Jump-adapted discretization schemes for Lévy-driven SDEs

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Jump-adapted discretization schemes for Lévy-driven SDEs"

Transcription

1 Jump-adapted discretization schemes for Lévy-driven SDEs Arturo Kohatsu-Higa Osaka University Graduate School of Engineering Sciences Machikaneyama cho -3, Osaka , Japan Peter Tankov Ecole Polytechnique Centre de Mathématiques Appliquées 928 Palaiseau Cedex France Abstract We present new algorithms for weak approximation of stochastic differential equations driven by pure jump Lévy processes. The method is built upon adaptive non-uniform discretization based on the jump times of the driving process coupled with suitable approximations of the solutions between these jump times. Our technique avoids the costly simulation of the increments of the Lévy process and in many cases achieves better convergence rates than the traditional schemes with equal time steps. To illustrate the method, we consider applications to simulation of portfolio strategies and option pricing in the Libor market model with jumps. Key words: Lévy-driven stochastic differential equation, Euler scheme, jumpadapted discretization, weak approximation, Libor market model with jumps. 2 Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 6H35, Secondary 65C5, 6G5. Introduction Let Z be a d-dimensional Lévy process without diffusion component, that is, Z t = γt + y N(dy, ds) + y y > Corresponding author yn(dy, ds), t,.

2 Here γ d, N is a Poisson random measure on d, ) with intensity ν satisfying y 2 ν(dy) < and N(dy, ds) = N(dy, ds) ν(dy)ds denotes the compensated version of N. Further, let X be an n -valued adapted stochastic process, unique solution of the stochastic differential equation X t = X + h(x s )dz s, t,, () where h is an n d matrix. The traditional uniformly-spaced discretization schemes for () 5, suffer from two difficulties: first, in general, we do not know how to simulate the driving Lévy process and second, a large jump of Z occurring between two discretization points can lead to an important discretization error. On the other hand, in many cases of interest, the Lévy measure of Z is known and one can easily simulate the jumps of Z bigger in absolute value than a certain >. As our benchmark example, consider the one-dimensional tempered stable Lévy process 5 which has the Lévy density ν(x) = C e λ x x +α x< + C +e λ+ x x +α+ x>. (2) This process, also known as the CGMY model 3 when C = C + and α = α +, is a popular representation for the logarithm of stock price in financial markets. No easy algorithm is available for simulating the increments of this process (cf 2, 4), however, it is straightforward to simulate random variables with density ν(x) x > x > ν(x)dx (3) using the rejection method 5, example 6.9. Sometimes, other approximations of Z by a compound Poisson process, such as the series representations 6 lead to simpler simulation algorithms. A natural idea due to ubenthaler 7 (in the context of finite-intensity jump processes, this idea appears also in 2, 3), is to replace the process Z with a suitable compound Poisson approximation and place the discretization points at the jump times of the compound Poisson process. When the jumps of Z are highly concentrated around zero, however, this approximation is too rough and can lead to convergence rates which are arbitrarily slow. In this paper we are interested in approximating the solution of () in the weak sense. We use the idea of Asmussen and osiński (see also 4) and replace the small jumps of Z with a Brownian motion between the jump times of the compound Poisson approximation. We then replace the solution of the continuous SDE between the jump times by a suitable approximation, which is explicitly computable. Combined, these two steps lead to a much lower discretization error than in 7. If N is the average number of operations required to simulate a single trajectory, the discretization error of our method converges 2

3 to zero faster than N in all cases and faster than N if the Lévy measure of Z is locally symmetric near zero. In practice, the convergence rates are always better than these worst-case bounds: for example, if α = α + =.8 in (2), our method has the theoretical convergence rate of N.22 (compared to only N. without the Brownian approximation) and when α = α + =.5, the rate of our method is N 7. Consider a family of measurable functions (χ ) > : d, such that χ d (y)ν(dy) < and y > y 2 ( χ )(y)ν(dy) < for all > and lim χ (y) = for all y. The Lévy measure ν will be approximated by finite measures χ ν. The most simple such approximation is χ (y) := y >, but others can also be useful (see Example 7 below). We denote by N a Poisson random measure with intensity χ ν ds and by N its compensated Poisson random measure. Similarly, we denote by N the compensated Poisson random measure with intensity χ ν ds, where χ := χ. The process Z can then be represented in law as follows: d Z t = γ t + Zt + t, γ = γ yχ ν(dy) + Z t = t = y yn (dy, ds), d y N (dy, ds). d y > y χ ν(dy), We denote by λ = χ d ν(dy) the intensity of Z, by (Nt ) the Poisson process which has the same jump times as Z, and by Ti, i N, the jump times of Z. Furthermore, we denote by Σ the variance-covariance matrix of : Σ ij = y i y j χ ν(dy), d and in the one-dimensional case we set σ 2 := Σ. Sometimes we shall use the following technical assumption on (χ ): (A) n 2, C such that z n+ χ ν(dz) C z n χ ν(dz) d d for sufficiently small. This assumption, roughly, means that the approximation (χ ) does not remove small jumps faster than big jumps, and it is clearly satisfied by χ (y) = y >. for the process (3) this corresponds to having α + = α and C + = C 3

4 Supposing that no further discretization is done between the jump times of Z, the computational complexity of simulating a single approximate trajectory is proportional to the random number N. To compare our method to the traditional equally-spaced discretizations, we measure instead the computational complexity by the average number of jumps of Z on,, equal to λ. We say that the approximation ˆX converges weakly for some order α > if, for a sufficiently smooth function f, Ef(X ) Ef( ˆX ) Kλ α for some K > and all sufficiently small. In this paper, we provide two versions of the jump-adapted discretization scheme for pure jump Lévy processes. The scheme presented in Section 2 is easier to use and implement but works in the case d = n =. A fully general scheme is then presented in Section 3. Section 4 presents two detailed examples where our method is applied to the problems of long term portfolio simulation and of option pricing in the Libor market model with jumps. 2 One-dimensional SDE For our first scheme we take d = n = and consider the ordinary differential equation dx t = h(x t )dt, X = x. (4) In the one-dimensional case, the solution to this equation can always be written: X t := θ(t; x) = F (t + F(x)), where F is the primitive of h(x). Alternatively, a high-order discretization scheme (such as unge-kutta) can be used and is easy to construct (see also emark 4). We define inductively ˆX() = X and for i, ˆX(T i+ ) = θ( γ (T i+ T i ) + σ (W(T i+ ) W(T i )) 2 h (XT i )σ 2 (T i+ T i ); ˆX(T i )) (5) ˆX(T i ) = ˆX(T i ) + h( ˆX(T i )) Z(T i ). (6) Similarly, for any other point t (Ti, T i+ ), we define ˆX(t) = θ ( γ (t η t ) + σ (W(t) W(η t )) 2 h ( ˆX(η t ))σ 2 (t η t ); ˆX(η t ) ), (7) where we set η t := sup{ti : Ti t}. Here W denotes a one dimensional Brownian motion. Therefore, the idea is to replace the original equation with an Asmussen- osiński type approximation which is explicitly solvable between the times of 4

5 big jumps and is exact for all h if the driving process is deterministic, and for affine h in all cases. The purpose of this construction becomes clear from the following lemma. Lemma. Let h C. The process ( ˆX(t)) defined by (5) (7) is the solution of the stochastic differential equation { d ˆX t = h( ˆX t ) dzt + σ dw t + γ dt + } 2 (h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) ))σdt 2. Proof. It is enough to show that the process Y t := θ(γ t + σ W t 2 h (x)σ 2 t; x) (8) is the solution of the continuous SDE dy t = h(y t ) {σ dw t + γ dt + 2 } (h (Y t ) h (x))σ 2 dt. This follows by an application of Itô formula to (8) using θ(t, z) = h(θ(t, z)) t 2 θ(t, z) t 2 = h (θ(t, z))h(θ(t, z)). For the convergence analysis, we introduce two sets of conditions (parameterized by an integer number n): (H n ) f C n, h C n, f (k) and h (k) are bounded for k n and z 2n ν(dz) <. (H n) f C n, h C n, h (k) are bounded for k n, f (k) have at most polynomial growth for k n and z k ν(dz) < for all k. Theorem 2. (i) Assume (H 3 ) or (H 3) + (A). Then ( Ef( ˆX σ 2 ) ) f(x ) C (σ 2 λ + γ ) + y 3 χ ν(dy). (ii) Assume (H 4 ) or (H 4 ) + (A), let γ be bounded and let the measure ν satisfy y 3 χ ν(dy) y 4 χ ν (dy) (9) 5

6 for some measure ν. Then ( Ef( ˆX σ 2 ) ) f(x ) C (σ 2 + γ ) + y 4 χ (ν + ν)(dy) λ and in particular, Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) C ( σ 2 ) + y 4 χ (ν + ν)(dy). λ emark 3. (i)under the polynomial growth assumptions (H 3 ) or (H 4 ), the constants in the above theorem may depend on the initial value x. (ii) Condition (9) is satisfied, for example, if χ (y) = χ ( y) for all y and and if ν is locally symmetric near zero. That is, ν(dy) = (+ξ(y))ν (dy), where ν is a symmetric measure and ξ(y) = O(y) for y. emark 4. The convergence rates given in Theorem 2 are obtained under the assumption that the equation (4) is solved explicitly. If a discretization scheme is used for this equation as well, the total error will be bounded from below by the error of this scheme. However, usually this constraint is not very important since it is easy to construct a discretization scheme for (4) with a high convergence order, for example, the classical unge-kutta scheme has convergence order 4. Corollary 5 (Worst-case convergence rates). Let χ (x) = x >. Then, under the conditions of part (i) of Theorem 2, Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) o(λ 2 ), and under the conditions of part (ii) of Theorem 2, Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) o(λ ). Proof. These worst-case bounds follow from the following estimates. First, for every Lévy process, σ as. By the dominated convergence theorem, 2 λ as. This implies λ y 3 ν(dy) 2 λ σ 2 and similarly λ y y y 4 ν(dy) 2 λ σ 2. Example 6 (Stable-like behavior). Once again, let χ (x) = x >, and assume that the Lévy measure has an α-stable-like behavior near zero, meaning that ν has a density ν(z) satisfying ν(z) = g(z) z +α, 6

7 where g has finite nonzero right and left limits at zero as, for example, for the tempered stable process (CGMY) 5. Then σ 2 = O( 2 α ), λ = O( α ), y 3 ν(dy) = O( 3 α ) and y 4 ν(dy) = O( 4 α ), y so that in general for α (, 2) y Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) O(λ 3 α ), and if the Lévy measure is locally symmetric near zero and α (, ), Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) O(λ 4 α ). Example 7 (Simulation using series representation). In this example we explain why it can be useful to make other choices of truncation than χ (x) = x >. The gamma process has Lévy density ν(z) = ce λz z z>. If one uses the truncation function χ (x) = x >, one will need to simulate random variables with law ce λz zν((, )) z>, which may be costly. Instead, one can use one of the many series representations for the gamma process 6. Maybe the most convenient one is X t = λ e Γi/c V i Ui t, i= where (Γ i ) is a sequence of jump times of a standard Poisson process, (U i ) is an independent sequence of independent random variables uniformly distributed on, and (V i ) is an independent sequence of independent standard exponential random variables. For every τ >, the truncated sum X t = λ e Γi/c V i Ui t, i:γ i<τ defines a compound Poisson process with Lévy density ν τ (x) = c e λx e λxeτ/c x>, x and therefore this series representation corresponds to χ (x) = e λx(eτ/c ), where can be linked to τ, for example, by setting τ =. Theorem 2 will be proved after a series of lemmas. Lemma 8 (Bounds on moments of X and ˆX). Assume z p ν(dz) < for some p 2, 7

8 h C () and h(x) K( + x ) and h (x) K for some K <. Then there exists a constant C > (which may depend on p but not on ) such that E sup X s p C( + x p ), () s E sup ˆX s p C( + x p ). () s Proof. We shall concentrate on the bound (), the other one will follow by making go to zero. We have with ˆX t = x + γ t = γ + Z t = σ W t + z > h( ˆX s ) γ s ds + h( ˆX s )d Z s zν(dz) + 2 σ2 {h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) )}, z ˆN (dz, ds). Observe that γ t is bounded uniformly on t and on. Using a predictable version of the Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality 6, lemma 2., we then obtain for t and for some constant C < which may change from line to line E sup ˆX s p CE x p + s t ( + h 2 ( ˆX s )(σ 2 + CE x p + h( ˆX s ) p γ s p ds z 2 χ ν(dz))ds) p/2 + h( ˆX s ) p ds CE + x p + h( ˆX s ) p ds The bound () now follows from Gronwall s inequality. ˆX s p ds. z p χ ν(dz) Lemma 9 (Derivatives of the flow). Let p 2 and for an integer n assume z np ν(dz) <, h C n () and h(x) K( + x ) and h (k) (x) K for some K < and all k with k n. Then k p E T < for all k with k n. x k X(t,x) 8

9 Proof. See the proof of lemma 4.2 in 5. Lemma. Let u(t, x) := E (t,x) f(x T ). (i) Assume (H n ) with n 2. Then u C,n (, ), k u are uniformly x k bounded for k n and u is a solution of the equation ( u u (t, x) + γ (t, x)h(x) + u(t, x + h(x)y) u(t, x) u ) (t, x)h(x)y ν(dy) t x y x + (u(t, x + h(x)y) u(t, x)) ν (dy) = (2) y > u(, x) = f(x). (ii) Assume (H n ) with n 2. Then u C,n (, ), u is a solution of equation (2) and there exist C < and p > with k u(t, x) x k C( + x p ) for all t,, x and k n. Proof. The derivative u x satisfies u(t, x) x = E f (X (t,x) T ) x X(t,x) T The interchange of the derivative and the expectation is justified using lemma 9. The boundedness under (H n ) or the polynomial growth under (H n) then follow from lemmas 8 and 9. The other derivatives with respect to x are obtained by successive differentiations under the expectation. The derivative with respect to t is obtained from Itô s formula applied to f(x (t,x) T. Z is a Lévy process and h does not depend on t, Ef(X (t,x) T and hence it is sufficient to study the derivative Ef(X(,x) t yields Ef(X t ) = f(x) + E + E f (X s )h(x s )dz s ). In fact, note that since ) = Ef(X (,x) t ) T t ). The Itô formula {f(x s + h(x s )z) f(x s ) f (X s )h(x s )z}n(dz, ds). Denoting by Z the martingale part of Z and by γ := γ + zν(dz) the z > residual drift, and using lemma 8, we get Ef(X t ) = f(x) + ds γef (X s )h(x s ) + dse {f(x s + h(x s )z) f(x s ) f (X s )h(x s )z}ν(dz), 9

10 and therefore = γef (X t )h(x t ) + E Ef(X t ) t = γef (X t )h(x t ) + {f(x t + h(x t )z) f(x t ) f (X t )h(x t )z}ν(dz) dθe ( θ)h 2 (X t )z 2 2 f(x t + θzh(x t )) ν(dz). Now, once again, lemma 8 allows to prove the finiteness of this expression. Finally, equation (2) is a consequence of Itô s formula applied, this time, to u(t, X t ). Lemma. Let f :, ), ) be an increasing function. Then E f(t η(t))dt Ef(τ), where τ is an exponential random variable with intensity λ. In particular, E (t η(t)) p+ (p + )! dt λ p+. Proof. Let k = sup{k : Tk < }. Then k T i E f(t η(t))dt = E = E E i= k Ti T i i= Ti k T i i= = E T i x 2 f(t Ti )dt + f(t T k )dt T k f(t i t)dt + f(t i t)dt + f(inf{t i : T i > t} t)dt T k f( t)dt f(t k+ t)dt T k = Ef(τ). The second statement of the lemma is a direct consequence of the first one. Proof of theorem 2. From Itô s formula and lemmas 8 and, Ef( ˆX ) f(x ) = Eu(, ˆX ) u(, X ) 2 u(t, = dte ˆX t ) 2 x 2 σh 2 2 ( ˆX t ) χ ν(dy)(u(t, ˆX t + h( ˆX t )y) u(t, ˆX t ) u(t, ˆX t ) + dte 2 σ2 u(t, ˆX t ) h( x ˆX t )(h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) )) x h( ˆX t )y) (3). (4)

11 Denote the expectation in (3) by A t and the one in (4) by B t. From lemmas and 8, we then have, under the hypothesis (H 3 ), A t E 2 y3 h 3 ( ˆX t ) χ ( θ) 2 3 u(t, ˆX t + θyh( ˆX t )) x 3 dθν(dy) CE + h 3 ( ˆX t ) y 3 χ ν(dy) C( + x 3 ) y 3 χ ν(dy). If, instead, the polynomial growth condition (H 3 ) is satisfied, then for some p >, A t CE y 3 ( + h 3 ( ˆX t ))( + ˆX t p + yh( ˆX t ) p ) χ ν(dy) and once again, we use lemma 8 together with the assumption (A), because the Lévy measure is now supposed integrable with any power of y. Under the condition of part (ii) and the hypothesis (H 4 ), A t E 3 u(t, ˆX t ) x 3 h 3 ( ˆX t ) y 3 χ ν(dy) + E 24 y4 h 4 ( ˆX t ) C( + x 4 ) y 4 χ (ν + ν)(dy). ( θ) 3 4 u(t, ˆX t + θyh( ˆX t )) x 4 dθ χ ν(dy) The case of (H 4) is treated as above. To analyze the term B t, define H(t, x) = u(t, x) h(x) x and assume, to fix the notation, that (H 3 ) is satisfied. Then, once again by

12 lemmas and 8, Taylor formula and the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality, B t 2 σ2 E(H(t, ˆX t ) H(t, ˆX η(t) ))(h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) )) + 2 σ2 E H(t, ˆX η(t) )(h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) )) 2 σ2 E ( ˆX t ˆX η(t) ) 2 dθ H x ( ˆX η(t) + θ( ˆX t ˆX η(t) )) + 2 σ2 E H(t, ˆX η(t) )E dθ h ( ˆX η(t) + θ ( ˆX t ˆX η(t) )) (h ( ˆX t ) h ( ˆX η(t) )) F η(t) Cσ 2 E( ˆX t ˆX η(t) ) 2 ( + ˆX t + ˆX η(t) ) + 2 σ2 EH(t, ˆX η(t) )h ( ˆX η(t) )E ˆX t ˆX η(t) F η(t) + 2 σ2 E H(t, ˆX η(t) )( ˆX t ˆX η(t) ) 2 dθ( θ)h (3) ( ˆX η(t) + θ( ˆX t ˆX η(t) )) CσE( 2 ˆX t ˆX η(t) ) 4 /2 + 2 σ2 EH(t, ˆX η(t) )h ( ˆX η(t) )E ˆX t ˆX η(t) F η(t). Note that ˆX t ˆX η(t) = E ˆX t ˆX η(t) F η(t) = E η(t) (5) { h( ˆX s ) σ dw s + γ ds + } 2 (h ( ˆX s ) h ( ˆX ηs ))σds 2, h( ˆX s ) {γ ds + 2 } (h ( ˆX s ) h ( ˆX ηs ))σ 2 ds F η(t). η(t) The Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality and, the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality and lemma 8 then give, under the hypothesis (H 3 ): E( ˆX t ˆX η(t) ) 4 CE h( ˆX s ) {γ ds + 2 } (h ( ˆX s ) h ( ˆX 4 ηs ))σ 2 ds η(t) ( ) 2 t + Cσ 4 E h 2 ( ˆX s )ds η(t) C( γ + σ 2 )4 E(t η(t)) 4 ( + sup ˆX) 4 + Cσ 4 E(t η(t))2 ( + sup ˆX) 4 C( γ + σ 2 )4 E(t η(t)) Cσ 4 E(t η(t)) 4 2. Similarly, for the second term in (5), we get 2 σ2 EH(t, ˆX η(t) )h ( ˆX η(t) )E ˆX t ˆX η(t) F η(t) Cσ 2 ( γ + σ 2 )E(t η(t))2 2. 2

13 Assembling together the estimates for the two terms in (5), B t Cσ 2 (( γ +σ 2 )2 E(t η(t)) 8 2 +σ 2 E(t η(t)) 4 2 +( γ +σ 2 )E(t η(t))2 2 ) Using the Jensen inequality and lemma, this is further reduced to ( B t dt Cσ 2 ( γ + σ 2)2 + γ + σ 2 ). λ From the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality we get ( ) 2 y χ ν(dy) λ y 2 χ ν(dy) Cλ, y y which implies that γ C λ and finally B Cσ 2 λ. Assembling these estimates with the ones for A, we complete the proof under the assumptions (H 3 ) (or (H 4 )). Under the assumptions (H 3) or (H 4) the proof is done in a similar fashion. λ 4 γ +σ 2 3 Approximating multidimensional SDE using expansions In this section we propose an alternative approximation scheme, which yields similar rates to the ones obtained in section 2 but has the advantage of being applicable in the multidimensional case. On the other hand, it is a little more difficult to implement. As before, we start by replacing the small jumps of Z with a suitable Brownian motion, yielding the SDE d X t = h( X t ){γ dt + dwt + dz t }, (6) where W is a d-dimensional Brownian motion with covariance matrix Σ. This process can also be written as X(t) = X(η t ) + h ( ) X(s) dw (s) + η t X(T i ) = X(T i ) + h( X(T i )) Z(T i ). η t h ( X(s) ) γ ds, The idea now is to expand the solution of (6) between the jumps of Z around the solution of the deterministic dynamical system (4), treating the stochastic term as a small random perturbation (see 8, Chapter 2). Assume that the coefficient h is Lipschitz and consider a family of processes (Y α ) α defined by Y α (t) = X(η t ) + α h (Y α (s)) dw (s) + η t h (Y α (s))γ ds η t 3

14 Our idea is to replace the process X := Y with its first-order Taylor approximation: X(t) Y (t) + α Y α (t) α=. Therefore, the new approximation X is defined by X(t) = Y (t) + Y (t), t > η t, X(T i ) = X(T i ) + h( X(T i )) Z(Ti ), Y (t) = X(η t ) + Y (t) = η t η t h(y (t))γ ds (7) h x i (Y (s)) Y i (s)γ ds + η t h (Y (s)) dw (s) where we used the Einstein convention for summation over repeated indices. Conditionally on the jump times (Ti ) i, the random vector Y (t) is Gaussian with mean zero. Applying the integration by parts formula to Y i(t)y j (t), it can be shown that its covariance matrix Ω(t) satisfies the (matrix) linear equation Ω(t) = η t (Ω(s)M(s) + M (s)ω (s) + N(s))ds (8) where M denotes the transpose of the matrix M and M ij (t) = h ik(y (t)) x j γ k and N(t) = h(y (t))σ h (Y (t)). Successive applications of Gronwall s inequality yield the following bounds for Y and Ω: Y (t) ( Y (η t ) + C γ (t η t )) e C γ (t ηt) Ω(t) C Σ (t η t )( + Y (η t ) 2 )e C γ (+ γ )(t ηt). (9) Lemma 2. Assume ν( d ) =. Then γ 2 lim =. λ Proof. Left to the reader as an exercise. To prove Theorem 4, we need to generalize lemmas 8, 9 and to the multidimensional setting. While the generalization of the last two lemmas is straightforward, the first one requires a little work, because it needs to be adapted to the new discretization scheme. Lemma 3 (Bounds on moments of X). Assume ν( d ) =, h C b (n ) and z d z p ν(dz) < for some p 2. 4

15 Then there exists a constant C > (which may depend on p but not on ) such that for all sufficiently small, E sup X s p C( + x p ). (2) s Proof. Denote h t := h( X t ) and h t := h(y (t)). The SDE for X can be rewritten as d X t = h t d Z t + h t dwt + h t γdt + ( h t h t )γ dt + h (Y (t)) Y x (t)γ i dt, i where Z t = ynˆ (dy, ds), γ = γ + yν(dy). y > y > By predictable Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality 6, lemma 2., we then have ( E sup X s p CE x p + h s 2 s t + h s p ds z p χ ν(dz) + + CE ) p/2 z 2 χ ν(dz)ds ( ) p/2 h s 2 Σ ds t h s p γ p ds + γ p h s h s p ds + γ p Y (s) p ds x p + h s p ds + ( + γ p ) t h s h s p ds + γ p Y (s) p ds, where the constant C does not depend on and may change from line to line. Since h is bounded, we have t E sup X s p CE x p + h s p ds + ( + γ p ) Y (s) p ds. s t (2) Using (9), the last term can be estimated as E ( + γ p ) CE ( + γ p ) CE ( + γ p ) CE ( + γ p ) Y (s) p ds = CE ( + γ p ) Ω(s) p/2 ds E Y (s) p F η(s) ds ( + X η(s) ) p ) Σ p/2 (s η s ) p/2 e C γ (+ γ )(s ηs) ds ( + X η(s) ) p ) Σ p/2 τ p/2 e C γ (+ γ )τ ds, 5

16 where τ is an independent exponential random variable with parameter λ. Due to Lemma 2, for sufficiently small, the expectation with respect to τ exists, and computing it explicitly we obtain E ( + γ p ) Y (s) p ds C E ( + X η(s) p )ds, where C as. Inequality (2) therefore becomes t E sup X s p CE x p + h s p ds + C ( + X η(s) p ) s t CE x p + which implies that for sufficiently small, E sup X s p CE + x p + s t and we get (2) by Gronwall s lemma. Theorem 4. h s p ds + C t( + sup X s p ) s t h s p ds, (i) Assume (H 3 ) or (H 3) + (A). Then ( ) Ef( ˆX Σ ) f(x ) C ( Σ + γ ) + y 3 χ ν(dy). λ d (ii) Assume (H 4 ) or (H 4 )+(A), let γ be bounded and suppose that for some measure ν y i y j y k χ ν(dy) d y 4 χ ν (dy) d for all i, j, k and all sufficiently small. Then ( ) Ef( ˆX Σ ) f(x ) C + y 4 χ (ν + ν)(dy). λ d Proof. By Itô formula we have Ef( X ) f(x ) = Eu(, X ) u(, X ) u(t, = dte X(t)) { h ij (Y (t)) + h } ij(y (t)) Y k (t) h ij ( x i x X(t)) γ j (22) k + 2 u( X(t)) h ik (Y (t))σ kl 2 x i x h jl(y (t)) (23) j { u(t, X(t) + h( X(t))y) u(t, X(t)) u(t, X } t ) h ij ( x X(t))y j χ ν(dy). d i (24), 6

17 Denote the expectation term in (22) by A t and the sum of the terms in (23) and (24) by B t. The term A t satisfies u(t, A t CE X(t)) x Y (t) 2 γ Under the assumption (H 4 ) or (H 3 ), using (9), we have A CE Y (t) 2 γ CE Ω(t) γ CE + Y (η t ) 4 /2 Σ γ E(t η t )e C γ (+ γ )(t ηt). Using Lemmas and 3, we then get A t dt C( + x 2 ) Σ γ λ. Under (H 4 ) or (H 3 ) this result can be obtained along the same lines. Let us now turn to the term B t. It is rewritten via B t =E { u(t, X(t) + h( X(t))y) u(t, X(t)) d 2 u(t, X t ) x i x j h ik ( X(t))h jl ( X(t))y k y l } χ ν(dy) u(t, X(t)) h ij ( x X(t))y j i { Σ kl h ik (Y (t))h jl (Y (t)) h ik ( X(t))h jl ( X(t)) } ) + 2 u(t, Y (t)) x i x j ( 2 u(t, + X(t)) 2 u(t, Y (t)) x i x j x i x j { Σ kl h ik (Y (t))h jl (Y (t)) h ik ( X(t))h jl ( X(t)) } Denote the first two lines by B (t), the third line by B 2 (t) and the fourth by B 3 (t). Under the hypotheses (H 4 ) or (H 3 ), we get 3 u(t, X t + θh( X(t))y) B (t) E h il ( x d i x j k X(t))h jm ( X t )h kn ( X(t))y l y m y n χ ν(dy) CE h( X t ) 3 y 3 χ ν(dy) C( + x 3 ) y 3 χ ν(dy). d d Let F ikjl (x) := h ik (x)h jl (x). Using the fact that conditionally on F ηt, Y is a centered Gaussian process, B 2 (t) E 2 u(t, Y (t)) Σ kl {F x i x ikjl (Y (t)) F ikjl ( X(t)) F } ηt j E 2 u(t, Y (t)) Σ kl x i x (t)y q (t) ( θ) 2 F ikjl (Y (t) + θy (t)) dθ j x p x q CE Σ Y (t) 2 ( + sup X s ) s. 7

18 Using once again Lemmas and 3, we obtain B 2 dt C( + x ) Σ 2 λ. With a similar reasoning we obtain that B 3 also satisfies B 3 dt C( + x ) Σ 2 λ. The proof of the first part of the theorem under assumptions (H 4 ) or (H 3 ) is done along the same lines. 4 Applications Stochastic models driven by Lévy processes are gaining increasing popularity in financial mathematics, where they offer a much more realistic description of the underlying risks than the traditional diffusion-based models. In this context, many quantities of interest are given by solutions of stochastic differential equations which cannot be solved explicitly. In this paper we consider two such applications: portfolio management with constraints and the Libor market model with jumps. One-dimensional SDE: portfolio management with constraints The value V t of a portfolio in various common portfolio management strategies can often be expressed as solution to SDE. One example is the so-called Constant Proportion Portfolio Insurance (CPPI) strategy which aims at maintaining the value of the portfolio above some prespecified guaranteed level B t and consists in investing m(v t B t ) into the risky asset S t and the remaining amount into the risk-free bond, where B t is the time-t value of the guarantee: dv t = m(v t B t ) ds t S t + (V t m(v t B t ))rdt. For simplicity we shall suppose that the guarantee is the value of a zero-coupon bond expiring at time t with nominal amount N = : B t = e r(t t) N. This equation can then easily be solved analytically, but often additional constraints imposed on the portfolio make the analytic solution impossible. For instance, often leverage is not allowed, and the portfolio dynamics becomes dv t = min(v t, m(v t B t )) ds t S t + (V t min(v t, m(v t B t )))rdt. Suppose that the stock S follows an exponential Lévy model: dz t = ds t S t rdt, (25) 8

19 where Z is a pure-jump Lévy process, and let Vt = Vt B t be the value of the portfolio computed using B t as numéraire. Equation (25) can be simplified to dv t = min(v t, m(v t ))dz t. (26) This equation cannot be solved explicitly, but the corresponding deterministic ODE dx t = min(x t, m(x t ))dt admits a simple explicit solution for m > : if x Otherwise, for < x < m m X t = xe t. m m then X t = + (x )e mt, t t X t = m m (x )(m )/m e t, t t with t = m log (x )(m ). Figure shows the trajectories of the solution of (26) simulated in the variance gamma model. The variance gamma model is a pure-jump Lévy process with Lévy density ν(x) = Ce λ x x x< + Ce λ+x x>. x The variance gamma process is thus a difference of two independent gamma processes and we simulate it using the approximation of Example 7. The nearexact solution was produced using the standard Euler scheme with discretization steps. With jumps, the jump-adapted scheme has a greater error than the Euler scheme with points, because the Euler scheme uses exact simulation of increments. However for 2 jumps, the error of the jumpadapted scheme virtually disappears, whereas the Euler scheme still has a significant error even with 5 steps. This illustrates the exponential convergence of the jump-adapted scheme for the variance gamma process. Note that these graphs show the trajectories of the solution and hence illustrate the strong convergence. The effect of the weak approximation of small jumps by Brownian motion is therefore not visible, but even without this additional improvement, the convergence for the variance gamma process is very fast. Multidimensional SDE: Libor market model with jumps One important example of a non-trivial multidimensional SDE arises in the Libor market model, which describes joint arbitrage-free dynamics of a set of forward interest rates. Libor market models with jumps were considered among others by Jamshidian, Glasserman and Kou 9 and Eberlein and Özkan 7. Let T i = T +(i )δ, i =,...,n+ be a set of dates called tenor dates. The Libor rate L i t is the forward interest rate, defined at date t for the period T i, T i+. If 9

20 Jump adapted with jumps Jump adapted with 2 jumps Near exact solution Euler with points Euler with 5 points Near exact solution Figure : CPPI portfolio simulation with V =.5 and m = 2 in the variance gamma model (no diffusion component added). Left: jump-adapted scheme. ight: standard Euler scheme. B t (T) is the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond, that is, a bond which pays to its holder unit at date T, the Libor rates can be computed via L i t = ( ) Bt (T i ) δ B t (T i+ ) A Libor market model (LMM) is a model describing an arbitrage-free dynamics of a set of Libor rates. In this example, we shall use a simplified version of the general semimartingale LMM given in, supposing that all Libor rates are driven by a d- dimensional pure jump Lévy process. In this case, following, an arbitragefree dynamics of L t,...,l n t can be constructed via the multi-dimensional SDE dl i t L i t = σ i (t)dz t σ i (t)z d n j=i+ ( + δlj t σj (t)z + δl j t ) ν(dz)dt. (27) Here Z is a d-dimensional martingale pure jump Lévy process with Lévy measure ν, and σ i (t) are d-dimensional deterministic volatility functions. Equation (27) gives the Libor dynamics under the so-called terminal measure, which corresponds to using the last zero-coupon bond B t (T n+ ) as numéraire. This means that the price at time t of an option having payoff H = h(l T,...,L n T ) 2

21 at time T is given by h(l π t (H) = B t (T n+ )E T,..., L n T ) B T (T n+ ) F t n = B t (T n+ )E h(l T,..., L n T ) ( + δl i T ) F t = i= B t (T ) n i= ( + δli t) E h(l T,..., L n T ) n ( + δl i T ) F t i= (28) The price of any such option can therefore be computed by Monte Carlo using equation (27). Introducing a n + -dimensional state process X t with Xt t and Xi t = Li t for i n, a d + -dimensional driving Lévy process Z t = (t Z t ), and a (n + ) (d + )-dimensional function h(x) defined by h =, h j = for j = 2,...,d +, h i = f i (x) and h ij = σj i (x ) with f i (x) := σ i (x )z d n j=i+ ( + δx jσ j ) (x )z + δx j ν(dz), we see that the equation (27) takes the homogeneous form dx t = h(x t )d Z t, to which the discretization scheme of section 3 can be readily applied. For the purposes of illustration, we simplify the model even further, taking d = and supposing that the functions σ i (t) are constant: σ i (t). The driving Lévy process Z is supposed to follow the CGMY model with two alternative sets of parameters: α =.5 and C =.5 in Case and α =.8 and C =. in Case 2. In both cases, we take λ + = and λ = 2. The set of tenor dates for the Libor market model is {5, 6, 7, 8, 9, } years, which corresponds to a stochastic differential equation in dimension 5. The initial values of all forward Libor rates are all equal to 5%. This big a value was taken to emphasize the non-linear effects in the simulation. For the numerical implementation of the scheme of section 3, we solved the equations (7) and (8) simultaneously using the classical 4-th order unge- Kutta scheme, with time step equal to max(, Ti+ T i ). This means that most of the time there is only one step of the unge-kutta scheme between two consecutive jump times, and our numerical tests have shown that even in this case the error associated to the unge-kutta scheme is negligible compared to the stochastic approximation error. As a sanity check, we first compute the price of a zero-coupon bond with maturity T, which corresponds to taking h in equation (28). By construction of the model, if the SDE is solved correctly, we must recover the input price of the zero-coupon bond. Figure 2 shows the ratio of the zero coupon bond price estimated using the first-order scheme of section 3 to the input value. For comparison, we also give the value computed using the -order approximation 2

Sensitivity analysis of European options in jump-diffusion models via the Malliavin calculus on the Wiener space

Sensitivity analysis of European options in jump-diffusion models via the Malliavin calculus on the Wiener space Sensitivity analysis of European options in jump-diffusion models via the Malliavin calculus on the Wiener space Virginie Debelley and Nicolas Privault Département de Mathématiques Université de La Rochelle

More information

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS Denis Bell University of North Florida Modelling Stock Prices Example American Express In mathematical finance, it is customary to model a stock price by an (Ito) stochatic

More information

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Monte Carlo Simulation: IEOR E473 Fall 24 c 24 by Martin Haugh Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations 1 Brief Review of Stochastic Calculus and Itô s Lemma Let S t be the time t price of a particular

More information

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim J. Korean Math. Soc. 43 (2006), No. 4, pp. 845 858 TWO APPROACHES FOR STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATE OPTION MODEL Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim Abstract. We present two approaches of the stochastic interest

More information

Lecture 10. Finite difference and finite element methods. Option pricing Sensitivity analysis Numerical examples

Lecture 10. Finite difference and finite element methods. Option pricing Sensitivity analysis Numerical examples Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 10 Sensitivities and Greeks Key task in financial engineering: fast and accurate calculation of sensitivities of market models with respect to model

More information

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance Author: Yiyang Yang Advisor: Pr. Xiaolin Li, Pr. Zari Rachev Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics State University of New York at Stony Brook October 2, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction

More information

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options he Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options Paul J Atzberger Comments should be sent to: atzberg@mathucsbedu Introduction In this article we shall discuss the Black-Scholes-Merton approach to determining

More information

A spot price model feasible for electricity forward pricing Part II

A spot price model feasible for electricity forward pricing Part II A spot price model feasible for electricity forward pricing Part II Fred Espen Benth Centre of Mathematics for Applications (CMA) University of Oslo, Norway Wolfgang Pauli Institute, Wien January 17-18

More information

Maximum likelihood estimation of mean reverting processes

Maximum likelihood estimation of mean reverting processes Maximum likelihood estimation of mean reverting processes José Carlos García Franco Onward, Inc. jcpollo@onwardinc.com Abstract Mean reverting processes are frequently used models in real options. For

More information

Master of Mathematical Finance: Course Descriptions

Master of Mathematical Finance: Course Descriptions Master of Mathematical Finance: Course Descriptions CS 522 Data Mining Computer Science This course provides continued exploration of data mining algorithms. More sophisticated algorithms such as support

More information

Introduction to portfolio insurance. Introduction to portfolio insurance p.1/41

Introduction to portfolio insurance. Introduction to portfolio insurance p.1/41 Introduction to portfolio insurance Introduction to portfolio insurance p.1/41 Portfolio insurance Maintain the portfolio value above a certain predetermined level (floor) while allowing some upside potential.

More information

Stephane Crepey. Financial Modeling. A Backward Stochastic Differential Equations Perspective. 4y Springer

Stephane Crepey. Financial Modeling. A Backward Stochastic Differential Equations Perspective. 4y Springer Stephane Crepey Financial Modeling A Backward Stochastic Differential Equations Perspective 4y Springer Part I An Introductory Course in Stochastic Processes 1 Some Classes of Discrete-Time Stochastic

More information

On exponentially ane martingales. Johannes Muhle-Karbe

On exponentially ane martingales. Johannes Muhle-Karbe On exponentially ane martingales AMAMEF 2007, Bedlewo Johannes Muhle-Karbe Joint work with Jan Kallsen HVB-Institut für Finanzmathematik, Technische Universität München 1 Outline 1. Semimartingale characteristics

More information

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS NICOLE BÄUERLE AND STEFANIE GRETHER Abstract. In this short note we prove a conjecture posed in Cui et al. 2012): Dynamic mean-variance problems in

More information

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models 780 w Interest Rate Models The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates Before discussing how a bond market-maker would delta-hedge, we first need to specify how bonds behave. Suppose we try to model a zero-coupon

More information

Markovian projection for volatility calibration

Markovian projection for volatility calibration cutting edge. calibration Markovian projection for volatility calibration Vladimir Piterbarg looks at the Markovian projection method, a way of obtaining closed-form approximations of European-style option

More information

Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems

Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems Dmitry Kramkov Carnegie Mellon University Workshop on Interdisciplinary Mathematics, Penn State, May 8-10, 2015 1 / 24 Outline Financial market

More information

Guaranteed Annuity Options

Guaranteed Annuity Options Guaranteed Annuity Options Hansjörg Furrer Market-consistent Actuarial Valuation ETH Zürich, Frühjahrssemester 2008 Guaranteed Annuity Options Contents A. Guaranteed Annuity Options B. Valuation and Risk

More information

The Black-Scholes Formula

The Black-Scholes Formula FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Black-Scholes Formula These notes examine the Black-Scholes formula for European options. The Black-Scholes formula are complex as they are based on the

More information

EXIT TIME PROBLEMS AND ESCAPE FROM A POTENTIAL WELL

EXIT TIME PROBLEMS AND ESCAPE FROM A POTENTIAL WELL EXIT TIME PROBLEMS AND ESCAPE FROM A POTENTIAL WELL Exit Time problems and Escape from a Potential Well Escape From a Potential Well There are many systems in physics, chemistry and biology that exist

More information

ECG590I Asset Pricing. Lecture 2: Present Value 1

ECG590I Asset Pricing. Lecture 2: Present Value 1 ECG59I Asset Pricing. Lecture 2: Present Value 1 2 Present Value If you have to decide between receiving 1$ now or 1$ one year from now, then you would rather have your money now. If you have to decide

More information

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Sun and Chen Journal of Uncertainty Analysis and Applications (215) 3:11 DOI 1.1186/s4467-15-35-7 RESEARCH Open Access Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Jiajun Sun 1 and Xiaowei

More information

A new Feynman-Kac-formula for option pricing in Lévy models

A new Feynman-Kac-formula for option pricing in Lévy models A new Feynman-Kac-formula for option pricing in Lévy models Kathrin Glau Department of Mathematical Stochastics, Universtity of Freiburg (Joint work with E. Eberlein) 6th World Congress of the Bachelier

More information

A Novel Fourier Transform B-spline Method for Option Pricing*

A Novel Fourier Transform B-spline Method for Option Pricing* A Novel Fourier Transform B-spline Method for Option Pricing* Paper available from SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2269370 Gareth G. Haslip, FIA PhD Cass Business School, City University London October

More information

Monte Carlo Methods and Models in Finance and Insurance

Monte Carlo Methods and Models in Finance and Insurance Chapman & Hall/CRC FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS SERIES Monte Carlo Methods and Models in Finance and Insurance Ralf Korn Elke Korn Gerald Kroisandt f r oc) CRC Press \ V^ J Taylor & Francis Croup ^^"^ Boca Raton

More information

Probability and Statistics Prof. Dr. Somesh Kumar Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur

Probability and Statistics Prof. Dr. Somesh Kumar Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur Probability and Statistics Prof. Dr. Somesh Kumar Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur Module No. #01 Lecture No. #15 Special Distributions-VI Today, I am going to introduce

More information

Numerical methods for American options

Numerical methods for American options Lecture 9 Numerical methods for American options Lecture Notes by Andrzej Palczewski Computational Finance p. 1 American options The holder of an American option has the right to exercise it at any moment

More information

Contents. 5 Numerical results 27 5.1 Single policies... 27 5.2 Portfolio of policies... 29

Contents. 5 Numerical results 27 5.1 Single policies... 27 5.2 Portfolio of policies... 29 Abstract The capital requirements for insurance companies in the Solvency I framework are based on the premium and claim expenditure. This approach does not take the individual risk of the insurer into

More information

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory Journal of Uncertain Systems Vol.3, No.1, pp.3-10, 2009 Online at: www.jus.org.uk Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory aoding Liu Uncertainty Theory Laboratory, Department of Mathematical Sciences

More information

Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application

Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application Katja Schilling University of Ulm March 7, 2014 Joint work with Daniel Bauer, Marcus C. Christiansen, Alexander Kling

More information

Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment

Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment Appl. Math. J. Chinese Univ. 21, 25(2: 29-216 Asymptotics of discounted aggregate claims for renewal risk model with risky investment JIANG Tao Abstract. Under the assumption that the claim size is subexponentially

More information

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Jirô Akahori, Yuji Hishida and Maho Nishida Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, Ritsumeikan University 1-1-1 Nojihigashi, Kusatsu, Shiga 525-8577, Japan E-mail: {akahori,

More information

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS L. M. Dieng ( Department of Physics, CUNY/BCC, New York, New York) Abstract: In this work, we expand the idea of Samuelson[3] and Shepp[,5,6] for

More information

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion P. Coolen-Schrijner, F.P.A. Coolen Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Durham, Durham, DH1 3LE, UK e-mail: Pauline.Schrijner@durham.ac.uk

More information

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem Gagan Deep Singh Assistant Vice President Genpact Smart Decision Services Financial

More information

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88 The Heat Equation Lectures INF232 p. 1/88 Lectures INF232 p. 2/88 The Heat Equation We study the heat equation: u t = u xx for x (,1), t >, (1) u(,t) = u(1,t) = for t >, (2) u(x,) = f(x) for x (,1), (3)

More information

Mathematical Finance

Mathematical Finance Mathematical Finance Option Pricing under the Risk-Neutral Measure Cory Barnes Department of Mathematics University of Washington June 11, 2013 Outline 1 Probability Background 2 Black Scholes for European

More information

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Drazen Pesjak Supervised by A.A. Tsvetkov 1, D. Posthuma 2 and S.A. Borovkova 3 MSc. Thesis Finance HONOURS TRACK Quantitative

More information

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia Aim and setting An underlying process X = (X t ) t 0, observed at equally spaced discrete times

More information

The Effective Dimension of Asset-Liability Management Problems in Life Insurance

The Effective Dimension of Asset-Liability Management Problems in Life Insurance The Effective Dimension of Asset-Liability Management Problems in Life Insurance Thomas Gerstner, Michael Griebel, Markus Holtz Institute for Numerical Simulation, University of Bonn holtz@ins.uni-bonn.de

More information

Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski.

Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski. Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski. Fabienne Comte, Celine Duval, Valentine Genon-Catalot To cite this version: Fabienne

More information

HPCFinance: New Thinking in Finance. Calculating Variable Annuity Liability Greeks Using Monte Carlo Simulation

HPCFinance: New Thinking in Finance. Calculating Variable Annuity Liability Greeks Using Monte Carlo Simulation HPCFinance: New Thinking in Finance Calculating Variable Annuity Liability Greeks Using Monte Carlo Simulation Dr. Mark Cathcart, Standard Life February 14, 2014 0 / 58 Outline Outline of Presentation

More information

Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models

Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models General Linear Models - part I Henrik Madsen Poul Thyregod Informatics and Mathematical Modelling Technical University of Denmark DK-2800 Kgs. Lyngby

More information

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula 2.1 Binomial Trees We consider a financial market consisting of a bond B t = B(t), a stock S t = S(t), and a call-option C t = C(t), where the

More information

Rolf Poulsen, Centre for Finance, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, SE-40530 Gothenburg, Sweden. E-mail: rolf.poulsen@economics.gu.se.

Rolf Poulsen, Centre for Finance, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, SE-40530 Gothenburg, Sweden. E-mail: rolf.poulsen@economics.gu.se. The Margrabe Formula Rolf Poulsen, Centre for Finance, University of Gothenburg, Box 640, SE-40530 Gothenburg, Sweden. E-mail: rolf.poulsen@economics.gu.se Abstract The Margrabe formula for valuation of

More information

Example of High Dimensional Contract

Example of High Dimensional Contract Example of High Dimensional Contract An exotic high dimensional option is the ING-Coconote option (Conditional Coupon Note), whose lifetime is 8 years (24-212). The interest rate paid is flexible. In the

More information

Stochastic volatility: option pricing using a multinomial recombining tree

Stochastic volatility: option pricing using a multinomial recombining tree Stochastic volatility: option pricing using a multinomial recombining tree Ionuţ Florescu 1,3 and Frederi G. Viens,4 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Stevens Institute of Technology, Castle Point

More information

Stochastic Gradient Method: Applications

Stochastic Gradient Method: Applications Stochastic Gradient Method: Applications February 03, 2015 P. Carpentier Master MMMEF Cours MNOS 2014-2015 114 / 267 Lecture Outline 1 Two Elementary Exercices on the Stochastic Gradient Two-Stage Recourse

More information

OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS

OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS ONDERZOEKSRAPPORT NR 8904 OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl IN A NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS BY M. VANDEBROEK & J. DHAENE D/1989/2376/5 1 IN A OPTIMAl PREMIUM CONTROl NON-liFE INSURANCE BUSINESS By Martina Vandebroek

More information

The Exponential Distribution

The Exponential Distribution 21 The Exponential Distribution From Discrete-Time to Continuous-Time: In Chapter 6 of the text we will be considering Markov processes in continuous time. In a sense, we already have a very good understanding

More information

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013 Option Pricing Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model Stefan Ankirchner University of Bonn last update: 6th November 2013 Stefan Ankirchner Option Pricing 1 Dividend payments So far: we assumed

More information

1 Simulating Brownian motion (BM) and geometric Brownian motion (GBM)

1 Simulating Brownian motion (BM) and geometric Brownian motion (GBM) Copyright c 2013 by Karl Sigman 1 Simulating Brownian motion (BM) and geometric Brownian motion (GBM) For an introduction to how one can construct BM, see the Appendix at the end of these notes A stochastic

More information

5 Numerical Differentiation

5 Numerical Differentiation D. Levy 5 Numerical Differentiation 5. Basic Concepts This chapter deals with numerical approximations of derivatives. The first questions that comes up to mind is: why do we need to approximate derivatives

More information

Disability insurance: estimation and risk aggregation

Disability insurance: estimation and risk aggregation Disability insurance: estimation and risk aggregation B. Löfdahl Department of Mathematics KTH, Royal Institute of Technology May 2015 Introduction New upcoming regulation for insurance industry: Solvency

More information

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t. LECTURE 7: BLACK SCHOLES THEORY 1. Introduction: The Black Scholes Model In 1973 Fisher Black and Myron Scholes ushered in the modern era of derivative securities with a seminal paper 1 on the pricing

More information

Dirichlet forms methods for error calculus and sensitivity analysis

Dirichlet forms methods for error calculus and sensitivity analysis Dirichlet forms methods for error calculus and sensitivity analysis Nicolas BOULEAU, Osaka university, november 2004 These lectures propose tools for studying sensitivity of models to scalar or functional

More information

Explicit Option Pricing Formula for a Mean-Reverting Asset in Energy Markets

Explicit Option Pricing Formula for a Mean-Reverting Asset in Energy Markets Explicit Option Pricing Formula for a Mean-Reverting Asset in Energy Markets Anatoliy Swishchuk Mathematical & Computational Finance Lab Dept of Math & Stat, University of Calgary, Calgary, AB, Canada

More information

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Abstract Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Artur Sepp Mail: artursepp@hotmail.com, Web: www.hot.ee/seppar 16 November 2002 We study pricing under the local volatility. Our research is mainly

More information

Adaptive Online Gradient Descent

Adaptive Online Gradient Descent Adaptive Online Gradient Descent Peter L Bartlett Division of Computer Science Department of Statistics UC Berkeley Berkeley, CA 94709 bartlett@csberkeleyedu Elad Hazan IBM Almaden Research Center 650

More information

Valuation of the Surrender Option in Life Insurance Policies

Valuation of the Surrender Option in Life Insurance Policies Valuation of the Surrender Option in Life Insurance Policies Hansjörg Furrer Market-consistent Actuarial Valuation ETH Zürich, Frühjahrssemester 2010 Valuing Surrender Options Contents A. Motivation and

More information

Sums of Independent Random Variables

Sums of Independent Random Variables Chapter 7 Sums of Independent Random Variables 7.1 Sums of Discrete Random Variables In this chapter we turn to the important question of determining the distribution of a sum of independent random variables

More information

7: The CRR Market Model

7: The CRR Market Model Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney MATH3075/3975 Financial Mathematics Semester 2, 2015 Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein

More information

Pricing and calibration in local volatility models via fast quantization

Pricing and calibration in local volatility models via fast quantization Pricing and calibration in local volatility models via fast quantization Parma, 29 th January 2015. Joint work with Giorgia Callegaro and Martino Grasselli Quantization: a brief history Birth: back to

More information

1 The Brownian bridge construction

1 The Brownian bridge construction The Brownian bridge construction The Brownian bridge construction is a way to build a Brownian motion path by successively adding finer scale detail. This construction leads to a relatively easy proof

More information

Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab

Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab Monte Carlo Simulation: IEOR E4703 Fall 2004 c 2004 by Martin Haugh Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation, Probability Review and Introduction to Matlab 1 Overview of Monte Carlo Simulation 1.1 Why use simulation?

More information

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15 Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15 1. Motivation This is a pure jump model and hence avoids the theoretical drawbacks of continuous path models.

More information

Pricing complex options using a simple Monte Carlo Simulation

Pricing complex options using a simple Monte Carlo Simulation A subsidiary of Sumitomo Mitsui Banking Corporation Pricing complex options using a simple Monte Carlo Simulation Peter Fink Among the different numerical procedures for valuing options, the Monte Carlo

More information

Probability and Statistics

Probability and Statistics Probability and Statistics Syllabus for the TEMPUS SEE PhD Course (Podgorica, April 4 29, 2011) Franz Kappel 1 Institute for Mathematics and Scientific Computing University of Graz Žaneta Popeska 2 Faculty

More information

Lecture Notes to Accompany. Scientific Computing An Introductory Survey. by Michael T. Heath. Chapter 10

Lecture Notes to Accompany. Scientific Computing An Introductory Survey. by Michael T. Heath. Chapter 10 Lecture Notes to Accompany Scientific Computing An Introductory Survey Second Edition by Michael T. Heath Chapter 10 Boundary Value Problems for Ordinary Differential Equations Copyright c 2001. Reproduction

More information

Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Pricing Forwards and Swaps Chapter 7 Pricing Forwards and Swaps 7. Forwards Throughout this chapter, we will repeatedly use the following property of no-arbitrage: P 0 (αx T +βy T ) = αp 0 (x T )+βp 0 (y T ). Here, P 0 (w T ) is

More information

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas The Black-Scholes pricing formulas Moty Katzman September 19, 2014 The Black-Scholes differential equation Aim: Find a formula for the price of European options on stock. Lemma 6.1: Assume that a stock

More information

Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering

Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering Department of Industrial Engineering and Management Sciences Northwestern University September 15th, 2014

More information

HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS. n!f n (1) lim. ln x n! + xn x. 1 = G n 1 (x). (2) k + 1 n. (n 1)!

HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS. n!f n (1) lim. ln x n! + xn x. 1 = G n 1 (x). (2) k + 1 n. (n 1)! Math 7 Fall 205 HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS Problem. 2008 B2 Let F 0 x = ln x. For n 0 and x > 0, let F n+ x = 0 F ntdt. Evaluate n!f n lim n ln n. By directly computing F n x for small n s, we obtain the following

More information

Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves

Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves Optimal proportional reinsurance and dividend pay-out for insurance companies with switching reserves Abstract: This paper presents a model for an insurance company that controls its risk and dividend

More information

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price Abstract: Chi Gao 12/15/2013 I. Black-Scholes Equation is derived using two methods: (1) risk-neutral measure; (2) - hedge. II.

More information

Alternative Price Processes for Black-Scholes: Empirical Evidence and Theory

Alternative Price Processes for Black-Scholes: Empirical Evidence and Theory Alternative Price Processes for Black-Scholes: Empirical Evidence and Theory Samuel W. Malone April 19, 2002 This work is supported by NSF VIGRE grant number DMS-9983320. Page 1 of 44 1 Introduction This

More information

A non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process for electricity spot price modeling and derivatives pricing

A non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process for electricity spot price modeling and derivatives pricing A non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process for electricity spot price modeling and derivatives pricing Thilo Meyer-Brandis Center of Mathematics for Applications / University of Oslo Based on joint work

More information

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com In this Note we derive the Black Scholes PDE for an option V, given by @t + 1 + rs @S2 @S We derive the

More information

Pricing and hedging American-style options: a simple simulation-based approach

Pricing and hedging American-style options: a simple simulation-based approach The Journal of Computational Finance (95 125) Volume 13/Number 4, Summer 2010 Pricing and hedging American-style options: a simple simulation-based approach Yang Wang UCLA Mathematics Department, Box 951555,

More information

EXISTENCE AND NON-EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR A NONLINEAR HEAT EQUATION

EXISTENCE AND NON-EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR A NONLINEAR HEAT EQUATION Sixth Mississippi State Conference on Differential Equations and Computational Simulations, Electronic Journal of Differential Equations, Conference 5 (7), pp. 5 65. ISSN: 7-669. UL: http://ejde.math.txstate.edu

More information

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model D. Düvelmeyer Technische Universität Chemnitz, Fakultät für Mathematik, 09107 Chemnitz, Germany Abstract In this paper we discuss

More information

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model Applied Mathematical Sciences, vol 8, 14, no 143, 715-7135 HIKARI Ltd, wwwm-hikaricom http://dxdoiorg/11988/ams144644 A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting

More information

THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS

THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS THE BLAC-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS EVAN TURNER Abstract. This paper will derive the Black-Scholes pricing model of a European option by calculating the expected value of the option. We will assume that

More information

Vilnius University. Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics. Gintautas Bareikis

Vilnius University. Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics. Gintautas Bareikis Vilnius University Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics Gintautas Bareikis CONTENT Chapter 1. SIMPLE AND COMPOUND INTEREST 1.1 Simple interest......................................................................

More information

Lectures 5-6: Taylor Series

Lectures 5-6: Taylor Series Math 1d Instructor: Padraic Bartlett Lectures 5-: Taylor Series Weeks 5- Caltech 213 1 Taylor Polynomials and Series As we saw in week 4, power series are remarkably nice objects to work with. In particular,

More information

CONTROLLABILITY. Chapter 2. 2.1 Reachable Set and Controllability. Suppose we have a linear system described by the state equation

CONTROLLABILITY. Chapter 2. 2.1 Reachable Set and Controllability. Suppose we have a linear system described by the state equation Chapter 2 CONTROLLABILITY 2 Reachable Set and Controllability Suppose we have a linear system described by the state equation ẋ Ax + Bu (2) x() x Consider the following problem For a given vector x in

More information

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model 1 第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model Outline 有 关 股 价 的 假 设 The B-S Model 隐 性 波 动 性 Implied Volatility 红 利 与 期 权 定 价 Dividends and Option Pricing 美 式 期 权 定 价 American

More information

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Ralf Korn 1 and L. C. G. Rogers 2 Abstract In the Black-Scholes model, any dividends on stocks are paid continuously, but in reality dividends

More information

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes Dmitry Kramkov, Carnegie Mellon University Based on a paper with Mihai Sirbu from Columbia University Math Finance Seminar,

More information

An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model

An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model Naoufel El-Bachir (joint work with D. Brigo, Banca IMI) Radon Institute, Linz May 31, 2007 ICMA Centre, University

More information

Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability

Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability Nonlinear Dynamics and Systems Theory, 1(2) (2001) 111 119 Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability V. Lakshmikantham 1 and S. Leela 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Florida

More information

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS 1. Introduction All of the options that we have considered thus far have been of the European variety: exercise is permitted only at the termination of the contract. These

More information

Life-insurance-specific optimal investment: the impact of stochastic interest rate and shortfall constraint

Life-insurance-specific optimal investment: the impact of stochastic interest rate and shortfall constraint Life-insurance-specific optimal investment: the impact of stochastic interest rate and shortfall constraint An Radon Workshop on Financial and Actuarial Mathematics for Young Researchers May 30-31 2007,

More information

Grey Brownian motion and local times

Grey Brownian motion and local times Grey Brownian motion and local times José Luís da Silva 1,2 (Joint work with: M. Erraoui 3 ) 2 CCM - Centro de Ciências Matemáticas, University of Madeira, Portugal 3 University Cadi Ayyad, Faculty of

More information

How To Balance In A Distributed System

How To Balance In A Distributed System 6 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON PARALLEL AND DISTRIBUTED SYSTEMS, VOL. 11, NO. 1, JANUARY 2000 How Useful Is Old Information? Michael Mitzenmacher AbstractÐWe consider the problem of load balancing in dynamic distributed

More information

Master s Thesis. Pricing Constant Maturity Swap Derivatives

Master s Thesis. Pricing Constant Maturity Swap Derivatives Master s Thesis Pricing Constant Maturity Swap Derivatives Thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the Master of Science degree in Stochastics and Financial Mathematics by Noemi

More information

A SURVEY ON CONTINUOUS ELLIPTICAL VECTOR DISTRIBUTIONS

A SURVEY ON CONTINUOUS ELLIPTICAL VECTOR DISTRIBUTIONS A SURVEY ON CONTINUOUS ELLIPTICAL VECTOR DISTRIBUTIONS Eusebio GÓMEZ, Miguel A. GÓMEZ-VILLEGAS and J. Miguel MARÍN Abstract In this paper it is taken up a revision and characterization of the class of

More information

OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A COMMERCIAL LOAN REPAYMENT PLAN. E.V. Grigorieva. E.N. Khailov

OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A COMMERCIAL LOAN REPAYMENT PLAN. E.V. Grigorieva. E.N. Khailov DISCRETE AND CONTINUOUS Website: http://aimsciences.org DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS Supplement Volume 2005 pp. 345 354 OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A COMMERCIAL LOAN REPAYMENT PLAN E.V. Grigorieva Department of Mathematics

More information

Applications to Data Smoothing and Image Processing I

Applications to Data Smoothing and Image Processing I Applications to Data Smoothing and Image Processing I MA 348 Kurt Bryan Signals and Images Let t denote time and consider a signal a(t) on some time interval, say t. We ll assume that the signal a(t) is

More information