Experiential Learning of The Efficient Market Hypothesis: Two Trading Games

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Experiential Learning of The Efficient Market Hypothesis: Two Trading Games"

Transcription

1 Experiential Learning of The Efficient Market Hypothesis: Two Trading Games Andreas Park Assistant Professor University of Toronto Department of Economics 150 St. George Street Toronto, ON, M5S 3G7, Canada Phone: Fax:

2 Experiential Learning of The Efficient Market Hypothesis: Two Trading Games Abstract In goods markets an equilibrium price balances demand and supply; in a financial market an equilibrium price also aggregates people s information to reveal the true value of a financial security. Although the underlying idea of informationally efficient markets is one of the centerpieces of capital market theory, students often have difficulties grasping and accepting that asset prices fulfill this dual role of information revelation and demand-supply aggregation. The author presents two simple classroom games that illustrate the workings of information transmission and aggregation through prices. The games are easy to comprehend, simple to implement and short. Each game takes about 30 minutes, including classroom discussions, and by the end students will have an intuitive feel for informational efficiency. Keywords: efficient capital markets, information aggregation, trading JEL codes: A22, C91, D82, G14 1

3 One of the hallmarks of finance theory is that financial markets are informationally efficient, that is, that asset prices correctly reflect market participants information. Yet this notion is difficult to convey in the classroom: to many students it seems rather miraculous that prices should aggregate information. In this article I propose two classroom games that help students get a feel for the process of information aggregation. Both games have a common theme: students are presented an item that represents the fundamental value of a company s share. Its value is represented by a glass jar of nickels or small, identically sized glass objects and it is thus tangible, yet uncertain. With some effort and patience, students can count the objects and thus get a good estimate of the asset s true value. Students record their first estimate before trading starts so that in the aftermath they can determine if indeed prices reveal the average opinion. Asking them to also record their estimate after trading has concluded allows them to document whether there is learning from prices. Students opinions about the share s value will differ, but if prices aggregate information correctly, then, loosely, the market price that equilibrates demand and supply should reveal the average opinion. When there are also sufficiently many opinions, this average should be close to the true value of the underlying asset. And indeed I usually observe both outcomes. The first game represents an idealized Walrasian market in which students submit demand-supply-schedules for an asset. Demands and supplies are aggregated centrally and a market clearing price is determined in the spirit of a Walrasian auction (henceforth: the Walrasian game). The second game mimics the dynamic trading environment of most 2

4 traditional stock exchanges. Students trade assets face-to-face and all transactions are publicly listed (henceforth: the face-to-face trading game). The details are outlined below. For the Walrasian game I observed that the market price is close to and usually slightly below the average opinion. 1 Moreover, provided that there are sufficiently many students present, prices also reflect the true value. There are several possible explanations for why the price is slightly below the average opinion, for instance, people may be avoiding the winner s curse, there may be too much noise in the small sample, or people may be simply risk averse. The classroom discussion will help students get an intuitive grasp of these concepts. Aggregate demand and supplies are usually monotonic, and it never fails to impress students how smoothly the market aggregates their different opinions. With face-to-face trading, prices typically fluctuate widely in the first few minutes. The simplest explanation for this fluctuation is that the first few trades are arranged oneon-one without public guidance as to what the correct price might be. Eventually, prices settle on a tentative upward trajectory. If the group is not too large and trading is transparent, then after about two-thirds of the trading time, activity comes to a stop for several minutes. Towards the end trading activity resumes and often prices fall a little. This is consistent with learning: early trades are only observed with a lag, whereas later trades are more transparent because there are fewer transactions. There are two types of buyers: those with high valuations and those who speculate on rising prices. Together these two types create a tentative upward trajectory of prices. As prices rise, it becomes harder to find someone with a high enough valuation to sell shares to. Eventually, as the market closing time approaches, speculators try to unload their positions, causing price 3

5 drops. After the game, the spread of opinions tightens, which illustrates learning from prices. There are three simple messages that students can derive from playing these games: (1) the wisdom of masses holds, that is, the average prior opinion is close to the truth, (2) markets and prices aggregate opinions, and (3) people often act according to the efficient market hypothesis even if they have not yet been taught the concept. Although these learning objectives obtain independently of the trading mechanism, the trading outcomes differ in the two games, illustrating the importance of the organization of financial market trading. In a nutshell, in the Walrasian game prices are generally closer to the true value and the average opinion than in the face-to-face trading game. There are several possible reasons for the differences. For instance, there may be behavioral biases such as the unwillingness to realize losses. Another explanation is that endowments may be too limited and short selling is not allowed. The latter hinders the revelation of low valuations compared to the Walrasian game, which implicity allows short-selling and where endowments play no role. The Walrasian game is thus the cleanest way to show how well prices aggregate the average opinion. The face-to-face trading game, on the other hand, can illustrate the relevance of limited endowments or short-selling constraints. The latter game also provides an intuitive background for discussions of no-trading results, which state that two parties cannot agree to be both benefiting from a trade. Moreover, it also illustrates other trading motives such as the greater-fool-fallacy that is based on the idea that while one may be a fool to buy, one expects to find an even greater fool who one can sell to at a higher price. 4

6 Although prices usually converge to the true underlying value, one must be careful when setting up the game. It matters how many shares are available for trading: the more shares there are, the less trading activity is observed. Even if prices ultimately do not reflect the true value, the classroom discussion helps students greatly to understand how prices aggregate information and why market frictions may impede this mechanism. The ultimate goal of the games is for students to get a feel for trading and the informational role of prices, and to establish credibility for the idea that financial market prices aggregate information. In contrast to most games that are used in the financial markets experimental literature (discussed in the next section), the games proposed here do not require students to compute the value of a stock with a mathematical model. The simple setup and its easy implementation make it more likely that the learning objectives are achieved. The game is suitable for most standard undergraduate finance courses, and may be useful in graduate financial economics courses or speciality courses on financial market microstructure. 2 In the next section I review the literature on market-efficiency games and their adaptations to the classroom. I then explain the setups of my two trading games, outline some common findings of the games and provide guidelines for the classroom discussion. The appendices contain the games instructions. LITERATURE ON FINANCIAL MARKET (CLASSROOM) GAMES The games that I propose are a blend of classroom market games in the tradition of Smith (1962) and winner s curse games as described, among others, in Thaler (1988). In contrast to all other games in the literature that mimic financial market trading, students are not expected to compute the value of a financial asset. This simplifies the 5

7 implementation of the games in the classroom greatly and avoids distorted outcomes caused by the students limited mathematical capabilities. Several financial market game authors studied the emergence of bubbles in market experiments, starting with Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988), and, more recently, Lei, Noussair, and Plott (2001) and Haruvy and Noussair (2006). The frameworks employed in these articles are very similar, and Ball and Holt (1998) provided an adaptation of these setups for a classroom environment. In all these games, there is an underlying fundamental value that is constant (or decreasing) over time. 3 All information is public, and students can effectively compute the (risk-neutral) fundamental value by backward induction. In these games one frequently observes large positive deviations from this value, and this is usually interpreted as the emergence of a bubble. In a second strand of literature Plott and Sunder (1988) and Forsythe and Lundholm (1990) examined how information is aggregated through prices. In these games people receive private signals, and the pooled information reveals the true value of the underlying asset. These studies usually find that the existence of informational efficiency crucially depends on the market structure. All of these experiments require that participants understand a problem on a relatively high level of abstraction. At the very least, participants have to compute a (discounted) sum of expected future payments and understand backward induction. It cannot be overemphasized that problems and settings that seem simple to academic economists may be hard for our student audience. 4 Information aggregation is also taught in the context of auctions. Bazerman and Samuelson (1983) were the first to auction glasses of pennies, nickels, or paper clips. 5 6

8 The penny-auction is usually designed to illustrate the winner s curse, and so when setting up the game, one tries to ensure that winner s-curse-type overbidding occurs. A first step towards this goal is making it difficult to estimate the true value. For instance, in Bazerman and Samuelson (1983) the value of the object is $8, but the average opinion is only about $5. The purpose of the games that I propose is different: people are supposed to be able to estimate the value correctly (and they do on average), and prices are meant to reveal information (which they do). The first definition of the efficient markets by Fama (1965) is still the one found in most textbooks, yet it gives very little guidance as to exactly how information aggregation is achieved, and under which conditions we would accept or reject that a price or market is informationally efficient. The seminal micro foundation of the efficient market hypothesis (EMH) was provided by Grossman (1976, 1977) and Grossman and Stiglitz (1976, 1980) and the games proposed here are best described as an experimental implementation of Grossman s work. However, for teaching purposes, especially on the undergraduate level, Grossman s models are usually considered to be too advanced. Moreover, the underlying theoretical models are very specific, usually combining constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) utility functions with normally distributed asset returns. This specific structure makes an experimental implementation difficult. The games that I outline here can thus be seen as filling a gap, allowing instructors to discuss the information aggregation role of prices as well as, tentatively, allowing a simple illustration of Grossman s results. 7

9 THE SETUP OF THE TRADING GAMES I ran the games with several groups of undergraduate students: about 2/3 were third or fourth year students in economics or commerce, who had one term training in basic finance; the remaining third were second year students of commerce and economics with two years of standard training in economics (but no training in finance). I also ran the games with a class of Financial Economics graduate students, who usually proceed to become analysts or traders in major Canadian financial institutions. The group sizes varied between 13 and 36 people; larger classes were split in half. One needs about two instructors per 20 students to organize trading efficiently. Each game requires four steps: first, explaining the rules, second, playing the game, third, analyzing and summarizing the information collected during the game and Insert Figure 1 here. fourth, discussing the outcomes in class. Ideally one would perform Steps 1 and 2 in the last 20 minutes of the class or tutorial/discussion section that precedes the lecture where the efficient markets are to be taught, so that one can analyze the data between classes (Step 3) and then discuss the outcomes in the following lecture (Step 4). 6 Common Setup for Both Games The asset. The security is represented by a glass filled with a number of identical objects. The objects and the jars should be chosen in such a manner that it is possible to get a good estimate of the number of objects. I find that small glasses (spice jars) filled with 8

10 $2-$3 worth of U.S. or Canadian 5 cent coins or glass-pebbles worth 5 cents each work well. Photos of sample shares are in Figure 1. Note that a bank-roll of nickels is worth $2. The number of jars. I suggest using one jar per three participants. Market activity and the number of shares are negatively related. If there are too few jars, on the other hand, then the game no longer resembles a market but becomes an auction. Ex ante information extraction. Before trading starts, participants are allowed to examine the jar for a limited amount of time. The time constraint ensures some residual uncertainty, leading to differences in perception. One usually observes that some, though not all, participants try to count the number of coins (some will be taking notes). Assessing the average opinion. Each student will be assigned a trader ID. Before the start of trading/the submission of orders, participants are asked to record their initial assessment of the value of the asset. This information is to be collected right away. In the face-to-face setting students will be asked for their valuation again after the games concludes. If they see their original opinion they may feel inclined to give the same number to be consistent. Suitable class size. The Walrasian game can be played with classes of arbitrary size. Face to face trading requires a manageable group size of about people. If the group is too large, trade reporting becomes logistically challenging. 7 Timing relative to the teaching of informationally efficient markets. I suggest letting students play the game prior to the lecture on informationally efficient markets. This ensures that students approach the games with an open mind instead of wondering what is required of them given the material that was just covered in class. One can then combine 9

11 the formal introduction of informational efficiency with the discussion of the game(s) (see Section 5). Organization of Trading In addition to standard finance classes, I use both games in a course on financial market microstructure to illustrate the institutional differences in market trading arrangements. These two games allow an illustration of two major mechanisms: continuous trading as practiced on most stock exchanges during the day and simultaneous order submission as practiced during the opening sessions of exchanges. 8 Organization of the demand-supply-schedule trading process. Each student receives a sheet of paper with the printout of a table. The first column of this table lists prices (in cents), and in the second and third column students are to enter the number of units they would buy and sell if the price in the first column were the equilibrium price. The maximum quantity that students can buy or sell at any price is restricted (for instance, 10 units) and there is a fixed number x of assets in supply. The instructions (see Appendix A) state that all individual participants demands and supplies will be added up for each price. The price at which the aggregate demand minus supply is closest to x is the market price. Students are also informed how their payoffs are computed. These payoffs depend on the price that they pay and the true value of the asset, and are computed as (quantity demanded at the market price quantity supplied at the market price) (true value market price). 10

12 Students record the number of units that they wish to buy or sell in the table that is given to them, their orders are collected, entered in a spread sheet and the market clearing price is computed. Organization of the face-to-face trading process. The face-to-face trading occurs in a simple, lightly regulated double auction market, in structure akin to floor-based open outcry markets (for instance, the New York Board of Trade). 9 Deals are arranged face-toface, trading tickets are filled out, and prices plus transactions are reported. A fixed number of shares is distributed at random to students. Students are told that those who receive a share have to pay the instructor the true value of the stock after trading concludes and that those who own the stock after trading concludes will be paid the true value by the instructor. 10 Therefore there is a firm terminal value and full information revelation after trading concludes. All other payments are self-explanatory buy-sell transactions. Students are asked to leave their seats to roam the classroom in search of trading partners. The trading process itself is unregulated. For instance, they can negotiate with several people at a time or they can auction their share. Once an agreement is reached, both trading parties record their transactions on trading tickets, and the seller reports the trade to the central trading desk. Transaction prices are then centrally listed on the blackboard. Instructions are in Appendix B. The trading session lasts for roughly 8-12minutes, depending on the class size. The rule of thumb is that the larger the class size, the longer the trading time should be. With groups of students 7 to 8 minutes are sufficient. Although it may be beneficial to have students trade for longer (so that there is more time for price adjustment and 11

13 learning), the time pressure is important to ensure that speculators feel the need to unload their positions. A word about payments. It may be controversial to ask students for payments in a classroom environment; in my sessions no money changed hands. Despite this, students usually take this exercise very seriously and treat their trading as if it were for real money they cherish gains and loathe losses. After all, there is pride involved when making a good transaction or when beating their classmates. As a control I also ran the games twice during paid experimental sessions and found no difference in behavior. For a more detailed discussion on how to properly motivate students to take classroom games seriously see Marks, Lehr, and Brastow (2006) (their footnote 12). COMMON OUTCOMES Common outcomes of the Walrasian game. Figure 2 displays an example of the aggregate demand and supply schedules from the Walrasian game trading session. The column chart is the transaction volume that could be realized for the given prices. The increasing curve is the aggregate supply as a function of the price, the decreasing curve is the aggregate demand. The underlying true value was $2.35, the average opinion was $2.41, the median opinion was $2.25, the market price would be between $2.20 and $2.30. Allocational efficiency was at 82 percent. An aside: Stock exchanges often describe their opening procedure as a process that tries to determine the price that maximizes volume. The graph illustrates this notion because volume is indeed maximal around the transaction price. 12

14 In general, most students submit monotonic demand and supply schedules, with demands that decline with prices, and supplies that increase. There are always some who submit erratic schedules, but the effect of such orders on the equilibrium price is typically negligible. Prices can also deviate from the average opinion because of some residual noise that cannot be eliminated in a small sample. Insert Figure 2 here. That prices are slightly below the average opinion is consistent with two theoretical concepts. First, there may be a small degree of risk aversion. Second, if the price were set at the average opinion, then on average people should be indifferent between buying and selling. This is, however, not market-clearing because there is also a fixed supply of x shares. Therefore, if the average person would obtain a share at his/her own assessment then s/he would be a victim of the winner s curse. By the same token, if prices are above the average opinion, then this may indicate that students were subject to the winner s curse. In three out of seven sessions, the price was below or just marginally above the average opinion. In four sessions, the price was not below the average opinion; notably this occurred for the groups that had no training in finance. These groups also paid on average more than (a) their assessment, (b) the average opinion and (c) the k-th highest opinion, where k is the number of issued shares. Although the students in these sessions violated the theoretical prediction, there is a point to be made that at least on average students acted rationally, that is, on average they 13

15 submitted demand-supply schedules that avoided the winner s curse. To see this I computed the students virtual gains: this number is obtained by multiplying each student s net demand with the difference of their prior valuation and the market price. For instance, if a student has valuation 310 and would buy 5 shares at price p = 300, then his or her virtual profit is 5 ( ) = 50. Table 1 summarizes the above observations. As can be seen in column labelled average virtual profits, the average virtual profit was positive. Also, the column labelled number virtual losses indicates the number of people who made virtual losses. Overall, less than 42 percent of students made virtual losses; with finance-trained students this number is, somewhat comfortingly, even smaller. Finally, one can ask if those with the highest valuations also ended up buying the shares; I dub this the allocation efficiency of the trading process. As can be see from Table 1, allocation efficiency is highest for the finance-trained groups (82-92 percent). Insert Table 1 here. Common Outcomes with face-to-face trading. Figure 3 plots the price development for an example of a face-to-face trading session. The figure plots trading prices against the time when the transaction occurred in a face to face example. The data is from one of the control sessions where people were paid; these were the only sessions presented here for which I had recorded the times of trades. There were 13 people in the session, the true value was $2.85, and there were 4 assets that could be traded. The average opinion was $3.23, the median $2.90, the 4-th highest opinion was $3.00; allocation efficiency at the end was 75 percent. Prices rise along a linear trend. 14

16 Although it is not visible from graph, in the last two minutes of trading there almost no activity; only towards the very end did people engage in negotiations again. Generally, in the smaller sized groups (15-20 people), students first negotiate trades bilaterally. After one or two minutes, when the first prices are posted, trading becomes more organized: people often start an open auction by lifting their shares and shouting prices. 11 In the middle of the trading session volume declines, and instead the auctioneers try to sell their assets at very high prices (higher than the last transaction price). Towards the end, transaction activity picks up again, and is often accompanied by a slight downswing in prices (which is observed but not statistically significant). Overall with face-to-face trading, one observes a tentative price increase during the first 2/3 of the session, followed by low activity, followed by a slight downswing in prices. Incidentally, this U-shaped volume pattern is also observed on most stock markets. Students buy for two reasons: first, they think that the security is undervalued. Second, they buy because they speculate that there may be somebody else who has a higher valuation. For a given class size, roughly 2/3 of students are actively transacting. A sizeable number of the non-transacting students try to trade but cannot agree on a price. This is worthy of discussion because people who have a low opinion of the asset cannot easily convey this belief. If short-sales were allowed or if there were larger endowments of assets, then those who believe that the asset is overvalued could potentially bring the price down by selling. Because the shares are allocated randomly and there are fewer shares than students, before trading starts, early sellers are not necessarily those who have a low opinion; 15

17 instead, all participants are in search for the highest opinion. Once they realize that these people are rare, prices slowly fall as speculators unload their positions. Insert Figure 3 here. The number of transactions is negatively related to the number of assets, 12 that is, the more shares there are the lower is the number of transactions. Moreover, there is also a negative correlation between the average trading price (scaled by the true value) and the number of assets, that is, the more shares are available the lower the price. The range of opinions shrinks/tightens from before to after trading and the variance of opinions also shrinks. The average price is above the average opinion by about 11 percent, above the true value by 9 percent, and above the k-th highest opinion by 4.5 percent, where k is the number of issued shares. There is also a substantial amount of speculative trading: on average more than 50 percent of the buyers trade above their valuation, whereas only 25 percent of the sellers transact at prices below their valuation. On average buyers lose in expectation, whereas sellers gain. Allocational efficiency on average is at 64 percent which is lower than in the Walrasian game. All of the above findings are summarized in Table 2. Speculation may account for the (virtual) losses that buyers are willing to incur in the process, but one is left wondering why people hold on to their shares beyond the end of the game when they could have unloaded them earlier. Looking only at the inefficient allocations and excluding a session with poor data recording, 71 percent of the buyers who held on to their shares until the end of trading made an average virtual loss. Half of 16

18 the last owners could have made a profit had they sold at (one of) the last trading prices. This point is worth mentioning to students for it documents the well-known phenomenon that people tend to hang on to their losses. SUGGESTIONS FOR THE CLASSROOM DISCUSSION The classroom discussion following the game is a vital component of the learning exercise and should clarify key concepts. The discussion should center around the question of whether or not prices aggregate information, and the discussion should include the following components. First, students should discuss how they came up with their valuation. This way they learn that there were some people with better and some with worse assessment techniques. Second, the instructor should lead the discussion to let individuals describe how they learned from market behavior. Most likely, those with the most extreme initial valuations revised their opinion after observing trading behavior. Third, informational efficiency of prices can be assessed relative to two numbers: the true value and the average opinion. Usually these two measures are close, the true value can only be revealed if the average opinion is sufficiently close to it. If the two are not close, then prices can still be close to the average opinion and thus aggregate information. Irrespective of whether the true value is revealed, the game will help students understand how actions reveal information and how prices then aggregate information. As stated before, I propose to introduce the standard teaching material on 17

19 efficient markets only after the game has been played. This material can then be intertwined with the discussion of the game outcomes. In what follows I will outline a few core concepts from the theory of informationally efficient markets. The literature on market efficiency originated in Fama (1965). He introduced three notions of efficient markets as follows: first, markets are weak-form efficient if all information from past market trading is reflected by the current price. Next there is the semi-strong form when all publicly available information regarding the prospects of a firm is reflected in the current price. Finally, under the strong-form efficiency, all information relevant to the firm is reflected by the current price, including insider information; Campbell, Lo, and MacKinlay (1997) used the term private information. These three types of market efficiency have their origin in empirical work, and early work lacked a micro foundation. Grossman (1976) filled the gap by developing a framework in which people s private information is incorporated in a rational expectations market clearing price. In the games presented here, arguably, people obtain a private signal from examining the jar of nickels, 13 and thus the games test to what extent prices incorporate information in the sense of Grossman. 14 Because Grossman provided a micro foundation for the EMH, by association the games illustrate the efficient market hypothesis in Fama s sense. To wit, because the private signals are based on public information it is reasonable to assert that the relevant EMH studied here is the semistrong form. The games also help students to get a better understanding of the standard empirical tests of the efficient market hypothesis. One of the implications of the weak-form EMH is that prices are a sub-martingale, or, more loosely, they are a random-walk. Consequently, 18

20 a so-called technical analysis, which is the extraction of information about the future movement of prices from past prices, should have no merit. The face-to-face setting can actually illustrate why this may or may not be accurate. For instance, it is not true that every trading-action is fully informative, because people speculate so that a buy-trade may originate either from someone who has a favorable opinion or from a speculator. Students understand this idea well, and many apply it. The classroom discussion can then establish that speculative behavior, to some extent, can be understood as trying to exploit alleged short-term inefficiencies, that is, situations in which the price reflects information inaccurately. At the same time, speculators often lose money and although this is not directly caused by the weak-form efficient nature of prices, it illustrates the greater-fool fallacy. It also illustrates that the common initial upward trend is not a useful predictor for future price movements. Next, an implication of the semi-strong form of the EMH is that a fundamental analysis (a careful analysis of the value of the jar) should have no or little merit as prices will incorporate the information that analysts have obtained. When acting on the basis of an accurate analysis, one can avoid making the wrong decision: in the demand-supplyschedule game, most people made virtual profits, that is, given their assessment they took positions that would be profitable from their subjective perspectives. Moreover, people who were more careful in their counting usually did better. In part this thus illustrates what a fundamental analysis is and why it may have merit. At the same time, in the face-to-face trading game, a careful analysis may not pay out: prices are usually high, often exceeding the average opinion. Invariably there will be some students who merely eye-balled the value and thus arrived at a poor quality 19

21 assessment and others, who came up with a careful assessment method that allowed a precise estimate. These latter people are often the ones who believe that trading prices are too high. Yet because endowments are limited and short-selling is not allowed, they cannot utilize their knowledge, and their opinion does not enter prices adequately. This observation can lead to inspiring classroom discussion of real-world institutional and regulatory restrictions: for instance, mutual funds and most pension funds are banned from taking short positions whereas hedge-funds are not. 15 Another issue that merits discussion is that in the face-to-face setting, all profits and losses add to zero. As a consequence, on every trade, one party gains, one loses. Of course, in reality trading can be Pareto-improving because of diversification or tax benefits; the face-to-face trading game can thus inspire a discussion of these trading motives. It should be stressed that the games do not provide a perfect test of the validity of any level of efficient market hypothesis. Indeed, as Forsythe and Lundholm (1990) pointed out, it is generally impossible to devise a test that definitively determines whether or not market efficiency prevails. That being said, it is usually plainly visible in the games that some form of information aggregation occurs; for instance, prices never grossly deviate from the opinions in the room. In summary, for teaching purposes the games provide ample evidence in favor of Grossman s information aggregation models. 20

22 CONCLUSION I presented two simple trading games that allow students to develop an intuitive grasp of how financial market prices aggregate people s opinions. The first game is a setting that is close to an idealized Walrasian market: people submit a demand-supply schedule that lists precisely how much they are willing to buy or sell at each price. The Walrasian market clearing price usually reflects the average opinion and is also often very close to the true value. The second game mimics intra-day trading on financial markets, with all its frantic activity and standard shortcomings. Although prices never grossly deviate from the opinions in the room, they tend to be higher than in the Walrasian game. This allows the instructor to lead students into meaningful, well-founded discussions on, for instance, the impact of short-selling constraints and limited endowments on the inclusion of negative opinions. The major innovation of the games is their simplicity: in contrast to all other financial market trading games in the literature, students do not have to compute a value that is based on a mathematical construction. Instead, students only have to estimate the number of coins in a jar. Thus although I provided a teaching module, there are potential implications for experimental research that may use the games simplicity to check the robustness of existing findings. 21

23 Appendix A INSTRUCTIONS FOR STUDENTS: DEMAND-SUPPLY SCHEDULE You will participate in a simple trading simulation that follows these steps 1. I will show you the asset. Your job is to estimate its true value. 2. You then have to submit your demand-supply schedule. 3. A market price is established (demand=supply). 4. The true cash value of the asset is announced. 5. Trading gains/losses are computed. Profits and losses. To illustrate gains and losses, suppose the market clearing price is 150 whereas the true value is 140. Example 1: You bought 5 assets. Your payoff: 5 ( ) = 50. Example 2: You sold 10 assets. Your payoff: 10 ( ) = 100. Bottom line: If you buy when the market price is above the true value, then you lose money; if you buy when the market price is below the true value, then you win. Likewise, if you sell when the market price is above the true value, then you win and if you sell if the market price is above the true value then you lose. The Asset. You will be trading assets. These assets are jars filled with blue or green pebbles; I will them show to you in a moment. Each pebble is worth 5 cents. You may look at the jar, but you are not allowed to open it. Please note that the jar itself has no value (it is only wrapping) and that all jars are identical and contain the same number of pebbles. 22

24 Apart from the jars that are bought and sold by your fellow classmates there is a fixed supply of 8 jars. Before we start trading, we will ask you to assess the value of a share. You will find a form in front of you. Please enter your trader ID (a number I give you), and your assessment. Please also express how confident you are about your own assessment by marking the respective box. Order Submission: attached to these instructions is a yellow sheet of paper that lists prices from For each price, please record how many jars you would buy or sell at this price if this were the market price. (This list is your demand-supply schedule.) Note that the price is only established after all demands and supplies have been collected and aggregated. Rules: At any price, you may buy or sell at most 10 jars. If you do not want to participate, then simply do not submit the yellow sheet. 23

25 Appendix B INSTRUCTIONS FOR STUDENTS: FACE-TO-FACE TRADING You will now participate in a simple face-to-face trading simulation. Before you is a glass filled with nickels (5 cent coins). You may look at the jar, but you are not allowed to open it. The content of these jars represents the fundamental value of one share of company xyz. Please note that the jar itself has no value. All jars are identical and contain the same number of nickels. There are 10 identical jars that can be traded on the market. Just before we start trading I give these jars to some students in the room at random. The value of holding a share is as follows: 1. After the game ends, each initial owner of the jars pays the true value of the jar (i.e., the sum of the nickels). 2. Likewise, those who own the jar at the end of trading will be paid the true value (in return for the content of the jar). Before we start trading, I will ask you to assess the value of a jar. You will find a form in front of you. Please enter your trader ID (the number on the blue or green cover sheet of the handout), and your assessment. The organization of trading is simple: markets will be open for 10minutes. 1 minute before the end I will announce that the market is about to close. All trading must stop after I announce the end of trading. You may record last minute trades, but you cannot negotiate further. 24

26 During these 10 minutes you may buy or sell (if you own it) the jar; you can trade with any person in the room, at any price that you agree upon. You may also abstain from trading. Record keeping. The front of the cover sheet (blue or green) that has been given to you indicates your trader ID, the back is your trading ticket. On it you must record your trades. More specifically, recording works as follows: 1. Both parties record their trades on their trading tickets. 2. On your trading ticket you record Your role (buyer or seller), the ID of the other trader (a number) and the price that you agreed upon. 3. The SELLER reports the trade to the market organizer who will record the IDs of both traders and the transaction price. The market organizer will then publicize the transaction price by writing it on the blackboard. 25

27 1 This result is true for the groups of finance students that I played this game with; behavior of groups that were not trained in finance was slightly different. 2 For the latter two, the games are particularly useful in illustrating the different trading mechanisms that are commonly used in capital markets. 3 For instance, in the simple game proposed by Ball and Holt (1998), the fundamental value is $1+$6 (5/6) = $6 and computed as follows: At the end of each round, each share pays a $1 dividend. After the dividend, each share is destroyed with probability 1/6, the outcome being determined by the roll of a die. At the end of all rounds, after the last roll of the die, the surviving asset pays $6. The fundamental value can then be determined by backward induction. Before the last period, the fundamental value is $1+(5/6) $6 = $6. Iterating this argument, the fundamental value is a flat $6 in every period. The other cited papers additionally allow decreasing or stochastic dividends. (Comment: $1+$6(5/6)=$6 to clarify) 4 Having run the Ball and Holt game in several classes I have yet to encounter a student who would compute the fundamental value correctly. I find this quite striking (in a sample of about 80). All students in my sample are trained in basic finance, all are able to compute expectations and know backward induction arguments, and most know how to compute fundamental values, at least for this simple form. 26

28 5 An alternative is Feinstein (2000), who suggested auctioning an envelope that contains either a high or a low value and the class organizer has given students some information about the value. The purpose of his game is to illustrate the strong form of the efficient market hypothesis. 6 Alternatively, a teaching assistant can compute average opinions and Walrasian market prices during the lecture or the games. 7 For instance, the lag between arranging a trade, reporting it, and the price publication becomes too large. Of course large classes can be broken up into subgroups or teams. 8 Market microstructure matters: markets can be centralized (for instance, stock exchanges) or decentralized (such as currency markets), they can be order- or quotedriven, there can be a monopolistic specialist (e.g. NYSE or Deutsche Börse) or many market makers (NASDAQ), there can be a central, onetime clearing system (as in the opening sessions at TSX, NYSE or for infrequently traded stocks on Paris Bourse) or trading can occur continuously. The institutional market microstructure differences lead to differences in trading volume, bid-ask-spreads, intra-day trading patterns and so on. 9 A nice illustration of this trading mechanism can be found in the movie Trading Places: in one of the last scenes, the two heros engage in floor trading in the trading pit for concentrated frozen orange juice (CFOJ). One should point out to students, however, that the two main characters engage in illegal insider trading. 27

29 10 In contrast to the auctioning of a jar of pennies, instructors won t be able to earn their lunch money (see Thaler 1988): they make zero profits. 11 Again this is a noteworthy point in the classroom discussion because it illustrates that people may have a preference for an open process. Of course, it is also possible that students merely copy what they see on television or in the movies. 12 This confirms the recent theoretical result by Hong, Scheinkman, and Xiong (2006), although the specifications that I looked at always had fewer shares than students. It would probably be interesting to consider the case where all students get share allocations so that the number of shares exceeds the number of students. 13 Although the jar is public information, when examining it with their information processing technology students create a piece of private information. The jar is thus a metaphor of a financial statement. Analysts process the information contained in these statements, and they have different capabilities of processing quantities of information, of seeing linkages between different pieces of information, etc. 14 The trading process in the Walrasian game is actually quite similar to Grossman s (1977) model where people submit complete demand-supply schedules. 28

30 15 Brunnermeier and Nagel (2004) show, however, that hedge-funds strategies are more subtle, even if a fund has determined that a stock is overpriced. 29

31 REFERENCES BALL S. B. AND C. A. HOLT Classroom games: Speculation and bubbles in asset markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (1): BAZERMAN M. H. AND W. F. SAMUELSON I won the auction but don t want the prize.. The Journal of Conflict Resolution 27 (4): BRUNNERMEIER M. AND S. NAGEL Hedge funds and the technology bubble. Journal of Finance 59 (5): CAMPBELL J. Y. A. W. LO AND A. C. MACKINLAY The econometrics of financial markets. Princeton University Press. FAMA E The behavior of stock market prices. Journal of Business FEINSTEIN S. P Teaching the strong-form efficient market hypothesis and making the case for insider trading A classroom experiment. Journal of Financial Education 26 (2): FORSYTHE R. AND R. LUNDHOLM Information aggregation in an experimental market. Econometrica 58 (2): GROSSMAN S On the efficiency of competitive stock markets where trades have diverse information. The Journal of Finance 31 (2): The existence of futures markets noisy rational expectations and informational externalities. The Review of Economic Studies 44 (3): GROSSMAN S. J. AND J. E. STIGLITZ Information and competitive price systems. American Economic Review 66 (2):

32 On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. The American Economic Review 70 (3): HARUVY E. AND C. N. NOUSSAIR The effect of short selling on bubbles and crashes in experimental spot asset markets. Journal of Finance 61 (3): HONG H. J. SCHEINKMAN AND W. XIONG Asset float and speculative bubbles. Journal of Finance 61 (3): LEI V. C. N. NOUSSAIR AND C. R. PLOTT Nonspeculative bubbles in experimental asset markets lack of common knowledge of rationality vs. actual irrationality. Econometrica 69 (4): MARKS M. D. LEHR AND R. BRASTOW Cooperation versus free riding in a threshold public goods classroom experiment. The Journal of Economic Education 37 (2): PLOTT C. R. AND S. SUNDER rational expectiations and the aggregation of diverse information in laboratory security markets. Econometrica 56 (5): SMITH V. L An experimental study of competitive market behavior. The Journal of Political Economy 70 (2): SMITH V. L. G. SUCHANEK AND A. W. WILLIAMS Bubbles, crashes and endogenous expectations in experimental spot asset markets. Econometrica 56: THALER R. H Anomalies the winner s curse. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 2 (1):

33 TABLE 1: Outcomes of the Walrasian Games. True Value Finance trained Average Standard deviation k-th highest Number of traders Price Allocation efficiency Average virtual profits 290 no % no % no % no % yes % yes % yes % Number virtual losses 32

34 TABLE 2: Summary Statistics from Face-to-Face Trading True Value Ø allocation efficiency 29% 85% 67% 75% 50% 43% 80% 82% 75% 60% 65% finance course yes yes yes yes no no no no yes yes number of Assets number of transactions number of people number of active people ø price ø opinion before ø opinion after σ opinion before σ opinion after kth opinion before kth opinion after max ante opinion min ante opinion max post opinion min post opinion buyer ante V p 44(172) -20(82) -45(51) -53(132) -52.5(91) -33(87) -43(64) 5(66) -37(47) -1.9(100) buyer post V p 8(28) -19(56) -39(45) -38(58) 22(180) -8(92) -4(60) 24(72) -17(26) -19(57) seller ante p V -13(53) 23(68) 54(41) 57(91) 49(126) 37(103) 59(71) 4(42) 33(36) -17(127) seller post p V 1(35) 28(52) 50(41) 50(52) -9(153) 26(83) 11(50) -4(67) 23(29) 11(93) ø of ante & post opinion ø price/( ø post & ante) 97% 111% 116% 105% 121% 124% 116% 99% 104% 115% 111% (buyer ante V p)/(ø post & ante) 18% -7% -18% -17% -22% -17% -17% 2% -12% -1% -9% (buyer post V p)/(ø post & ante) 3% -7% -16% -13% 9% -4% -2% 9% -5% -8% -3% (seller ante p V)/(ø post & ante) -5% 8% 22% 19% 20% 19% 24% 2% 10% -7% 11% (seller post p V)/(ø post & ante) 0% 10% 20% 17% -4% 13% 4% -2% 7% 5% 7% buyer neg % ante 33% 69% 67% 56% 59% 53% 67% 35% 73% 61% 57% buyer neg % post 42% 50% 67% 69% 50% 34% 55% 32% 55% 61% 52% seller neg % ante 58% 19% 0% 25% 35% 24% 22% 35% 18% 33% 27% seller neg % post 42% 13% 0% 13% 41% 34% 39% 30% 18% 17% 25% Note: Symbol ø signifies an average and σ a standard deviation. The k in kth highest opinion corresponds to the number of assets available in that setup. neg stands for negative. Buyer ante V-p is the buyer s ex ante valuation minus the price at which s/he traded, averaged over all transactions (similarly for Buyer post and Seller ante/post ) 33

Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options

Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options Question 2.1. The payoff diagram of the stock is just a graph of the stock price as a function of the stock price: In order to obtain the profit diagram

More information

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 7

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 7 ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 7 Diderik Lund Department of Economics University of Oslo 11 March 2015 Diderik Lund, Dept. of Economics, UiO ECON4510 Lecture 7 11 March 2015 1 / 24 Market efficiency Market

More information

Speculation and Bubbles in an Asset Market

Speculation and Bubbles in an Asset Market lassroom Games Speculation and Bubbles in an sset Market Sheryl B. Ball and harles. Holt * bstract: This exercise puts students into a classroom market in which the assets being traded pay a fixed cash

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

SHORT-SELLING AND THE WTA- WTP GAP. Shosh Shahrabani, Tal Shavit and Uri Ben-Zion. Discussion Paper No. 07-06. July 2007

SHORT-SELLING AND THE WTA- WTP GAP. Shosh Shahrabani, Tal Shavit and Uri Ben-Zion. Discussion Paper No. 07-06. July 2007 SHORT-SELLING AND THE WTA- WTP GAP Shosh Shahrabani, Tal Shavit and Uri Ben-Zion Discussion Paper No. 07-06 July 2007 Monaster Center for Economic Research Ben-Gurion University of the Negev P.O. Box 653

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Markus K. Brunnermeier

Markus K. Brunnermeier Institutional tut Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity Markus K. Brunnermeier Preceptor: Dong BeomChoi Princeton University 1 Market Making Limit Orders Limit order price contingent

More information

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011. Two-State Options John Norstad j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011 Abstract How options are priced when the underlying asset has only two possible

More information

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income 2. Forwards, Options, and Hedging This lecture covers the basic derivatives contracts: forwards (and futures), and call and put options. These basic contracts are

More information

Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997

Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997 Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997 Lawrence Harris Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Presented to U.S. House of Representatives Committee on

More information

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 422 March 2009 Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Monika Piazzesi Stanford University and National

More information

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013) Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013) Introduction The United States government is, to a rough approximation, an insurance company with an army. 1 That is

More information

THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY

THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY THE STOCK MARKET GAME GLOSSARY Accounting: A method of recording a company s financial activity and arranging the information in reports that make the information understandable. Accounts payable: The

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

Price Bubbles in Large Financial Asset Markets by Arlington W. Williams, Indiana University

Price Bubbles in Large Financial Asset Markets by Arlington W. Williams, Indiana University Price Bubbles in Large Financial Asset Markets by Arlington W. Williams, Indiana University Forthcoming in Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, C. Plott & V. Smith (eds.) The propensity for long-lived

More information

How to Win the Stock Market Game

How to Win the Stock Market Game How to Win the Stock Market Game 1 Developing Short-Term Stock Trading Strategies by Vladimir Daragan PART 1 Table of Contents 1. Introduction 2. Comparison of trading strategies 3. Return per trade 4.

More information

Steve Meizinger. FX Options Pricing, what does it Mean?

Steve Meizinger. FX Options Pricing, what does it Mean? Steve Meizinger FX Options Pricing, what does it Mean? For the sake of simplicity, the examples that follow do not take into consideration commissions and other transaction fees, tax considerations, or

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider This paper studies household beliefs during the recent US housing boom. The first part presents

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Emilia Matei 1005056 EC372 Term Paper. Topic 3 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes and Merton method of modelling derivatives prices was first introduced

More information

INTRODUCTION TO COTTON FUTURES Blake K. Bennett Extension Economist/Management Texas Cooperative Extension, The Texas A&M University System

INTRODUCTION TO COTTON FUTURES Blake K. Bennett Extension Economist/Management Texas Cooperative Extension, The Texas A&M University System INTRODUCTION TO COTTON FUTURES Blake K. Bennett Extension Economist/Management Texas Cooperative Extension, The Texas A&M University System Introduction For well over a century, industry representatives

More information

Understanding Margins

Understanding Margins Understanding Margins Frequently asked questions on margins as applicable for transactions on Cash and Derivatives segments of NSE and BSE Jointly published by National Stock Exchange of India Limited

More information

Risk, Return and Market Efficiency

Risk, Return and Market Efficiency Risk, Return and Market Efficiency For 9.220, Term 1, 2002/03 02_Lecture16.ppt Student Version Outline 1. Introduction 2. Types of Efficiency 3. Informational Efficiency 4. Forms of Informational Efficiency

More information

Short Selling Tutorial

Short Selling Tutorial Short Selling Tutorial http://www.investopedia.com/university/shortselling/ Thanks very much for downloading the printable version of this tutorial. As always, we welcome any feedback or suggestions. http://www.investopedia.com/investopedia/contact.asp

More information

Understanding Margins. Frequently asked questions on margins as applicable for transactions on Cash and Derivatives segments of NSE and BSE

Understanding Margins. Frequently asked questions on margins as applicable for transactions on Cash and Derivatives segments of NSE and BSE Understanding Margins Frequently asked questions on margins as applicable for transactions on Cash and Derivatives segments of NSE and BSE Jointly published by National Stock Exchange of India Limited

More information

Contrarian investing and why it works

Contrarian investing and why it works Contrarian investing and why it works Definition Contrarian a trader whose reasons for making trade decisions are based on logic and analysis and not on emotional reaction. What is a contrarian? A Contrarian

More information

Implementation Shortfall One Objective, Many Algorithms

Implementation Shortfall One Objective, Many Algorithms Implementation Shortfall One Objective, Many Algorithms VWAP (Volume Weighted Average Price) has ruled the algorithmic trading world for a long time, but there has been a significant move over the past

More information

Probability and Expected Value

Probability and Expected Value Probability and Expected Value This handout provides an introduction to probability and expected value. Some of you may already be familiar with some of these topics. Probability and expected value are

More information

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET Wei T. Yue Alok R. Chaturvedi Shailendra Mehta Krannert Graduate School of Management Purdue University

More information

BONUS REPORT#5. The Sell-Write Strategy

BONUS REPORT#5. The Sell-Write Strategy BONUS REPORT#5 The Sell-Write Strategy 1 The Sell-Write or Covered Put Strategy Many investors and traders would assume that the covered put or sellwrite strategy is the opposite strategy of the covered

More information

Introduction to Futures Contracts

Introduction to Futures Contracts Introduction to Futures Contracts September 2010 PREPARED BY Eric Przybylinski Research Analyst Gregory J. Leonberger, FSA Director of Research Abstract Futures contracts are widely utilized throughout

More information

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS PROBLEM SETS 1. The correlation coefficient between stock returns for two non-overlapping periods should be zero. If not, one could use returns from one period

More information

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk A. Research on Information Acquisition in Markets and Agency Issues Between Investors and Financial Intermediaries An important dimension of the workings of financial markets

More information

Decision Theory. 36.1 Rational prospecting

Decision Theory. 36.1 Rational prospecting 36 Decision Theory Decision theory is trivial, apart from computational details (just like playing chess!). You have a choice of various actions, a. The world may be in one of many states x; which one

More information

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs. OPTIONS THEORY Introduction The Financial Manager must be knowledgeable about derivatives in order to manage the price risk inherent in financial transactions. Price risk refers to the possibility of loss

More information

Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel

Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel Covered Call Writing: I nvestors use two strategies involving stock options to offset risk: (1) covered call writing and (2) protective puts. The strategy

More information

BUBBLES AND CENTRAL BANKS

BUBBLES AND CENTRAL BANKS BUBBLES AND CENTRAL BANKS Abdullah Yavaş MPC Member, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey Distinguished Professor of Real Estate Economics University of Wisconsin- Madison Acting President, International

More information

Equities 2: The Stock Market

Equities 2: The Stock Market Equities 2: The Stock Market Jan 2016 Week 3, FNCE102 R. Loh Raising Stock Stock 1 Equities 2 overview Raising Stock Initial public offering Understanding IPO tombstone ads IPO underpricing offering Pricing

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending Lamont Black* Indiana University Federal Reserve Board of Governors November 2006 ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes empirically the

More information

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems 11 Option Payoffs and Option Strategies Answers to Questions and Problems 1. Consider a call option with an exercise price of $80 and a cost of $5. Graph the profits and losses at expiration for various

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

Challenges in the Life Insurance Industry

Challenges in the Life Insurance Industry Challenges in the Life Insurance Industry Remarks by Superintendent Julie Dickson Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions Canada (OSFI) to the 2010 Life Insurance Invitational Forum Cambridge,

More information

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna April 30, 2015 Outline 1. The Takeover Game 2. Hidden Type (Adverse Selection) 3. Empirical Economics: Intro 4. Empirical Economics: Home Insurance 5. Empirical

More information

WINNING STOCK & OPTION STRATEGIES

WINNING STOCK & OPTION STRATEGIES WINNING STOCK & OPTION STRATEGIES DISCLAIMER Although the author of this book is a professional trader, he is not a registered financial adviser or financial planner. The information presented in this

More information

An Option In the security market, an option gives the holder the right to buy or sell a stock (or index of stocks) at a specified price ( strike

An Option In the security market, an option gives the holder the right to buy or sell a stock (or index of stocks) at a specified price ( strike Reading: Chapter 17 An Option In the security market, an option gives the holder the right to buy or sell a stock (or index of stocks) at a specified price ( strike price) within a specified time period.

More information

2. How is a fund manager motivated to behave with this type of renumeration package?

2. How is a fund manager motivated to behave with this type of renumeration package? MØA 155 PROBLEM SET: Options Exercise 1. Arbitrage [2] In the discussions of some of the models in this course, we relied on the following type of argument: If two investment strategies have the same payoff

More information

Gaming the Law of Large Numbers

Gaming the Law of Large Numbers Gaming the Law of Large Numbers Thomas Hoffman and Bart Snapp July 3, 2012 Many of us view mathematics as a rich and wonderfully elaborate game. In turn, games can be used to illustrate mathematical ideas.

More information

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices Determination of Forward and Futures Prices Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull 2012 Short selling A popular trading (arbitrage) strategy is the shortselling or

More information

Cap Tables Explained

Cap Tables Explained Cap Tables Explained Introduction Capitalization tables ( cap tables ) are used to record and track ownership in a company. If you are a sole proprietor, then it is not necessary to use a cap table you

More information

Recognizing Informed Option Trading

Recognizing Informed Option Trading Recognizing Informed Option Trading Alex Bain, Prabal Tiwaree, Kari Okamoto 1 Abstract While equity (stock) markets are generally efficient in discounting public information into stock prices, we believe

More information

Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise

Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise Jeff Donaldson, University of Tampa Donald Flagg, University of Tampa ABSTRACT Although a lecture on microstructure serves to initiate the inspiration of

More information

INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS

INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS 1. What is the difference between a put option and a call option? 2. What is the difference between an American option and a European option? 3. Why does an option

More information

EVIDENCE IN FAVOR OF MARKET EFFICIENCY

EVIDENCE IN FAVOR OF MARKET EFFICIENCY Appendix to Chapter 7 Evidence on the Efficient Market Hypothesis Early evidence on the efficient market hypothesis was quite favorable to it. In recent years, however, deeper analysis of the evidence

More information

THE EQUITY OPTIONS STRATEGY GUIDE

THE EQUITY OPTIONS STRATEGY GUIDE THE EQUITY OPTIONS STRATEGY GUIDE APRIL 2003 Table of Contents Introduction 2 Option Terms and Concepts 4 What is an Option? 4 Long 4 Short 4 Open 4 Close 5 Leverage and Risk 5 In-the-money, At-the-money,

More information

Time Value of Money Dallas Brozik, Marshall University

Time Value of Money Dallas Brozik, Marshall University Time Value of Money Dallas Brozik, Marshall University There are few times in any discipline when one topic is so important that it is absolutely fundamental in the understanding of the discipline. The

More information

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade chapter 6 >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade One of the nine core principles of economics we introduced in Chapter 1 is that markets

More information

Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks

Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks Peter N Bell and Brian Lui and Alex Brekke University of Victoria 1. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39534/

More information

Hedge Fund Returns: You Can Make Them Yourself!

Hedge Fund Returns: You Can Make Them Yourself! Hedge Fund Returns: You Can Make Them Yourself! Harry M. Kat * Helder P. Palaro** This version: June 8, 2005 Please address all correspondence to: Harry M. Kat Professor of Risk Management and Director

More information

CHAPTER 3 THE LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL

CHAPTER 3 THE LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL CHAPTER 3 THE LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL The next model in our series is called the Loanable Funds Model. This is a model of interest rate determination. It allows us to explore the causes of rising and falling

More information

The Effect of Short Selling on Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Spot Asset Markets. Ernan Haruvy and Charles Noussair ABSTRACT

The Effect of Short Selling on Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Spot Asset Markets. Ernan Haruvy and Charles Noussair ABSTRACT The Effect of Short Selling on Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Spot Asset Markets Ernan Haruvy and Charles Noussair University of Texas-Dallas and Emory University ABSTRACT We study the effect of allowing

More information

Chapter 5 Option Strategies

Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 4 was concerned with the basic terminology and properties of options. This chapter discusses categorizing and analyzing investment positions constructed by meshing puts

More information

THE TRADITIONAL BROKERS: WHAT ARE THEIR CHANCES IN THE FOREX? 205

THE TRADITIONAL BROKERS: WHAT ARE THEIR CHANCES IN THE FOREX? 205 Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. VI, No. 2 (Nov 2003), 205-220 THE TRADITIONAL BROKERS: WHAT ARE THEIR CHANCES IN THE FOREX? 205 THE TRADITIONAL BROKERS: WHAT ARE THEIR CHANCES IN THE FOREX? PAULA C.

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

The Intuition Behind Option Valuation: A Teaching Note

The Intuition Behind Option Valuation: A Teaching Note The Intuition Behind Option Valuation: A Teaching Note Thomas Grossman Haskayne School of Business University of Calgary Steve Powell Tuck School of Business Dartmouth College Kent L Womack Tuck School

More information

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT T H 1RD CANADIAN EDITION W. SEAN CLEARY Queen's University CHARLES P. JONES North Carolina State University JOHN WILEY & SONS CANADA, LTD. CONTENTS PART ONE Background CHAPTER 1

More information

Introduction... 2. The Mental Aspect... 3. Getting the Most Out of Momentum Trader... 4. Follow the Leader... 5

Introduction... 2. The Mental Aspect... 3. Getting the Most Out of Momentum Trader... 4. Follow the Leader... 5 CONTENTS Introduction... 2 Section 1: The Mental Aspect... 3 Section 2: Getting the Most Out of Momentum Trader... 4 Section 3: Follow the Leader... 5 Section 4: How to Read Momentum Trader Alerts... 6

More information

Economia Aziendale online 2000 Web International Business and Management Review

Economia Aziendale online 2000 Web International Business and Management Review Economia Aziendale online 2000 Web International Business and Management Review N. 1/2008 Special Issue 3 rd International Economic Scientific Session International Scientific Conference European Integration

More information

POLICY STATEMENT Q-22

POLICY STATEMENT Q-22 POLICY STATEMENT Q-22 DISCLOSURE DOCUMENT FOR COMMODITY FUTURES CONTRACTS, FOR OPTIONS TRADED ON A RECOGNIZED MARKET AND FOR EXCHANGE-TRADED COMMODITY FUTURES OPTIONS 1. In the case of commodity futures

More information

Lotto Master Formula (v1.3) The Formula Used By Lottery Winners

Lotto Master Formula (v1.3) The Formula Used By Lottery Winners Lotto Master Formula (v.) The Formula Used By Lottery Winners I. Introduction This book is designed to provide you with all of the knowledge that you will need to be a consistent winner in your local lottery

More information

CHAPTER 7 FUTURES AND OPTIONS ON FOREIGN EXCHANGE SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS

CHAPTER 7 FUTURES AND OPTIONS ON FOREIGN EXCHANGE SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS CHAPTER 7 FUTURES AND OPTIONS ON FOREIGN EXCHANGE SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS QUESTIONS 1. Explain the basic differences between the operation of a currency

More information

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Peter Norman Sørensen Økonomi, KU GetFIT, February 2012 Peter Norman Sørensen (Økonomi, KU) Prediction Markets GetFIT,

More information

Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes

Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes WORKING PAPER Comparing the performance of retail unit trusts and capital guaranteed notes by Andrew Clare & Nick Motson 1 1 The authors are both members of Cass Business School s Centre for Asset Management

More information

Understanding ETF Liquidity

Understanding ETF Liquidity Understanding ETF Liquidity SM 2 Understanding the exchange-traded fund (ETF) life cycle Despite the tremendous growth of the ETF market over the last decade, many investors struggle to understand the

More information

Execution Costs. Post-trade reporting. December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1

Execution Costs. Post-trade reporting. December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1 December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1 Execution Costs Execution costs are the difference in value between an ideal trade and what was actually done.

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Bargaining Under Time Pressure in an Experimental Ultimatum Game Martin Kocher, Sabine Strauss, Matthias Sutter 2003/01 Institute of Economic Theory,

More information

How To Get The Most Out Of The Momentum Trader

How To Get The Most Out Of The Momentum Trader Contents Introduction 2 Section 1: The Mental Aspect 4 Section 2: Getting the Most Out of the Momentum Trader 5 Section 3: Follow the Leader 6 Section 4: How to Read Momentum Trader Alerts 7 Section 5:

More information

The Definitive Guide to Swing Trading Stocks

The Definitive Guide to Swing Trading Stocks The Definitive Guide to Swing Trading Stocks 1 DISCLAIMER The information provided is not to be considered as a recommendation to buy certain stocks and is provided solely as an information resource to

More information

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1, XVII. SECURITY PRICING AND SECURITY ANALYSIS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET Consider the following somewhat simplified description of a typical analyst-investor's actions in making an investment decision. First,

More information

Futures Investment Series. No. 2. The Mechanics of the Commodity Futures Markets. What They Are and How They Function. Mount Lucas Management Corp.

Futures Investment Series. No. 2. The Mechanics of the Commodity Futures Markets. What They Are and How They Function. Mount Lucas Management Corp. Futures Investment Series S P E C I A L R E P O R T No. 2 The Mechanics of the Commodity Futures Markets What They Are and How They Function Mount Lucas Management Corp. The Mechanics of the Commodity

More information

COLLECTIVE INTELLIGENCE: A NEW APPROACH TO STOCK PRICE FORECASTING

COLLECTIVE INTELLIGENCE: A NEW APPROACH TO STOCK PRICE FORECASTING COLLECTIVE INTELLIGENCE: A NEW APPROACH TO STOCK PRICE FORECASTING CRAIG A. KAPLAN* iq Company (www.iqco.com) Abstract A group that makes better decisions than its individual members is considered to exhibit

More information

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral Copyright 2012 by the Investment Company Institute. All rights reserved. Suggested citation: Brady, Peter. 2012. The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of

More information

Commodity Options as Price Insurance for Cattlemen

Commodity Options as Price Insurance for Cattlemen Managing for Today s Cattle Market and Beyond Commodity Options as Price Insurance for Cattlemen By John C. McKissick, The University of Georgia Most cattlemen are familiar with insurance, insuring their

More information

CME Group 2012 Commodities Trading Challenge. Competition Rules and Procedures

CME Group 2012 Commodities Trading Challenge. Competition Rules and Procedures Competition Rules and Procedures CME Group with assistance from CQG and the University of Houston, is sponsoring a commodities trading competition among colleges and universities. Students will compete

More information

Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets

Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets Michael Fleming and Asani Sarkar* Federal Reserve Bank of New York 33 Liberty Street New York, NY 10045 (212) 720-6372 (Fleming) (212) 720-8943 (Sarkar)

More information

We never talked directly about the next two questions, but THINK about them they are related to everything we ve talked about during the past week:

We never talked directly about the next two questions, but THINK about them they are related to everything we ve talked about during the past week: ECO 220 Intermediate Microeconomics Professor Mike Rizzo Third COLLECTED Problem Set SOLUTIONS This is an assignment that WILL be collected and graded. Please feel free to talk about the assignment with

More information

Pair Trading with Options

Pair Trading with Options Pair Trading with Options Jeff Donaldson, Ph.D., CFA University of Tampa Donald Flagg, Ph.D. University of Tampa Ashley Northrup University of Tampa Student Type of Research: Pedagogy Disciplines of Interest:

More information

FIN 432 Investment Analysis and Management Review Notes for Midterm Exam

FIN 432 Investment Analysis and Management Review Notes for Midterm Exam FIN 432 Investment Analysis and Management Review Notes for Midterm Exam Chapter 1 1. Investment vs. investments 2. Real assets vs. financial assets 3. Investment process Investment policy, asset allocation,

More information

MA 1125 Lecture 14 - Expected Values. Friday, February 28, 2014. Objectives: Introduce expected values.

MA 1125 Lecture 14 - Expected Values. Friday, February 28, 2014. Objectives: Introduce expected values. MA 5 Lecture 4 - Expected Values Friday, February 2, 24. Objectives: Introduce expected values.. Means, Variances, and Standard Deviations of Probability Distributions Two classes ago, we computed the

More information

Why Do Firms Announce Open-Market Repurchase Programs?

Why Do Firms Announce Open-Market Repurchase Programs? Why Do Firms Announce Open-Market Repurchase Programs? Jacob Oded, (2005) Boston College PhD Seminar in Corporate Finance, Spring 2006 Outline 1 The Problem Previous Work 2 3 Outline The Problem Previous

More information

Investment Finance 421-002 Prototype Midterm I

Investment Finance 421-002 Prototype Midterm I Investment Finance 421-002 Prototype Midterm I The correct answer is highlighted by a *. Also, a concise reasoning is provided in Italics. 1. are an indirect way U. S. investor can invest in foreign companies.

More information

Cash flow before tax 1,587 1,915 1,442 2,027 Tax at 28% (444) (536) (404) (568)

Cash flow before tax 1,587 1,915 1,442 2,027 Tax at 28% (444) (536) (404) (568) Answers Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9 Financial Management June 2014 Answers 1 (a) Calculation of NPV Year 1 2 3 4 5 $000 $000 $000 $000 $000 Sales income 5,670 6,808 5,788 6,928 Variable

More information

Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design

Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design Buyer Search Costs and Endogenous Product Design Dmitri Kuksov kuksov@haas.berkeley.edu University of California, Berkeley August, 2002 Abstract In many cases, buyers must incur search costs to find the

More information

General Risk Disclosure

General Risk Disclosure General Risk Disclosure Colmex Pro Ltd (hereinafter called the Company ) is an Investment Firm regulated by the Cyprus Securities and Exchange Commission (license number 123/10). This notice is provided

More information

6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement

6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement 6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement Stigum (p. 507) says The primary job of the manager of a bank s fed funds desk is to ensure (1) that the bank settles with the Fed and (2) that in doing so, it hold no

More information

RISK WARNING. Retail transactions conducted with NatureForex are not insured by any deposit insurance of any kind.

RISK WARNING. Retail transactions conducted with NatureForex are not insured by any deposit insurance of any kind. RISK WARNING High Risk Investment Margined retail foreign exchange or currency ( forex ), commodities and financial derivatives transactions are extremely risky. Trading with Nature Forex Ltd. ( NatureForex

More information

Chapter 7 Stocks, Stock Valuation, and Stock Market Equilibrium ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Chapter 7 Stocks, Stock Valuation, and Stock Market Equilibrium ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS Chapter 7 Stocks, Stock Valuation, and Stock Market Equilibrium ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 7-1 a. A proxy is a document giving one person the authority to act for another, typically the power

More information

Usefulness of Moving Average Based Trading Rules in India

Usefulness of Moving Average Based Trading Rules in India Usefulness of Moving Average Based Trading Rules in India S K Mitra Institute of Management Technology 35 Km Milestone, Katol Road, Nagpur 441 502, India Tel: 91-712-280-5000 E-mail: skmitra@imtnag.ac.in

More information