Charity Hazard in Crop Insurance

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Charity Hazard in Crop Insurance"

Transcription

1 Charity Hazard in Crop Insurance Tatyana Deryugina and Barrett Kirwan PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. COMMENTS ARE WELCOME. April 14, 2014 Abstract The government acting as an insurer of last resort can cause moral hazard if agents respond by taking on more risk or reducing private insurance coverage, thinking they will be bailed out. This phenomenon dubbed charity hazard can increase the cost and impact of disasters. It is thought to be an important explanation for the relatively low rates of insurance take-up in some markets, but empirical studies are lacking. We estimate the extent of charity hazard in agriculture, where both private crop insurance and frequent federal disaster assistance are present. We use political variation within a county to instrument for disaster aid and identify the causal relationship between disaster assistance and insurance coverage. We show that bailout expectations are qualitatively and quantitatively important for the insurance decision. We also find evidence of moral hazard with respect to yields: higher expectations of disaster payments lead to significantly lower yields. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. We are grateful to seminar participants at the American Economic Association Meetings, the Midwestern Economics Association Meetings, the Institute of Government and Public Affairs, and the University of Illinois. 1

2 1 Introduction The state often acts as the insurer of last resort during systemic shocks, such as natural disasters and economic crises. Although there may be benefits to doing so, the state potentially crowds out private insurance purchases and other preventative behavior by providing free assistance to those impacted by such shocks. This phenomenon dubbed charity hazard to reflect the moral hazard induced by the expectation of charity can increase the cost and impact of disasters. It is thought to be an important explanation for the relatively low rates of insurance take-up in some markets. Although there are numerous theoretical models of charity hazard, there are very few empirical studies and no consensus on how much charity hazard occurs in practice. 1 Effective policy design, however, requires an understanding of the size and extent of government-induced charity hazard. We estimate the extent of charity hazard in U.S. agricultural production, where crop insurance is widely available, yet there have been numerous ad hoc disaster payment bills passed allocating funds to uninsured producers. Insurance availability alongside ad hoc bailouts is typical of settings where charity hazard is a potential concern, including homeowners who face the risk of natural disasters, farmers who face the risk of crop loss, and banks who face the risk of defaults. The identification of charity hazard in these settings, however, is problematic due to the endogeneity of disaster payments. For example, if lawmakers desire to assist the uninsured, areas with lower insurance take up will receive more federal assistance, leading to a negative correlation between insurance take up and disaster payments. However, in this example, it is the low insurance take up that causes high federal assistance, not the other way around. Additionally, individuals in disaster-prone areas may purchase more insurance than those in less-risky areas, and, on average, receive more disaster payments. But this positive correlation masks the underlying charity hazard if individuals don t purchase as much insurance as they otherwise would if there were no possibility of ad hoc disaster payments. 1 For theoretical research on charity hazard see, for example, Lewis and Nickerson (1989); Kelly and Kleffner (2003); Kim and Schlesinger (2005); Raschky and Weckhannemann (2007). 2

3 We unravel the joint determination of insurance and disaster assistance by exploiting withincounty variation in political factors that affect the likelihood of disaster assistance without affecting the risk faced by the decision maker. Since politically-motivated disaster payments are orthogonal to the producers risk environment and farmers do not represent a significant fraction of the electorate in most counties, we can be confident that the behavioral response identified with this variation is due to the expectation of disaster payments and not other confounding effects. We find that the elasticity of insurance take up with respect to disaster payments is about 0.2. That is, a one-percent increase in disaster payments reduces the number of insurance policies by 0.2 percent. We confirm these estimates by using alternative measures of coverage, such as total liability and gross insurance premiums (including premium subsidies). The elasticity of farmers own expenditure on insurance, which does not include subsidies paid by the government, is between 0.3 and 0.5. We also find evidence of moral hazard with respect to yields: higher expectations of disaster payments lead to significantly lower yields. The yield elasticity with respect to disaster payments is also about 0.2. This suggests that charity hazard occurs both through reduced insurance purchases and greater risk-taking through reduced effort and/or input use. On a per-policy basis, we find that farmer premiums and liability are both lower when expectations of disaster payment are higher. This is consistent with farmers choosing less generous insurance plans. However, we cannot tell whether this result is driven by who drops insurance coverage or changes in which plans insured farmers choose. Finally, we estimate the insurance value of both disaster payments and market insurance payments. We find that the former do not provide substantial risk protection at the county level: the representative farmer in the average county is not willing to pay more than the expected value for disaster payments. The same is not true for market insurance. Because there are likely to be few idiosyncratic shocks to yields within a county, this suggests that disaster payments are not valuable as an insurance product. This is not inconsistent with our charity hazard estimates, which speak to the marginal dollar of disaster payments, rather than the average. However, it suggests that the 3

4 value of continuing to provide disaster payments in their current form is low. This paper extends the literature on the crowd-out effect of publicly provided insurance. Much of the literature is concerned with crowding out of private health insurance by public health insurance. While many of the papers find significant crowd-out, some do not. 2 With respect to other crowd-out channels, Gross and Notowidigdo (2011) find that, following Medicaid expansions, consumer bankruptcy decreases, suggesting that bankruptcy acts as a form of insurance against high medical costs. Mahoney (2012) further shows that the existence of bankruptcy protection distorts the insurance decision. In the long-term care insurance market, Brown and Finkelstein (2008) find that government-funded Medicaid has the potential to significantly crowd out private coverage, even though the former is much less generous. Finally, Kousky et al. (2013) find that the expectation of disaster payments reduces the purchase of flood insurance. To our knowledge, we are the first to estimate crowd-out in the agricultural sector. There is scant evidence on the existence and size of charity hazard when it comes to disaster relief, likely due to the difficulty of credible identification. Browne and Hoyt (2000) find no evidence of charity hazard in flood insurance purchase, although the analysis is based on correlations. Kunreuther et al. (1978) find that homeowners in risky areas generally do not expect federal financial disaster relief. In a hypothetical choice experiment, however, Van Asseldonk et al. (2002) find that expectations of government relief are significant predictors of the decision to insure. Raschky and Schwindt (2009) find some evidence that foreign aid crowds out preventative measures for storms. With the exception of Kousky et al. (2013), the existing studies either use survey data or correlational analysis. Moreover, all the existing literature focuses on individuals or governments, rather than businesses or farmers. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we provide background on crop insurance and disaster payments in the US and briefly explain the idea of charity hazard. In Section 3, we describe our data and empirical strategy. Section 4 presents the results. We provide backof-the-envelope calculations of the insurance value of disaster payments and formal insurance in 2 For a brief review of the existing evidence, see Gruber and Simon (2008). 4

5 Section 5 and conclude in Section 6. 2 Disaster Payments, Crop Insurance, and Charity Hazard Federal crop insurance and agricultural disaster payments have provided overlapping risk protection to farmers for over 40 years. The Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 established the Federal Crop Insurance Corporation to administer what was essentially, until 1980, an experimental crop insurance program. 3 While crop insurance was in an experimental phase, Congress established a standing Crop Disaster Payment (CDP) program in 1973 that was akin to free insurance coverage for a select group of crops. Low-yield payments were made to farmers who participated in income- and price-support programs when yields fell below two-thirds of normal. The Government Accountability Office (GAO) (1980) recognized the conflict between these programs and the potential for charity hazard when it reported that, where crop insurance was offered, [disaster] payments actually compete with crop insurance because they require no premiums. In 1980, Congress responded by ending the standing CDP program and expanding the Federal Crop Insurance (FCI) program. 4 In spite of the large expansion of federal crop insurance, Congress quickly established a pattern of having two parallel mechanisms for dealing with crop-loss risk by providing $1.4 billion in drought relief in 1981 and $6.9 billion in disaster payments along with $4.3 billion in crop insurance indemnities from (U.S. General Accounting Office, 1989). At the same time FCI participation stagnated at X million acres, less than 25% of insurable acres. In 1989 the GAO reported that, federal disaster assistance programs provide farmers with direct cash payments at no cost to the farmers, resulting in the perception [among farmers] that crop insurance is unnecessary. Despite GAO warnings, Congress continued to frequently authorize ad hoc CDP programs. Between Congress allocated $XX billion (2011 dollars) to CDP programs. 5 Figure 1 3 For a more detailed history of the early crop insurance program see Glauber and Collins (2002). 4 In 1981, the FCIC added 1,340 county programs (a county program is a particular crop-county combination), and in 1982, 8,278 county programs were added. 5 See the appendix for a list of public laws passed between 1989 and 2009 that authorize some disaster payments. 5

6 shows the pattern of indemnity payments, made by insurance companies, and crop disaster payments, made by the government, over the same time period. To control for the growth of insurance coverage, we show these quantities as percent of total liability. On average, disaster and indemnity payments are similar. There are several years in which disaster payments exceed indemnity payments, although in recent years disaster payments have been relatively low. There are no years in which no disaster payments are made, although in some years, the amount is nearly 0. Consistent with their ad hoc nature, disaster payments are much more volatile than indemnity payments. Not only were ad hoc disaster payments awarded frequently, but Congress consistently awarded payments to regions of the country that typically received high indemnity payments. The geographic distribution of crop disaster payments creates the potential for charity hazard. Figure 2 illustrates the geographic distribution of total indemnity payments from Indemnities appear to be concentrated in the Plains, along the Lower Mississippi, and the Southeast. Figure 3 shows that total crop disaster payments over the same time period have a very similar geographic distribution. In fact, the spatial correlation coefficient between these two payments is 0.X, which is consistent with the GAO s assessment that CDP programs and the Federal Crop Insurance program compete against each other. Of course, these patterns could also be driven by the spatial distribution of risk or crops. In addition to the frequent, geographically consistent disaster payments, the similarities between crop insurance and CDP programs may have made it easier for farmers to view ad hoc CDP programs as a supplement to, or even a substitute for, crop insurance. Equation (1) illustrates the basic structure of an indemnity or disaster payment. P ayment = } P {{ Ȳ } Protection max[0, Ȳ Y ] Ȳ } {{ } Trigger, (1) where P is the price guarantee, Ȳ is the covered yield, and Y is the actual yield. As equation (1) shows, the protection level for both crop insurance and disaster assistance equals the price guarantee multiplied by the covered yield. A triggering mechanism equal to the shortfall relative to 6

7 coverage determines the magnitude of payments from both sources. 6 The indemnity payment trigger can be determined by (a) individual yield, (b) individual revenue, (c) mean county yield or (d) mean county revenue. Farmers cannot take out multiple insurance plans for the same plot. Within these plan types, farmers can choose from several coverage levels ranging from 50% to 90%. 7 The coverage level implicitly defines the amount by which yield or revenue has to fall (relative to a baseline) before any payment is made. If a farmer chooses a 65% coverage level, for example, he does not receive payments until his yield, revenue, the county yield, or the county revenue (depending on the type of plan chosen) falls to more than 35% below the established baseline. The plan type and coverage level largely describe the insurance plans available to farmers. 8 In contrast, Congress legislates the trigger for free-to-the-farmer disaster payments. Yield shortfall forms the basis for the disaster-payment trigger. Historically, Congress has set the yield guarantee to 65% of a farm s historical-average yield. To encourage future uptake of crop insurance, the legislation provides a higher price guarantee for farms with crop insurance vis-à-vis farms who could have purchased crop insurance but did not. 9 Besides payment formula similarities, CDP programs are administered in such a way that disaster payments are a de facto supplement to indemnity payments. In an effort to be equitable and not discourage crop insurance purchase, disaster payments are structured to ignore crop insurance payments in determining eligibility for assistance (Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 2006, 2005). Since crop insurance coverage does not affect CDP eligibility, after crop losses exceed the CDP trigger, an insured farmers income increases as crop losses grow. In other words, disaster payments top up indemnities. Figure 4 illustrates the change in farm revenue as crop losses grow for a farm with 65% crop insurance coverage that is eligible for disaster pay- 6 For a more comprehensive overview of the US crop insurance market, see Babcock (2012). 7 Not all coverage levels are available for all plan types and in all counties. 8 Farmers also have some choices within a plan-coverage-level combination, such as how to combine different plots and how much to get paid in the case of a shortfall. 9 During the period of our analysis, , only the U.S. Troop Readiness, Veterans Care, Katrina Recovery, and Iraq Accountability Appropriations Act of 2007 (2007) excluded farmers who could have purchased crop insurance but did not from receiving disaster payments. 7

8 ments. Under this scenario, a farm receives more revenue from a total crop loss than from a 10% crop loss, which might encourage moral hazard. 10 Because disaster payments are paid in addition to crop insurance, this might reduce the amount of charity hazard in this market. Although Congress has regularly responded to agricultural disasters with CDP programs, it has not been without reluctance. Over the period of our analysis, Congress attempted to move away from CDP programs by strengthening the Federal Crop Insurance program and weakening its own ability to pass disaster-assistance legislation by tightening budgetary constraints. From disaster payments came from emergency supplemental appropriations that were exempt from discretionary spending caps. The Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 made future agricultural crop disaster payments subject to discretionary spending caps by restricting them from being classified as emergency payments. The 1994 Act also greatly expanded the crop insurance program by mandating catastrophic-level (CAT), i.e., 50%, coverage for farms receiving subsidies. Together, these requirements sent a signal that future disaster payments were unlikely (see Jose and Valluru, 1997). Congress, however, rescinded the catastrophic-coverage mandate after just one year, and implemented a multi-year CDP program in 1998 (Agriculture, Rural Development, Food and Drug Administration, and Related Agencies Appropriations Act, 1999, 1998) something it said it would not do four years earlier. Since Congress ended the standing CDP in 1980, it has subsidized crop insurance premiums to encourage farmers to purchase more coverage and thereby reduce the need for ad hoc disaster payments. Despite premium subsidies of 30% for 55 65% coverage and 17% for 75% coverage, voluntary participation in the FCI program remained low through the 1980s and early 90s. The 1994 FCIR Act attempted to increases participation by increasing the subsidy rate on crop insurance premiums. Figure 5 illustrates the evolution of the crop-insurance premium subsidy rates from The subsidy rate varies by coverage level; for clarity, we have grouped premiums into four coverage groups: 50%; 55, 60, and 65%; 70 and 75%; and 80, 85, and 90% coverage. 10 Typically, a CDP program stipulates the sum of the value of the crop not lost, if any; the disaster payment received under this part; and any crop insurance payment... for losses to the same crop, cannot exceed 95 percent of what the crop s value would have been if there had been no loss ( Crop Disaster Program, 2008) 8

9 The figure shows the dramatic rise in the subsidy for 50% coverage due to the 1994 legislation and a modest increase for the other groups of about 10 percentage points each. Farmers response to the increased premium subsidies in 1994 was slight. Figure 6 illustrates the share of total acres insured by FCI by coverage group from Nearly all of the increase in participation in 1995 came from the mandated CAT (50%) coverage. Once the mandate was removed, participation levels fell until premium subsidies increased even more. The Agricultural Risk Protection Act of 2000 (ARPA) increased premium subsidies by 50% for the 65% coverage level, more than doubled the 75% coverage level subsidy, and nearly tripled the 85% coverage level subsidy. Even with these dramatically increased subsidy rates, participation didn t return to the 1994-mandated level until Meanwhile, Congress continued to provide ad hoc crop disaster payments. Overall, the structure of market insurance and disaster payments in this setting makes it difficult to determine ex ante whether we should expect significant charity hazard. First, the fact that insurance is not free whereas disaster payments are should discourage insurance takeup when disaster payments are present. However, due to the heavy premium subsidies, crop insurance is cheap, which should reduce the amount of crowd out. Second, disaster payments are given fairly regularly, which lowers the risk of being uninsured or underinsured and not getting bailed out. However, disaster payments are still more uncertain than insurance payments. Third, the fact that indemnity payments are largely ignored when calculating disaster payments should result in lower crowd out than when insured producers cannot receive disaster payments. However, insurance payments are not ignored completely: once the sum of indemnity and disaster payments reaches 95% of the farmer s baseline, the farmer is not eligible for more disaster payments. Finally, if the conditions that trigger crop insurance and disaster payments are very similar, then the latter might be a good substitute for the former. However, as we show in later sections, disaster payments are heavily influenced by politics and do not appear to function as an insurance product in the average county. Thus, the extent of charity hazard is ultimately an empirical question in this and other markets. 9

10 3 Empirical Strategy 3.1 Identification strategy The central empirical question examined in this paper is whether farmers purchase less crop insurance (Y ct ) when they expect ad hoc disaster payments (Disaster ct ) conditional on (1) county fixed effects (a c ) that account for the underlying soil type, climate, and other characteristics that determine the inherent riskiness of producing in each area and (2) year fixed effects (a t ) to account for macroeconomic shocks such as annual price variation and broad changes in the crop insurance program over time. In other words, conditional on a county s inherent riskiness, do farmers exhibit charity hazard by purchasing too little crop insurance when they expect to receive more disaster payments? If so, we would expect estimates of γ in equation (2) to be negative. ln (Y c,t ) = a c + a t + γdisaster c,t + X c,t 1φ + ε c,t. (2) The main econometric problem in interpreting an estimate of γ as evidence of Charity Hazard is that unobservable factors could influence both farmers crop insurance purchases and disaster payments. For instance, farmers in areas prone to disasters (and hence disaster payments) may be more likely to insure than those in safer areas, leading to spurious positive correlation. Even within a county, higher disaster payments may be positively correlated with risk perception and, thus, with crop insurance takeup. Finally, a desire to help uninsured or underinsured producers may result in a negative correlation between insurance and disaster payments even in the absence of charity hazard. We address this problem with county-level voting patterns that (a) affect farmers future disaster assistance and (b) should not affect the benefit from holding insurance through channels other than disaster aid, such as risk. The key identification assumption we make is that voting behavior changes are unrelated to unobservables that also affect insurance preferences. The literature on the role of politics in funding allocation is extensive. Some papers find support for the core voter theory, where legislators distribute funds to their supporters (e.g., Levitt and Snyder, 1995). Others find that funds are targeted toward areas where the votes are split close 10

11 to evenly between the major parties (e.g., Dahlberg and Johansson, 2002). There is also evidence for heterogeneity of preferences for different kinds of spending by party. For example, Albouy (2013) finds that states with Republican representatives receive more defense and transportation money, while states with Democratic representatives receive larger education and urban development grants. More narrowly, the non-agricultural disaster aid process has also been shown to be significantly affected by politics (e.g., Downton and Pielke, 2001; Garrett and Sobel, 2003; Kousky et al., 2013). In particular, Garrett and Sobel (2003) estimate that as much as half of all disaster aid is politically motivated. In agriculture, Garrett et al. (2006) find that the presence of a state s congressmen on committees that have the power to approve agricultural disaster aid is correlated with higher payments. Thus, if there is charity hazard, we should also expect farmers in these areas to be less likely to insure. 11 Other political factors may also have an effect on the propensity of an area to receive disaster payments. The factors that operate at the state level may be different from those that operate at the county level. For example, presidential candidates have an incentive to target states that are close to a split between Republicans and Democrats because of the winner-take-all design of presidential elections. At the county level, however, the absolute number of votes for one s party is likely to be more important. The number of votes can be increased by a combination of increasing turnout of loyal voters, decreasing turnout of non-loyal voters, or changing how people vote (which would involve targeting undecided voters). Consistent with the first two mechanisms, Chen (2013) finds that, in 2004, federal disaster aid in Florida increased turnout among incumbent voters (Republican) and decreased turnout among opposition party voters (Democrat). To capture these channels, we use two measures of political changes in the county: the extent to which a county is heavily Democratic or Republican ( polarization ) and the percentage of voters voting for a third-party candidate. Both measures are constructed using data from Presidential elections./footnotethe targeting of aid might also depend on the combination of which party is 11 We do not use the variables used by Garrett et al. (2006) because they are not strong enough instruments once state fixed effects are included. 11

12 more prevalent in a particular county and which party controls Congress. Unfortunately, during much of our sample period, the two chambers of Congress were controlled by different parties. Previous research has shown that the majority of Americans favor agricultural subsidies (Ellison et al., 2010). Thus, it may be rational for congressmen to influence agricultural disaster spending even in areas where farming is not a large fraction of the economy. Figure 7 shows the spatial distribution of our instruments for the counties in our preferred regression sample. To replicate the variation used in regression analysis, we first demean each political measure as well as account for year fixed effects. We then take the absolute value of these residuals and average them by county. The resulting map demonstrates where the largest sources of political variation are for each of the variables. Darker areas correspond to larger fluctuations in politics over our time period. Overall, there is little geographic concentration in these fluctuations, suggesting that our results will not be driven by a particular area of the country. Because political changes in an area should not directly affect an individual farmer s incentives to insure, the exogeneity requirement is likely to hold. However, we might be concerned that both insurance and political opinions are driven by some other factor, such as income. Fortunately, in most of the counties in our sample, farming is a small fraction of the economy, so farm income is not likely to have a significant impact on political opinions. Thus, political variation is likely to meet the exogeneity requirement. We estimate the relationship between politics and disaster payments using the following regression specification: ln (Disaster c,t ) = a c + a t + βp ctind c,t 1 + γp olarization c,t 1 + θx c,t 1 + ν c,t (3) where c indexes the county and t the year. The variable ln (Disaster c,t ) is the log of total disaster payments made to county c in year t. To avoid missing values, we add 1 to Disaster ct prior to taking the log. The variable P ctind c,t 1 measures what percent of the electorate voted for a 12

13 third party candidate, based on the most recent (but not the current) presidential election. The variable P olarization c,t 1, defined as LastF racrep c,t 1, where LastF racrep c,t 1 is the fraction of voters voting for a Republican candidate, measures the degree of polarization in the county. 12 Finally, X c,t 1 represents the time-varying control variables that could potentially affect both the crop insurance decision and political attitudes: population, the number of farm proprietors, per capita income, total farm income, total employment, and the share of total employment in the agricultural sector. These are all lagged because the insurance decision deadline is in March of a given year for most farmers. Standard errors are clustered by county. In the second stage, we test whether expectations of disaster payments affect insurance decisions: ln (P olicies c,t ) = a c + a t + γ ln (Disasterc,t ) + φx c,t 1 + ε c,t. (4) where ln (P olicies c,t ) is the log of total insurance policies in county c in year t and ln (Disasterc,t ) represents the predicted value of the log of disaster payments from the first stage. As above, X c,t 1 represents the time-varying control variables that could affect the crop insurance decision. In this specification, γ < 0 indicates charity hazard. While the total number of policies is an intuitive way to quantify charity hazard, it is not the only possible measure of insurance coverage. We also consider total liability, which measures the value of insurance purchased by the farmers, the premiums paid by the farmers, which corresponds to total insurance expenditure, and the unsubsidized premiums received by the producers. Finally, we also test whether there is any moral hazard with respect to yields, that is, whether yields are lower when farmers are expecting larger disaster payments. 12 We lag the voting data by at least one year because crop-insurance decisions happen earlier in the year (the spring) than presidential elections, which occur in November. 13

14 3.2 Data Insurance data used in the estimation come from the Risk Management Agency (RMA). The data contain information about the total number of policies, acres insured, premiums paid, liability, subsidies, and indemnity payments for each county where crop insurance was available between 1990 and Disaster payment data were obtained by a Freedom of Information Act request from the Farm Services Agency (FSA). Since livestock insurance was unavailable during the period of our analysis, we focus on disaster payments made for crop losses. After 1994, disaster payments for crops for which insurance was not available are classified under the Non-insurable Crop Disaster Assistance Program (NAP). We do not include NAP payments in our measure of disaster payments. Rather, we focus on disaster payments to producers of crops for which insurance is available because these are the payments to which farmers should respond when making their insurance decisions. 13 Because livestock and NAP payments are not necessarily indicative of potential disaster payments to producers of insurable crops, they may not affect insurance decisions. 14 Yield data are from the National Agricultural Statistical Service (NASS). We use data on yields for seven major crops barley, corn, oats, rice, sorghum, soybeans, and wheat and combine them into a single yield measure on the county-year level. 15 Specifically, we transform the yields into a uniform bushels per acre measure and then take a weighted average for each county-year combination, where the weights are the number of acres harvested for that crop. We use Regional Economic Information Systems (REIS) and County Business Patterns (CBP) data to control for county-level changes that might affect crop insurance decisions (X c,t 1 ). From REIS, we use data on population, the number of farm proprietors, total farm income, and per capita income. CBP provides us with information about the fraction of total employment in forestry and agriculture sectors. 13 Examples of program names are given in Appendix Table A2. A full list of program names is available upon request. 14 Given the highly specialized nature of U.S. agriculture, it is unlikely that farms are diversified enough to rely on cross-subsidization provided by livestock and NAP disaster payments. 15 These crops are also referred to as program crops. 14

15 Finally, our political instruments are constructed from data on county-level voting results in presidential elections. The 2004 and 2008 data come from Dave Leip s Atlas of U.S. Presidential Elections, while earlier data were generously shared by James Snyder. 4 Results 4.1 Summary statistics Table 1 shows economic and political summary statistics for our main regression sample, where we exclude counties that appear fewer than 18 times during our sample and observations that are missing control characteristics. All monetary amounts are reported in 2011 dollars. The average county has over 86, 000 residents, out of whom less than 1% or 710 people are farm proprietors. About one percent of total employment is in the forestry/agriculture sectors. Farm income represents about 3% of total personal income in the average county. Table 1 also shows summary statistics for voting in Presidential elections between 1988 and In the average county, about 34, 000 votes were cast, with a little less than 7% of those votes being cast for a third-party candidate. Our polarization measure ranges from 0 (representing a county where exactly half the voters voted Republican) to 0.85, representing a county that leans heavily toward one of the two major parties. In the regression analysis, we convert these political measures into standard deviations to make interpretation more intuitive. Table 2 shows insurance statistics for our main regression sample. On average, there are about 420 crop insurance policies issued per county in each year, covering over 70, 000 acres. Farmers in the average county spend about $640, 000 (in 2011 dollars) on insurance, with the government contributing an additional $840, 000 in premium subsidies. The mean total liability in a county is about $17 million. Over our sample period, insurers paid $1, 000, 000 in indemnity payments each year, on average, while the government contributed an additional $424, 000 in disaster payments. Thus, disaster payments are close to half the size of indemnity payments, while subsidies are over two thirds of the size. Taken together, subsidies and disaster payments exceed indemnity payments, 15

16 reinforcing the idea that agriculture is heavily subsidized. 16 The average loss ratio from the farmer s point of view (defined as indemnity payments divided by subsidized premiums) is 2.3, which implies that for the average farmer who buys crop insurance, a dollar spent on insurance will result in 2.3 dollars of indemnity payments. Thus, crop insurance has historically been very profitable for those taking it up. Below, we also show the loss ratio from the insurance provider s point of view, defined as the ratio of indemnity payments and unsubsidized premiums. In this case, the average is 0.82, implying that for every dollar received in premiums, insurance companies paid out 82 cents in indemnity payments. Overall, the summary statistics demonstrate that farmers represent a small fraction of the electorate and the economy in most counties, and are thus unlikely to be driving the political trends. Furthermore, while there is substantial government intervention in the form of disaster payments, crop insurance is also heavily subsidized, making it profitable to hold. This makes it unclear ex ante as to whether we are likely to find substantial crowd out of insurance by disaster payments. 4.2 OLS We proceed by looking at the raw relationship between disaster payments and insurance takeup. Table 3 shows the results of a naive regression of the number of policies in a county on same-year and previous-year disaster payments. All specifications include county and year fixed effects, while Columns 4-6 also control for lagged county-level characteristics. There is a positive and significant relationship between contemporaneous disaster payments and insurance takeup throughout. There is also a positive relationship between lagged disaster payments and takeup. Both estimates remain significant and relatively constant across the specifications. Specifically, a 1% increase in disaster payments is associated with a % increase in takeup in the following year and a % increase in takeup in the current year. This relationship can exist for a number of reasons. First, in some cases farmers who receive disaster payments are required to purchase crop 16 The government also reinsures private insurance providers; thus, this calculation of government expenditure represents a lower bound. 16

17 insurance in the next one or two years. Second, an adverse event can trigger disaster payments and change farmers beliefs about risk to their crops, resulting in more insurance in the following year on net. Thus, without a valid instrument that holds risk constant, we cannot say much about the existence of charity hazard. Table 3 also reveals other predictors of takeup. 17 As expected, the number of farm proprietors are strong predictors of the insurance decision. However, total employment and the share of employment in agriculture are not. Increases in the per capita personal income are associated with a decrease in insurance takeup. Finally, a higher population is associated with higher insurance takeup in some specifications. 4.3 First stage Because of potential confounders and reverse causality, the OLS analysis cannot illuminate the causal relationship between disaster payments and insurance takeup. We thus proceed with our instrumental variables strategy. Table 4 shows the estimated relationship between total disaster payments and political changes, as measured by the percent of the voters who voted for a thirdparty presidential candidate in the most recent election and by the degree to which the county is polarized toward one of the two major parties. Both measures are in standard deviations. Due to the presence of many zeros, we add 1 to the amount of disaster payments before taking the log. The results show a strong relationship between both measures of political changes in the county and disaster payments. Specifically, a one standard deviation increase in the percent of people who voted for a third party candidate in the last presidential election increases disaster payments in that county by 8.6%. Polarization is also associated with higher disaster payments: for every standard deviation increase, disaster payments increase by 16.9%. All else equal, counties with fewer farm proprietors, lower population, and lower per-capita income receive more disaster payments. The F-statistic in the specification that includes characteristic controls, as well as year and county fixed effects (Columns 4) is slightly above the conventional threshold of Farm income deciles are included in the regression but have been omitted from the table for readability. 17

18 4.4 Second stage Having established that political changes in the county are predictive of disaster payments, but should not affect the crop insurance decision in other ways, we proceed to use these variables as instruments in the second stage. Table 5 shows the estimated effect of disaster payments on crop insurance takeup in a county. Our preferred specification, which includes characteristics controls, is shown in Column 4. A one percent increase in expected disaster payments causes the number of crop insurance policies to drop by 0.2 percent. This estimate is highly significant. 18 The estimates above capture only the extensive margin of the insurance decision (choosing whether or not to have crop insurance). Due to the large number of plan choices faced by farmers, the intensive margin (choosing how much crop insurance to purchase) could be important as well. Because there could be differential selection out of insurance, we cannot estimate the intensive margin separately. However, we can look at other measures of insurance that include both the intensive and extensive margins. In Table 6, we estimate how disaster payment expectations change total liability and gross premiums (which include subsidy payments) in a county. We again find evidence of charity hazard: a one percent increase in expected disaster payments lowers total liability and gross premiums by about 0.34%. In dollar terms, this corresponds to about $8, 800 and $790, respectively. 19 In Table 7, we look at net premiums (which exclude subsidy payments), subsidy expenditure, and yields. In some counties in our sample, farmers pay no premiums out of pocket because of high subsidy levels. Thus, we consider net premiums both with and without adding 1 to them. If we consider only observations where farmers pay some premiums out of pocket (Column 1), we find significant charity hazard, with an estimated elasticity with respect to disaster payments of 0.3. If we also include observations where no premiums were paid (Column 2), our estimate of charity hazard becomes substantially larger, about 0.5. Regardless of the specification, these results 18 Because we do not have high frequency variation in voting, we cannot determine whether farmers are reacting to past disaster payments or expected disaster payments. If we instrument for lagged disaster payments, we get very similar estimates of the farmers response. 19 All dollar figures are calculated by exponentiating the mean of the variable, as shown in the second stage tables, and multiplying by the corresponding percentage. 18

19 suggest that farmers do reduce their expenditure on insurance in response to disaster payments. In Columns 3 and 4 of Table 7, we look at total subsidies and yields. The former represent an estimate of the government crowding out its own spending. The latter is an estimate of direct moral hazard with respect to disaster payments. We find that the elasticity of subsidies with respect to disaster payments is also about That is, for every percent increase in disaster payments, subsidy payments decrease by 0.34%. Finally, we find evidence for direct moral hazard: a one percent increase in disaster payments leads to a statistically significant decline in yields of 0.18%. Finally, in Table 8, we look at changes in insurance coverage conditional on buying a policy. In this case, the estimates will include both selection (i.e., who chooses to forego insurance) and changes in insurance decisions among those who continue to insure. We find that insurance coverage, as measured by liability per policy, falls by about 0.28% in response to a one percent increase in disaster coverage. Both gross and net premiums per policy fall by about 0.30%, while the subsidy per policy does not change significantly. Overall, our estimates imply that the elimination of disaster payments would significantly raise insurance coverage. 5 The Insurance Value of Disaster Payments As discussed earlier, disaster payments are more variable than indemnity payments. Furthermore, we find that they are significantly influenced by politics. Thus, their value as insurance against income shocks may be quite low. In this section, we estimate the certainty equivalent of the current disaster program for a representative farmer in each county. We compare this to the actual disaster payments and to the certainty equivalents of the formal crop insurance program in order to gauge the insurance value of disaster payments. We assume that there exists a representative farmer in each county, whose income, insurance choice, and disaster payments correspond to those of the average farmer. The farmer has a Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) utility function, U(w) = w1 ρ. Specifically, the farmer s utility is 1 ρ given by: 19

20 U(w, I, d, π) = (w + I + d π)1 ρ 1 ρ where w is income, net of crop losses, I is indemnity payments from the formal insurance program, d is disaster payments, π is insurance premiums, and ρ > 0 is the coefficient of risk aversion. Chetty (2006) estimates that ρ is likely to be close to 1, in which case the utility function is simply the log of the sum of its components. We vary risk aversion around this value. In our baseline scenario, we use the empirical counterparts of w, I, d, and π to calculate the expected utility in each county. To calculate the certainty equivalents of the disaster and insurance programs, we then simulate two counterfactual scenarios. In the first scenario, farmers no longer receive disaster payments but instead get a fixed transfer payment such that their utility is equal to that of the baseline scenario. These transfer payments are the certainty equivalents. We assume that insurance decisions are unchanged, which means that the calculated certainty equivalents are upper bounds. In the second scenario, we assume that farmers no longer receive indemnity payments or pay insurance premiums, while leaving the disaster payments unchanged. For each county, we calculate the fixed transfer payment that would leave farmers indifferent between this and the baseline scenario. We allow this transfer payment to vary by county. Estimating the empirical joint distribution of the utility components correctly is important. Luckily, we observe actual joint realizations of the number of farmers, farm incomes, insurance premiums, indemnities, and disaster payments in each county, in some cases for 20 years. The number of farm proprietors and their net income is reported by REIS, while the disaster and insurance variables are obtained from the RMA and FSA, as described in Section 3.2. Net farm income excludes production expenses and should capture income losses from a poor harvest. One complication is that reported farm income also includes disaster and indemnity payments, and it is important for us to be able to separate them from income itself. Our measures of dis- 20

21 aster and indemnity payments includes payments made to corporate farms, however, so simply subtracting them from income would be inappropriate. We proceed by assuming that disaster and indemnity payments are allocated to farm proprietors based on their average income share relative to corporate farms in that county and subtract them from net farm income. Another complication is that it is not uncommon for farm income to be negative in any given year. We address this issue in two different ways ways. The first way is to assume that farmers can borrow from future incomes for up to 5-10 years at a real interest rate of 3%. To incorporate this into our model, we calculate the mean of per farmer farm income, indemnities, disaster payments and premiums for each county, as well as their residuals. We then assume that the farmer s utility is a function of the sum of the discounted mean income, mean indemnities, and disaster payments minus premiums over either 5 or 10 years plus the residual fluctuations in these variables in any particular year. The second way is to take into account the fact that many farmers may have nonfarm income. Specifically, we assume that the farmer s non-farm income is equal to the per capita income in his county (but we do not allow for borrowing). We restrict the sample to counties for which we have at least 18 years of data. In order to avoid missing utility values, we also drop any county where the average annual income (taking into account insurance and disaster payments as well as premiums) is lower than $10, 000. This leaves us with a sample of 1,350 counties. Table 9 summarizes the average disaster payments and their certainty equivalents. Column 3 shows the estimates for the central risk aversion coefficient of 1, while the other columns show the results for lower and higher levels of risk aversion. The current disaster payments are simply taken from the data; thus, they do not vary by risk aversion. Overall, the certainty equivalents are very similar to the actual disaster payments. The average certainty equivalent is strictly lower than the average disaster payment in all scenarios, implying that the average farmer would not be willing to pay for the current disaster program. The certainty equivalents also do not vary much by risk aversion. In fact, there is a small but significant negative correlation between certainty equivalents and risk aversion in the underlying data, suggesting that 21

22 disaster payments are made in times of relatively high incomes, on average. Our assumptions about the time horizon do not seem to affect the estimates much. Accounting for the fact that many farmers have non-farm income substantially lowers the certainty equivalent. Overall, this table shows that disaster payments do not appear to be a valuable insurance product, at least at the county-year level. Because our simulation does not allow for a change in crop insurance decisions, these certainty equivalents are an upper bound. As we showed in the previous section, it s likely that farmers would compensate for some of the lost disaster payments by increasing their insurance coverage. These estimates also cannot speak about the value of the marginal dollar of disaster payments and are thus not inconsistent with our earlier findings of crowd out. Alternatively, it may be that even though disaster payments are not a good insurance product, they nonetheless create crowdout (Brown and Finkelstein, 2008). Table 10 shows the corresponding certainty equivalents of the formal insurance program. In contrast to the previous results, the average certainty equivalent always exceeds the average net insurance payment (indemnity minus premiums). The average farmer with a risk aversion coefficient of 1 is willing to pay between $131 and $206 more for the formal crop insurance program. Moreover, the certainty equivalents are significantly increasing in risk aversion, as would be expected in the case of an insurance program. We confirm that disaster payments do not appear to serve an insurance role at the county level by looking at the aggregate relationship between farm incomes, disaster payments, and indemnity payments. The results are shown in Table 11. A decrease of per farmer income by $1,000 is associated with a $44 rise in per farmer indemnity payments, but is completely unrelated to the amount of per farmer disaster payments in levels. In log terms (Columns 3-4), there is a small and only marginally significant association between per farmer disaster payments and per farmer income. By contrast, Column 3 indicates that a one percent decrease in per farmer income is strongly associated with a 0.25 percent rise in per farmer indemnity payments. A few discussion points are in order. First, the absence of a significant correlation between county-level farm income and disaster payments does not rule out that it exists at an individual 22

23 level. In that sense, our estimates of the certainty equivalent may be lower bounds. Unfortunately, farm-level insurance and income data are not available to us. However, many events that adversely affect farm incomes, such as droughts, floods, and pest outbreaks operate at a level above the individual farm, implying that farm incomes within a particular county should be highly correlated. Moreover, we find a substantial willingness to pay for the formal insurance program at the county level. Second, our analysis assumes that the distribution of disaster payments, indemnity payments, and incomes is not changing throughout this time period. As discussed in Section 2, the crop insurance program has undergone a number of changes and its penetration has increased substantially. The development and subsequent rise in popularity of revenue (as opposed to yield) insurance should have made the insurance program more valuable over time. Third, because we only have 20 years of data, our estimates may miss truly disastrous (and rare) realizations of farm incomes. However, it is unclear that this omission would impact the certainty equivalents of disaster payment more than that of the formal crop insurance program. Finally, counties with very low farm incomes are omitted from the estimation to accomodate the functional form of CRRA utility. If utility truly exhibits constant absolute risk aversion, then this omission is not likely to affect our estimates, as shocks to farm income are likely proportional to income levels. However, if shocks are relatively larger when incomes are smaller or if farmers do not have utility functions that are close to CRRA, then we are likely underestimating the value of both insurance and disaster payments. 6 Conclusion The existence of systemic risk may sometimes make it optimal for the government to act as an insurer of last resort. However, the possibility of a government bailout in such cases may also encourage risk-taking and crowd out private insurance takeup, leading to what is known as charity hazard. This type of moral hazard may exist in many areas of the economy, from banks taking 23

24 on excessive risk to homeowners foregoing flood insurance. Thus, understanding it and measuring its magnitude is extremely important. However, the extent to which charity hazard is a problem is debated, and few empirical papers exist that confirm or disprove its existence. We test for the existence of charity hazard in US agriculture, an area in which it has long been posited to be a problem. From the establishment of modern crop insurance in 1980, Congress has passed ad hoc bills granting disaster aid to farmers who did not have insurance or whose insurance did not cover all their crop losses. We instrument for disaster payments using political variation at the county level. We then estimate how expected disaster payments affect total crop insurance liability in the county. We find that charity hazard exists and is significant. The estimated elasticity of insurance takeup with respect to disaster payments is 0.2. Total insurance expenditure is also sensitive to disaster payments, decreasing by 0.3 percent for every percent increase in expected disaster payments. We also find that the government crowds out its own premium subsidies at about a 30% percent rate. Finally, we find evidence of moral hazard with respect to yields: expectations of higher disaster payments lead to modest but significant reductions in the county s yield. Our results imply that a nontrivial fraction of disaster payments is being transfered to farmers who would have had insurance otherwise. Moreover, it appears that disaster payments do not have a high insurance value, on average. Of course, eliminating disaster payments would require the government to be able to commit to not grant them ex post, something that it has not been able to do thus far in the realm of agricultural disaster payments. 24

25 References Crop Disaster Program (2008). 7 C.F.R Agriculture, Rural Development, Food and Drug Administration, and Related Agencies Appropriations Act, 1999 (1998). Pub. L. No Albouy, D. (2013). Partisan representation in congress and the geographic distribution of federal funds. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(1), Babcock, B. A. (2012). The politics and economics of the us crop insurance program. In J. S. G. Zivin and J. M. Perloff (Eds.), The Intended and Unintended Effects of U.S. Agricultural and Biotechnology Policies. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Brown, J. R. and A. Finkelstein (2008). The interaction of public and private insurance: Medicaid and the long-term care insurance market. The American Economic Review 98(3), Browne, M. J. and R. E. Hoyt (2000). The demand for flood insurance: Empirical evidence. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 20(3), Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 2006 (2005). Chen, J. (2013). Voter Partisanship and the Effect of Distributive Spending on Political Participation. American Journal of Political Science, 57(1), Chetty, R. (2006). A new method of estimating risk aversion. The American Economic Review 96(5), pp Dahlberg, M. and E. Johansson (2002). On the vote-purchasing behavior of incumbent governments. American Political Science Review 96(1), Downton, M. W. and R. A. Pielke (2001). Discretion without accountability: Politics, flood damage, and climate. Natural Hazards Review 2001(November),

26 Ellison, B., J. L. Lusk, and B. Briggeman (2010). Other-regarding behavior and taxpayer preferences for farm policy. The BE Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 10(1). Garrett, T., T. Marsh, and M. Marshall (2006, June). Political allocation of US agriculture disaster payments in the 1990s. International Review of Law and Economics 26(2), Garrett, T. a. and R. S. Sobel (2003, July). The Political Economy of FEMA Disaster Payments. Economic Inquiry 41(3), Glauber, J. W. and K. J. Collins (2002). Crop insurance, disaster assistance, and the role of the federal government in providing catastrophic risk protection. Agricultural Finance Review 62(2), Gross, T. and M. J. Notowidigdo (2011). Health insurance and the consumer bankruptcy decision: Evidence from expansions of medicaid. Journal of Public Economics 95(7), Gruber, J. and K. Simon (2008). Crowd-out 10 years later: Have recent public insurance expansions crowded out private health insurance? Journal of Health Economics 27(2), Jose, H. D. and R. S. K. Valluru (1997, November). Insights from the Crop Insurance Reform Act of Agribusiness 13(6), Kelly, M. and A. Kleffner (2003). Optimal loss mitigation and contract design. Journal of Risk and Insurance 70(1), Kim, B. J. and H. Schlesinger (2005). Adverse selection in an insurance market with governmentguaranteed subsistence levels. Journal of Risk and Insurance 72(1), Kousky, C., E. O. Michel-Kerjan, and P. Raschky (2013). Does federal disaster assistance crowd out private demand for insurance? The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Risk Management and Decision Processes Center Working Paper Kunreuther, H., R. Ginsberg, L. Miller, P. Sagi, P. Slovic, B. Borkan, and N. Katz (1978). Disaster insurance protection: Public policy lessons. Wiley New York. 26

27 Levitt, S. D. and J. M. Snyder (1995). Political parties and the distribution of federal outlays. American Journal of Political Science 39, Lewis, T. and D. Nickerson (1989). Self-insurance against natural disasters. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 16(3), Mahoney, N. (2012). Bankruptcy as implicit health insurance. NBER Working Paper No Raschky, P. and M. Schwindt (2009). Aid, Natural Disasters and the Samaritan s Dilemma. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No Raschky, P. and H. Weckhannemann (2007). Charity hazard A real hazard to natural disaster insurance? Environmental Hazards 7(4), U.S. General Accounting Office (1989). DISASTER ASSISTANCE: Crop Insurance Can Provide Assistance More Effectively Than Other Programs. Technical report, United States General Accounting Office. U.S. Government Accountability Office (1980, June). Federal Disaster Assistance: What Should The Policy Be? Number PAD Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. Troop Readiness, Veterans Care, Katrina Recovery, and Iraq Accountability Appropriations Act of 2007 (2007). Pub. L. No , 9001, 121 Stat Van Asseldonk, M. A., M. P. Meuwissen, and R. B. Huirne (2002). Belief in disaster relief and the demand for a public-private insurance program. Review of Agricultural Economics 24(1),

28 Figures Figure 1: Indemnity and disaster payments over time All amounts are in 2011 dollars. Disaster payment series represents payments to producers of crops for which insurance is available. 28

29 Figure 2: The Geographic Distribution of Total Indemnity Payments from Figure 3: The Geographic Distribution of Total Crop Disaster Payments from

30 Figure 4: Farm Revenue as Crop Losses Increase 30

31 Figure 5: The Crop Insurance Premium Subsidy Rates from

32 Figure 6: Acres Covered by Crop Insurance from

33 Figure 7: Absolute mean changes in political behavior Panel A: Polarization Panel B: percent voting for third party candidate. Illustrates mean absolute changes between 1988 and National trends and county fixed effects have been accounted for. Darker areas indicate larger changes. Shown only for counties included in the regression sample. 33

DOES THE SAMARITAN S DILEMMA MATTER? EVIDENCE FROM CROP INSURANCE

DOES THE SAMARITAN S DILEMMA MATTER? EVIDENCE FROM CROP INSURANCE DOES THE SAMARITAN S DILEMMA MATTER? EVIDENCE FROM CROP INSURANCE TATYANA DERYUGINA AND BARRETT KIRWAN July 14, 2014 Abstract The theory of the Samaritan s dilemma posits a downside to private or public

More information

The Supplementary Insurance Coverage Option: A New Risk Management Tool for Wyoming Producers

The Supplementary Insurance Coverage Option: A New Risk Management Tool for Wyoming Producers The Supplementary Insurance Coverage Option: A New Risk Management Tool for Wyoming Producers Agricultural Marketing Policy Center Linfield Hall P.O. Box 172920 Montana State University Bozeman, MT 59717-2920

More information

Implications of Crop Insurance as Social Policy

Implications of Crop Insurance as Social Policy Implications of Crop Insurance as Social Policy Bruce Babcock Iowa State University Presented at the Minnesota Crop Insurance Conference Sept 10, 2014 Mankato, MN Summary of talk 2014 farm bill irrevocably

More information

Lower Rates Mean Lower Crop Insurance Cost 1

Lower Rates Mean Lower Crop Insurance Cost 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

Group Risk Income Protection Plan and Group Risk Plans added in New Kansas Counties for 2005 1 Updated 3/12/05

Group Risk Income Protection Plan and Group Risk Plans added in New Kansas Counties for 2005 1 Updated 3/12/05 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

Influence of the Premium Subsidy on Farmers Crop Insurance Coverage Decisions

Influence of the Premium Subsidy on Farmers Crop Insurance Coverage Decisions Influence of the Premium Subsidy on Farmers Crop Insurance Coverage Decisions Bruce A. Babcock and Chad E. Hart Working Paper 05-WP 393 April 2005 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State

More information

Group Risk Income Protection Plan added in Kansas for 2006 Wheat (Updated) 1

Group Risk Income Protection Plan added in Kansas for 2006 Wheat (Updated) 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

CROP REVENUE COVERAGE INSURANCE PROVIDES ADDITIONAL RISK MANAGEMENT WHEAT ALTERNATIVES 1

CROP REVENUE COVERAGE INSURANCE PROVIDES ADDITIONAL RISK MANAGEMENT WHEAT ALTERNATIVES 1 Presented at the 1997 Missouri Commercial Agriculture Crop Institute CROP REVENUE COVERAGE INSURANCE PROVIDES ADDITIONAL RISK MANAGEMENT WHEAT ALTERNATIVES 1 Presented by: Art Barnaby Managing Risk With

More information

U.S. crop program fiscal costs: Revised estimates with updated participation information

U.S. crop program fiscal costs: Revised estimates with updated participation information U.S. crop program fiscal costs: Revised estimates with updated participation information June 2015 FAPRI MU Report #02 15 Providing objective analysis for 30 years www.fapri.missouri.edu Published by the

More information

Managing Risk With Revenue Insurance

Managing Risk With Revenue Insurance Managing Risk With Revenue Insurance VOLUME 4 ISSUE 5 22 Robert Dismukes, dismukes@ers.usda.gov Keith H. Coble, coble@agecon.msstate.edu Comstock 10 Crop revenue insurance offers farmers a way to manage

More information

Crop Tariff Models For Farmers Insurance

Crop Tariff Models For Farmers Insurance Rationality of Choices in Subsidized Crop Insurance Markets HONGLI FENG, IOWA STATE UNIVERSITY XIAODONG (SHELDON) DU, UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN-MADISON DAVID HENNESSY, IOWA STATE UNIVERSITY Plan of talk

More information

CHAPTER 2 AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE: A BACKGROUND 9

CHAPTER 2 AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE: A BACKGROUND 9 CHAPTER 2 AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE: A BACKGROUND 9 Chapter 2: AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE: A BACKGROUND In Chapter 1 we saw that insurance is one of the tools that farmers and other stakeholders can use to manage

More information

(Over)reacting to bad luck: low yields increase crop insurance participation. Howard Chong Jennifer Ifft

(Over)reacting to bad luck: low yields increase crop insurance participation. Howard Chong Jennifer Ifft (Over)reacting to bad luck: low yields increase crop insurance participation Howard Chong Jennifer Ifft Motivation Over the last 3 decades, U.S. farms have steadily increased participation in the Federal

More information

Group Risk Income Protection

Group Risk Income Protection Group Risk Income Protection James B. Johnson and John Hewlett* Objective Analysis for Informed Agricultural Marketing Policy Paper No. 13 July 2006 Decision Making * University of Wyoming, Extension Educator

More information

Farm Programs and Crop Insurance

Farm Programs and Crop Insurance Evaluating the Interaction between Farm Programs with Crop Insurance and Producers Risk Preferences Todd D. Davis John D. Anderson Robert E. Young Senior Economist Deputy Chief Economist Chief Economist

More information

From Catastrophic to Shallow Loss Coverage: An Economist's Perspective of U.S. Crop Insurance Program and Implications for Developing Countries

From Catastrophic to Shallow Loss Coverage: An Economist's Perspective of U.S. Crop Insurance Program and Implications for Developing Countries From Catastrophic to Shallow Loss Coverage: An Economist's Perspective of U.S. Crop Insurance Program and Implications for Developing Countries Robert Dismukes Agricultural Economist Insurance coverage:

More information

Explaining the Costs

Explaining the Costs TODAYcrop insurance Explaining the Costs of the Crop Insurance Program By Keith Collins and Frank Schnapp, NCIS This article examines the information typically presented to the public on the costs of the

More information

Medicaid Crowd-Out of Long-Term Care Insurance With Endogenous Medicaid Enrollment

Medicaid Crowd-Out of Long-Term Care Insurance With Endogenous Medicaid Enrollment Medicaid Crowd-Out of Long-Term Care Insurance With Endogenous Medicaid Enrollment Geena Kim University of Pennsylvania 12th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement Research Consortium August 5-6, 2010

More information

We have seen in the How

We have seen in the How : Examples Using Hedging, Forward Contracting, Crop Insurance, and Revenue Insurance To what extent can hedging, forward contracting, and crop and revenue insurance reduce uncertainty within the year (intrayear)

More information

What Harm is Done by Subsidizing Crop Insurance?

What Harm is Done by Subsidizing Crop Insurance? What Harm is Done by Subsidizing Crop Insurance? Barry K. Goodwin and Vincent H. Smith 1 Agriculture is subject to a wide variety of risks, including many hazards arising from wide-spread natural disasters.

More information

Crop Insurance as a Tool

Crop Insurance as a Tool Crop Insurance as a Tool By: Chris Bastian University of Wyoming There are several approaches to address income variability associated with production risk. One approach is to produce more than one product

More information

Farmer Savings Accounts

Farmer Savings Accounts Farmer Savings Accounts Mark A. Edelman, Iowa State University James D. Monke, Economic Research Service, USDA Ron Durst, Economic Research Service, USDA Introduction Various incentives can be used to

More information

CHOOSING AMONG CROP INSURANCE PRODUCTS

CHOOSING AMONG CROP INSURANCE PRODUCTS CHOOSING AMONG CROP INSURANCE PRODUCTS Gary Schnitkey Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Email: schnitke@uiuc.edu, Phone: (217) 244-9595 August

More information

CROP INSURANCE. Reducing Subsidies for Highest Income Participants Could Save Federal Dollars with Minimal Effect on the Program

CROP INSURANCE. Reducing Subsidies for Highest Income Participants Could Save Federal Dollars with Minimal Effect on the Program United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Requesters March 2015 CROP INSURANCE Reducing Subsidies for Highest Income Participants Could Save Federal Dollars with Minimal Effect

More information

2. To determine APH yields, can crop insurance history be used? The last program (2002) required actual scale tickets from the grain elevator.

2. To determine APH yields, can crop insurance history be used? The last program (2002) required actual scale tickets from the grain elevator. Questions and answers from Session 2 Managing Margin Risk 1. Could you elaborate more on the up to 150% of a county yield option on GRP and GRIP plans? What are the advantages and additional costs associated

More information

Buy the More Expensive Revenue Protection and Sell off Part of the Coverage 1

Buy the More Expensive Revenue Protection and Sell off Part of the Coverage 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

CROP INSURANCE FOR NEW YORK VEGETABLE CROPS

CROP INSURANCE FOR NEW YORK VEGETABLE CROPS CROP INSURANCE FOR NEW YORK VEGETABLE CROPS Multi-peril crop insurance is a valuable risk management tool that allows growers to insure against losses due to adverse weather conditions, price fluctuations,

More information

Evaluating the Impact of Proposed Farm Bill Programs with Crop Insurance for Southern Crops. Todd D. Davis * John D. Anderson Nathan B.

Evaluating the Impact of Proposed Farm Bill Programs with Crop Insurance for Southern Crops. Todd D. Davis * John D. Anderson Nathan B. Evaluating the Impact of Proposed Farm Bill Programs with Crop Insurance for Southern Crops Todd D. Davis * John D. Anderson Nathan B. Smith Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the Southern Agricultural

More information

TODAYcrop insurance. Crop Insurance Rate of Return. Issues & Concerns. By Frank Schnapp, NCIS

TODAYcrop insurance. Crop Insurance Rate of Return. Issues & Concerns. By Frank Schnapp, NCIS TODAYcrop insurance Crop Insurance Rate of Return Issues & Concerns By Frank Schnapp, NCIS In recent months, a variety of claims have been aired in the press regarding the cost of delivery of the Federal

More information

Appendix A. A Nonstochastic Comparison of Price- and Revenue-Based Support

Appendix A. A Nonstochastic Comparison of Price- and Revenue-Based Support Appendix A. A Nonstochastic Comparison of Price- and Revenue-ased Support efore planting, the producer can only guess at harvested yields and harvesttime prices due to their stochastic nature (that is,

More information

Market-Driven Inventory System (MDIS)

Market-Driven Inventory System (MDIS) Market-Driven Over the last dozen years, low-price and high-price extremes revealed shortcomings of the U.S. agricultural commodity program. Under the current program when supply exceeds demand, crop prices

More information

Social Insurance with Private Insurance Markets. 2 Social Insurance with Endogenous Private Insurance

Social Insurance with Private Insurance Markets. 2 Social Insurance with Endogenous Private Insurance Florian Scheuer 4/22/2014 Social Insurance with Private Insurance Markets 1 Overview in many insurance applications, public and private insurance co-exist even when private insurance markets may not be

More information

Cost & Efficiency Analysis of U.S. Crop Insurance Program: Implications of Additional FSA Responsibilities

Cost & Efficiency Analysis of U.S. Crop Insurance Program: Implications of Additional FSA Responsibilities Cost & Efficiency Analysis of U.S. Crop Insurance Program: Implications of Additional FSA Responsibilities Executive Summary Prepared for: Informa Economics Phone: 901.766.4669 www.informaecon.com September

More information

Designing public private crop insurance in Finland

Designing public private crop insurance in Finland Designing public private crop insurance in Finland Liesivaara 1, P., Meuwissen 2, M.P.M. and Myyrä 1, S 1 MTT Agrifood Research Finland 2 Business Economics, Wageningen University, the Netherlands Abstract

More information

Common Crop Insurance Policy (CCIP) DR. G. A. ART BARNABY, JR. Kansas State University 4B Agricultural Consultants

Common Crop Insurance Policy (CCIP) DR. G. A. ART BARNABY, JR. Kansas State University 4B Agricultural Consultants Common Crop Insurance Policy (CCIP) DR. G. A. ART BARNABY, JR. Kansas State University 4B Agricultural Consultants Phone: 785-532-1515 EMAIL: barnaby@ksu.edu Check out our WEB page at http://www.agmanager.info

More information

An Analysis of a Market-Driven Inventory System (MDIS)

An Analysis of a Market-Driven Inventory System (MDIS) An Analysis of a Market-Driven Inventory System (MDIS) Harwood D. Schaffer, Research Assistant Professor Chad Hellwinckel, Research Assistant Professor Daryll E. Ray, Professor and Co-Director Daniel G.

More information

Farmers Yield And Individual Revenue Plans - Budgetamentals

Farmers Yield And Individual Revenue Plans - Budgetamentals Online Appendix: Not for Publication September 18, 2015 1 Appendix A - Insurance Payments in Individual Plans Because farmer productivity varies, individual baseline yields are necessary for individual-level

More information

Managing Feed and Milk Price Risk: Futures Markets and Insurance Alternatives

Managing Feed and Milk Price Risk: Futures Markets and Insurance Alternatives Managing Feed and Milk Price Risk: Futures Markets and Insurance Alternatives Dillon M. Feuz Department of Applied Economics Utah State University 3530 Old Main Hill Logan, UT 84322-3530 435-797-2296 dillon.feuz@usu.edu

More information

SUBSIDIZING RISK: THE REGRESSIVE AND COUNTERPRODUCTIVE NATURE OF NATIONAL FLOOD INSURANCE RATE SETTING IN MASSACHUSETTS

SUBSIDIZING RISK: THE REGRESSIVE AND COUNTERPRODUCTIVE NATURE OF NATIONAL FLOOD INSURANCE RATE SETTING IN MASSACHUSETTS PPC Working Paper Series- Working Paper No. ENV-2015-01 SUBSIDIZING RISK: THE REGRESSIVE AND COUNTERPRODUCTIVE NATURE OF NATIONAL FLOOD INSURANCE RATE SETTING IN MASSACHUSETTS June, 2015 Chad McGuire Associate

More information

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold?

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley and NBER January 2004 This paper was presented at the 2004 Meetings of the American Economic Association. I

More information

Volume Title: The Intended and Unintended Effects of U.S. Agricultural and Biotechnology Policies

Volume Title: The Intended and Unintended Effects of U.S. Agricultural and Biotechnology Policies This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Intended and Unintended Effects of U.S. Agricultural and Biotechnology Policies Volume Author/Editor:

More information

Will ARC Allow Farmers to Cancel Their 2014 Crop Insurance (Updated)? 1

Will ARC Allow Farmers to Cancel Their 2014 Crop Insurance (Updated)? 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

The Impact of Alternative Farm Bill Designs on the Aggregate Distribution of Farm Program Payments. Keith H. Coble and Barry J.

The Impact of Alternative Farm Bill Designs on the Aggregate Distribution of Farm Program Payments. Keith H. Coble and Barry J. The Impact of Alternative Farm Bill Designs on the Aggregate Distribution of Farm Program Payments Keith H. Coble and Barry J. Barnett Abstract Several 2007 farm bill proposals focused on reforming commodity

More information

Risk Management Agency

Risk Management Agency Risk Management Agency Premium Rate Study Update Questions & Answers November 2012 Q1 Why is RMA examining premium rates and the process for determining them? A1 Section 508(i) of the Federal Crop Insurance

More information

Integrated Resource Plan

Integrated Resource Plan Integrated Resource Plan March 19, 2004 PREPARED FOR KAUA I ISLAND UTILITY COOPERATIVE LCG Consulting 4962 El Camino Real, Suite 112 Los Altos, CA 94022 650-962-9670 1 IRP 1 ELECTRIC LOAD FORECASTING 1.1

More information

Federal Crop Insurance: The Basics

Federal Crop Insurance: The Basics Federal Crop Insurance: The Basics Presented by Shawn Wade Director of Communications Plains Cotton Growers, Inc. 4517 West Loop 289 Lubbock, TX 79414 WWW.PLAINSCOTTON.ORG Why Federal Crop Insurance? Every

More information

Agricultural Outlook Forum For Release: Monday, February 23, 1998 AGRICULTURAL RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR

Agricultural Outlook Forum For Release: Monday, February 23, 1998 AGRICULTURAL RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR Agricultural Outlook Forum For Release: Monday, February 23, 1998 AGRICULTURAL RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR Joseph W. Glauber Deputy Chief Economist U.S. Department of Agriculture

More information

Title I Programs of the 2014 Farm Bill

Title I Programs of the 2014 Farm Bill Frequently Asked Questions: Title I Programs of the 2014 Farm Bill November 2014 Robin Reid G.A. Art Barnaby Mykel Taylor Extension Associate Extension Specialist Assistant Professor Kansas State University

More information

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers Ralph S. J. Koijen Motohiro Yogo University of Chicago and NBER Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 1 1 The views expressed herein are not necessarily

More information

Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice. Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University. Abstract

Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice. Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University. Abstract Using Prospect Theory to Explain Anomalous Crop Insurance Coverage Choice Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University Abstract Farmers decisions about how much crop insurance to buy are not generally consistent

More information

GAO CROP INSURANCE. Savings Would Result from Program Changes and Greater Use of Data Mining

GAO CROP INSURANCE. Savings Would Result from Program Changes and Greater Use of Data Mining GAO March 2012 United States Government Accountability Office Report to the Ranking Member, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs, U.S. Senate

More information

EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE. Copyright 2005 by the Society of Actuaries

EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE. Copyright 2005 by the Society of Actuaries EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE OF THE SOCIET OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE by Judy Feldman Anderson, FSA and Robert L. Brown, FSA Copyright 25 by the Society of Actuaries The Education and Examination

More information

Dairy Margin Protection Program 2014 FARM BILL PROVIDES NEW RISK MANAGEMENT TOOL FOR DAIRY FARMERS

Dairy Margin Protection Program 2014 FARM BILL PROVIDES NEW RISK MANAGEMENT TOOL FOR DAIRY FARMERS September 2014 INSIGHTS Inside the Dairy Margin Protection Program 2014 FARM BILL PROVIDES NEW RISK MANAGEMENT TOOL FOR DAIRY FARMERS AgriThought AgriBank provides financial solutions to meet the needs

More information

What Percent Level and Type of Crop Insurance Should Winter Wheat Growers Select? 1

What Percent Level and Type of Crop Insurance Should Winter Wheat Growers Select? 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Technical Paper Series Congressional Budget Office Washington, DC FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Albert D. Metz Microeconomic and Financial Studies

More information

Multiple Peril Crop Insurance

Multiple Peril Crop Insurance Multiple Peril Crop Insurance Multiple Peril Crop Insurance (MPCI) is a broadbased crop insurance program regulated by the U.S. Department of Agriculture and subsidized by the Federal Crop Insurance Corporation

More information

Cash in advance model

Cash in advance model Chapter 4 Cash in advance model 4.1 Motivation In this lecture we will look at ways of introducing money into a neoclassical model and how these methods can be developed in an effort to try and explain

More information

GAO CROP INSURANCE. Opportunities Exist to Reduce the Costs of Administering the Program. Report to Congressional Requesters

GAO CROP INSURANCE. Opportunities Exist to Reduce the Costs of Administering the Program. Report to Congressional Requesters GAO United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Requesters April 2009 CROP INSURANCE Opportunities Exist to Reduce the Costs of Administering the Program GAO-09-445 { April 2009

More information

JAMAICA. Agricultural Insurance: Scope and Limitations for Weather Risk Management. Diego Arias Economist. 18 June 2009

JAMAICA. Agricultural Insurance: Scope and Limitations for Weather Risk Management. Diego Arias Economist. 18 June 2009 JAMAICA Agricultural Insurance: Scope and Limitations for Weather Risk Management Diego Arias Economist 18 June 2009 Financed partly by the AAACP EU Support to the Caribbean Agenda The global market Products

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Understanding the Standard Reinsurance Agreement, Explains Crop Insurance Companies Losses 1,2

Understanding the Standard Reinsurance Agreement, Explains Crop Insurance Companies Losses 1,2 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

Yield Protection Crop Insurance will have the same Yield Coverage as Revenue Protection, but RP is Expected to be the Preferred Choice (Updated) 1

Yield Protection Crop Insurance will have the same Yield Coverage as Revenue Protection, but RP is Expected to be the Preferred Choice (Updated) 1 Disclaimer: This web page is designed to aid farmers with their marketing and risk management decisions. The risk of loss in trading futures, options, forward contracts, and hedge-to-arrive can be substantial

More information

PPACA Subsidy Model Description

PPACA Subsidy Model Description PPACA Subsidy Model Description John A. Graves Vanderbilt University November 2011 This draft paper is intended for review and comments only. It is not intended for citation, quotation, or other use in

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast Elements of Revenue Forecasting II: the Elasticity Approach and Projections of Revenue Components Fiscal Analysis and Forecasting Workshop Bangkok, Thailand June 16 27, 2014 Joshua Greene Consultant IMF-TAOLAM

More information

Portfolio Allocation and Alternative Structures of the Standard

Portfolio Allocation and Alternative Structures of the Standard Portfolio Allocation and Alternative Structures of the Standard Reinsurance Agreement Dmitry V. Vedenov, Mario J. Miranda, Robert Dismukes, and Joseph W. Glauber 1 Selected Paper presented at AAEA Annual

More information

Designing Crop Insurance to Manage Moral Hazard Costs

Designing Crop Insurance to Manage Moral Hazard Costs Designing Crop Insurance to Manage Moral Hazard Costs R.D. Weaver e-mail: r2w@psu.edu Taeho Kim Paper prepared for presentation at the X th EAAE Congress Exploring Diversity in the European Agri-Food System,

More information

Second Hour Exam Public Finance - 180.365 Fall, 2007. Answers

Second Hour Exam Public Finance - 180.365 Fall, 2007. Answers Second Hour Exam Public Finance - 180.365 Fall, 2007 Answers HourExam2-Fall07, November 20, 2007 1 Multiple Choice (4 pts each) Correct answer indicated by 1. The portion of income received by the middle

More information

Traditional Products. The two Traditional Crop Insurance Products are: Named Peril Crop Insurance (NPCI) Multi Peril Crop Insurance (MPCI)

Traditional Products. The two Traditional Crop Insurance Products are: Named Peril Crop Insurance (NPCI) Multi Peril Crop Insurance (MPCI) Traditional Products Traditional crop insurance relies on the principle of indemnity, where losses are measured in the field either after the event (named peril crop insurance) or through yield measurement

More information

Can Markets for Health Insurance Work?

Can Markets for Health Insurance Work? Can Markets for Health Insurance Work? Jonathan Levin Gaston Eyskens Lectures November 2013 Roadmap Lectures 1. Technology and Asymmetric Information 2. High Risk Consumer Credit Markets 3. Measuring Inefficiencies

More information

On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy

On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy Daiki Asanuma Abstract This paper examines whether the survival of low-productivity firms in Japan has prevented economic recovery since the bursting of the financial bubble

More information

The Effects of Premium Subsidies on Demand for Crop Insurance

The Effects of Premium Subsidies on Demand for Crop Insurance United States Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service Economic Research Report Number 169 July 2014 The Effects of Premium Subsidies on Demand for Crop Insurance Erik J. O Donoghue United States

More information

The Impact of Unemployment Benefits on Job Search Efforts

The Impact of Unemployment Benefits on Job Search Efforts Online job search and unemployment insurance during the Great Recession Ioana Marinescu, University of Chicago [PRELIMINARY; DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT AUTHOR S PERMISSION.] Abstract The 2007 2009 recession

More information

Does Federal Disaster Assistance Crowd Out Private Demand for Insurance?

Does Federal Disaster Assistance Crowd Out Private Demand for Insurance? Does Federal Disaster Assistance Crowd Out Private Demand for Insurance? Carolyn Kousky Resources for the Future Erwann O. Michel-Kerjan Wharton School University of Pennsylvania Paul A. Raschky Department

More information

Premium Copayments and the Trade-off between Wages and Employer-Provided Health Insurance. February 2011

Premium Copayments and the Trade-off between Wages and Employer-Provided Health Insurance. February 2011 PRELIMINARY DRAFT DO NOT CITE OR CIRCULATE COMMENTS WELCOMED Premium Copayments and the Trade-off between Wages and Employer-Provided Health Insurance February 2011 By Darren Lubotsky School of Labor &

More information

Effects of Subsidized Crop Insurance on Crop Choices

Effects of Subsidized Crop Insurance on Crop Choices Effects of Subsidized Crop Insurance on Crop Choices Jisang Yu Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis jiyu@primal.ucdavis.edu Selected Paper prepared for presentation

More information

Crop Insurance for Cotton Producers: Key Concepts and Terminology

Crop Insurance for Cotton Producers: Key Concepts and Terminology Crop Insurance for Cotton Producers: Key Concepts and Terminology With large investments in land, equipment, and technology, cotton producers typically have more capital at risk than producers of other

More information

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral Copyright 2012 by the Investment Company Institute. All rights reserved. Suggested citation: Brady, Peter. 2012. The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of

More information

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 11 FISCAL POLICY* Key Concepts The Federal Budget The federal budget is an annual statement of the government s expenditures and tax revenues. Using the federal budget to achieve macroeconomic

More information

4 th IAIS/A2ii Consultation Call Agricultural Insurance

4 th IAIS/A2ii Consultation Call Agricultural Insurance 4 th IAIS/A2ii Consultation Call Agricultural Insurance The following questions have been received during the 4 th IAIS-A2ii Consultation Call on Agricultural Insurance on June 26 th at 10am and 4pm and

More information

What is Grain Merchandising, Hedging and Basis Trading?

What is Grain Merchandising, Hedging and Basis Trading? Grain Merchandising What is Grain Merchandising, Hedging and Basis Trading? Grain merchandising describes the process of buying and selling grain. Agribusiness firms that merchandise grain include grain

More information

Celebrating Pork. The Dubious Success of the Medicare Drug Benefit. Dean Baker. March 2007

Celebrating Pork. The Dubious Success of the Medicare Drug Benefit. Dean Baker. March 2007 Celebrating Pork The Dubious Success of the Medicare Drug Benefit Dean Baker March 2007 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite 400 Washington, D.C. 20009 202 293 5380

More information

FLOOD DAMAGES AND TOOLS FOR THEIR MITIGATION Lenka Camrova, Jirina Jilkova

FLOOD DAMAGES AND TOOLS FOR THEIR MITIGATION Lenka Camrova, Jirina Jilkova FLOOD DAMAGES AND TOOLS FOR THEIR MITIGATION Lenka Camrova, Jirina Jilkova University of Economics, Prague, 2006, pp. 418. ISBN: 80-86684-35-0 English Summary In 1997 and 2002 the Czech Republic was heavily

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Fiscal Policy and Management in East Asia, NBER-EASE, Volume 16 Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi

More information

United States General Accounting Office

United States General Accounting Office GAO United States General Accounting Office Testimony Before the Committee on Small Business, House of Representatives For Release on Delivery Expected at 10 a.m. EDT Wednesday July 16, 1997 SMALL BUSINESS

More information

Executive Summary. Model Structure. General Economic Environment and Assumptions

Executive Summary. Model Structure. General Economic Environment and Assumptions Executive Summary The (LTFP) report is an update from the preliminary report presented in January 2009 and reflects the Mayor s Proposed Budget for Fiscal Year 2010 and Fiscal Year 2011. Details of the

More information

THE COMMODITY RISK MANAGEMENT GROUP WORLD BANK

THE COMMODITY RISK MANAGEMENT GROUP WORLD BANK THE COMMODITY RISK MANAGEMENT GROUP WORLD BANK Agricultural Insurance: Scope and Limitations for Rural Risk Management 5 March 2009 Agenda The global market Products Organisation of agricultural insurance

More information

EXPLAINING HEALTH CARE REFORM: Risk Adjustment, Reinsurance, and Risk Corridors

EXPLAINING HEALTH CARE REFORM: Risk Adjustment, Reinsurance, and Risk Corridors EXPLAINING HEALTH CARE REFORM: Risk Adjustment, Reinsurance, and Risk Corridors As of January 1, 2014, insurers are no longer able to deny coverage or charge higher premiums based on preexisting conditions

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION March 1, 2005 JCX-4-05 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER David Cutler Harvard University and NBER Patricia Seliger Keenan NBER December

More information

SCHOOL LOCAL PROPERTY TAX OPTION 1999 Legislation

SCHOOL LOCAL PROPERTY TAX OPTION 1999 Legislation STATE OF OREGON LEGISLATIVE REVENUE OFFICE H-197 State Capitol Building Salem, Oregon 97310-1347 Research Report (503) 986-1266 Research Report # 5-99 SCHOOL LOCAL PROPERTY TAX OPTION 1999 Legislation

More information

The consumer purchase journey and the marketing mix model

The consumer purchase journey and the marketing mix model Dynamic marketing mix modelling and digital attribution 1 Introduction P.M Cain Digital media attribution aims to identify the combination of online marketing activities and touchpoints contributing to

More information

Pasture, Rangeland, and Forage Insurance: A Risk Management Tool for Hay and Livestock Producers

Pasture, Rangeland, and Forage Insurance: A Risk Management Tool for Hay and Livestock Producers October 2012 Pasture, Rangeland, and Forage Insurance: A Risk Management Tool for Hay and Livestock Producers Monte Vandeveer, Otoe County Extension Educator University of Nebraska-Lincoln Institute of

More information

GAO. HOMEOWNERSHIP Potential Effects of Reducing FHA s Insurance Coverage for Home Mortgages

GAO. HOMEOWNERSHIP Potential Effects of Reducing FHA s Insurance Coverage for Home Mortgages GAO United States General Accounting Office Report to the Chairman, Subcommittee on Housing and Community Opportunity, Committee on Banking and Financial Services, House of Representatives May 1997 HOMEOWNERSHIP

More information

A Methodology for Calculating the Opportunity Cost of Layered Sovereign DRFI Strategies

A Methodology for Calculating the Opportunity Cost of Layered Sovereign DRFI Strategies IMPACT APPRAISAL FOR SOVEREIGN DISASTER RISK FINANCING AND INSURANCE PROJECT: PHASE 1 ACTUARIAL AND REINSURANCE, PAPER 1 A Methodology for Calculating the Opportunity Cost of Layered Sovereign DRFI Strategies

More information

GAO STUDENT LOAN PROGRAMS. As Federal Costs of Loan Consolidation Rise, Other Options Should Be Examined. Report to Congressional Requesters

GAO STUDENT LOAN PROGRAMS. As Federal Costs of Loan Consolidation Rise, Other Options Should Be Examined. Report to Congressional Requesters GAO United States General Accounting Office Report to Congressional Requesters October 2003 STUDENT LOAN PROGRAMS As Federal Costs of Loan Consolidation Rise, Other Options Should Be Examined GAO-04-101

More information

U.S. Farm Policy: Overview and Farm Bill Update. Jason Hafemeister 12 June 2014. Office of the Chief Economist. Trade Bureau

U.S. Farm Policy: Overview and Farm Bill Update. Jason Hafemeister 12 June 2014. Office of the Chief Economist. Trade Bureau U.S. Farm Policy: Office of the Chief Economist Trade Bureau Overview and Farm Bill Update Jason Hafemeister 12 June 2014 Agenda Background on U.S. Agriculture area, output, inputs, income Key Elements

More information

Weather Insurance to Protect Specialty Crops against Costs of Irrigation in Drought Years

Weather Insurance to Protect Specialty Crops against Costs of Irrigation in Drought Years Weather Insurance to Protect Specialty Crops against Costs of Irrigation in Drought Years By Edouard K. Mafoua Post-Doctoral Associate Food Policy Institute Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey

More information

THE INVOLVEMENT OF GOVERNMENTS IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE

THE INVOLVEMENT OF GOVERNMENTS IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF AGRICULTURAL INSURANCE International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management United Kingdom Vol. III, Issue 6, June 2015 http://ijecm.co.uk/ ISSN 2348 0386 THE INVOLVEMENT OF GOVERNMENTS IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF AGRICULTURAL

More information

Financial Impacts from Farmland Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05)

Financial Impacts from Farmland Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05) Financial Impacts from Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05) By Cory Walters and John Barnhart 1 Long-term farm financial strength stemming from investment decisions is a primary

More information