prices support the subjective probabilities of takeover completion derived from spot prices? Sergey Gelman March 2005

Do option prices support the subjective probabilities of takeover completion derived from spot prices? Sergey Gelman March 2005 Do option prices support the subjective probabilities of takeover completion derived from spot prices? Sergey Gelman March 2005 University of Muenster Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultaet Am Stadtgraben

More information